Expected Benefits from Voting and Voter Turnout in the U.S.: The Role of Senate PAC Election Campaign Contributions,

Similar documents
A Cost Benefit Analysis of Voting

Determinants of Migration, Revisited

Expressive Voting and Government Redistribution *

Case Study: Get out the Vote

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

This presentation is designed to focus our attention on New York s broken campaign finance system and discuss what can be done to fix it All the

TRACKING CITIZENS UNITED: ASSESSING THE EFFECT OF INDEPENDENT EXPENDITURES ON ELECTORAL OUTCOMES

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections

Online Appendix for Redistricting and the Causal Impact of Race on Voter Turnout

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

The Macro Polity Updated

Party Polarization, Revisited: Explaining the Gender Gap in Political Party Preference

AVOTE FOR PEROT WAS A VOTE FOR THE STATUS QUO

Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting

The Textile, Apparel, and Footwear Act of 1990: Determinants of Congressional Voting

Expressiveness and voting

Federal Elections, Union Publications. and. Union Websites

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group

Pavel Yakovlev Duquesne University. Abstract

Public Opinion and Political Participation

Retrospective Voting

THE EFFECT OF EARLY VOTING AND THE LENGTH OF EARLY VOTING ON VOTER TURNOUT

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

Midterm Elections Used to Gauge President s Reelection Chances

Macroeconomics and Presidential Elections

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1

Hungary. Basic facts The development of the quality of democracy in Hungary. The overall quality of democracy

LESSON Money and Politics

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties

Electoral Politics. John N. Lee. Summer Florida State University. John N. Lee (Florida State University) Electoral Politics Summer / 12

Expressive voting and government redistribution: Testing Tullock s charity of the uncharitable

Turnout and Strength of Habits

The Youth Vote 2004 With a Historical Look at Youth Voting Patterns,

FOR RELEASE APRIL 26, 2018

The Cook Political Report / LSU Manship School Midterm Election Poll

1. Amendments impacting Voting. 15th - No Racial Discrimination. 17th - Direct election of senators by citizens, not state legislature appointment

Young Voters after the 2008 Election: A Disappearing Act?

ABSENTEE VOTING, MOBILIZATION, AND PARTICIPATION


NEW JERSEY: DEM MAINTAINS EDGE IN CD11

Chapter 14: THE CAMPAIGN PROCESS. Chapter 14.1: Trace the evolution of political campaigns in the United States.

Migration Patterns in The Northern Great Plains

Purposes of Elections

Eric M. Uslaner, Inequality, Trust, and Civic Engagement (1)

Obama s Economic Agenda S T E V E C O H E N C O L U M B I A U N I V E R S I T Y F A L L

The Economic Impact of Crimes In The United States: A Statistical Analysis on Education, Unemployment And Poverty

Allocating the US Federal Budget to the States: the Impact of the President. Statistical Appendix

Ohio State University

Youth Voter Turnout has Declined, by Any Measure By Peter Levine and Mark Hugo Lopez 1 September 2002

AP PHOTO/MATT VOLZ. Voter Trends in A Final Examination. By Rob Griffin, Ruy Teixeira, and John Halpin November 2017

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design.

Economic Voting Theory. Lidia Núñez CEVIPOL_Université Libre de Bruxelles

EDW Chapter 9 Campaigns and Voting Behavior: Nominations, Caucuses

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

United States House Elections Post-Citizens United: The Influence of Unbridled Spending

Measuring the Shadow Economy of Bangladesh, India, Pakistan, and Sri Lanka ( )

CALTECH/MIT VOTING TECHNOLOGY PROJECT A

Voter Participation and Costs of Elections

Swing Voters in Swing States Troubled By Iraq, Economy; Unimpressed With Bush and Kerry, Annenberg Data Show

The Introduction of Voter Registration and Its Effect on Turnout

The Impact of Economic Freedom on Per Capita Real GDP: A Study of OECD Nation

The California Primary and Redistricting

Vote Likelihood and Institutional Trait Questions in the 1997 NES Pilot Study

Does Government Ideology affect Personal Happiness? A Test

Developing Political Preferences: Citizen Self-Interest

What to Do about Turnout Bias in American Elections? A Response to Wink and Weber

A Not So Divided America Is the public as polarized as Congress, or are red and blue districts pretty much the same? Conducted by

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

NEW JERSEY: CD03 STILL KNOTTED UP

Does Lobbying Matter More than Corruption In Less Developed Countries?*

The Battleground: Democratic Perspective September 7 th, 2016

Follow this and additional works at: Part of the American Politics Commons

THE LOUISIANA SURVEY 2017

Study Background. Part I. Voter Experience with Ballots, Precincts, and Poll Workers

Secretary of Commerce

The Effect of North Carolina s New Electoral Reforms on Young People of Color

US Government Module 3 Study Guide

Party Money in the 2006 Elections:

MEREDITH COLLEGE POLL September 18-22, 2016

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

A.P. United States Government Review Topic #1 Constitutional Underpinnings. Sources: Text Wilson; Reader - Roche and Beard, Federalist #51

The Demography of the Labor Force in Emerging Markets

A Perpetuating Negative Cycle: The Effects of Economic Inequality on Voter Participation. By Jenine Saleh Advisor: Dr. Rudolph

Immigration and Economic Growth: Further. Evidence for Greece

Chapter 9: Elections, Campaigns, and Voting. American Democracy Now, 4/e

THE PUBLIC AND THE CRITICAL ISSUES BEFORE CONGRESS IN THE SUMMER AND FALL OF 2017

Political Parties and Soft Money

Battleground 59: A (Potentially) Wasted Opportunity for the Republican Party Republican Analysis by: Ed Goeas and Brian Nienaber

Randall S. Kroszner Graduate School of Business University of Chicago Chicago, IL and N.B.E.R. and

A Powerful Agenda for 2016 Democrats Need to Give Voters a Reason to Participate

New Findings on the Fiscal Impact of Immigration in the United States

The Effect of Political Trust on the Voter Turnout of the Lower Educated

ORGANIZING TOPIC: NATIONAL GOVERNMENT: SHAPING PUBLIC POLICY STANDARD(S) OF LEARNING

Practice Questions for Exam #2

NH Statewide Horserace Poll

Transcription:

Cebula and Durden, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(2), September 2007, 1-16 1 Expected Benefits from Voting and Voter Turnout in the U.S.: The Role of Senate PAC Election Campaign Contributions, 1960-2004 Richard J. Cebula and Garey C. Durden* Armstrong Atlantic State University and Appalachian State University Abstract This study seeks to investigate the hypothesis that PAC (political action committee) election campaign contributions to U.S. Senate races may reduce the expected benefits of voting and hence voter turnout because the greater the growth of such real PAC contributions, the greater the extent to which eligible voters may become concerned that these contributions lead to PAC political influence over elected officials. Indeed, this study finds for the period 1960-2004 that the aggregate voter participation rate has been negatively impacted by the growth in real PAC contributions to Senate election campaigns, suggesting the need for genuine election campaign finance reform to strengthen and protect the democratic process in the U.S. Keywords: Voter turnout; PAC contributions; U.S. Senate JEL Classification: D72 1. Introduction In the U.S., federal election campaign finance legislation and policy has had a colorful and highly varied history, not only in the form of a variety of statutes but also in certain Supreme Court decisions. For example, in 1867, the federal government first acted to regulate election campaign finances by prohibiting officers and employees of the federal government from soliciting funds from civilian workers employed at U.S. naval yards. 1 Although this legislation was enacted, it obviously applied to only a very small demographic group. The fact remained that federal civil service workers were actually still expected to make election campaign contributions if they hoped to keep their jobs. This was presumably remedied by legislation enacted in 1883 that stopped the legal solicitation of campaign contributions from federal civil service workers. 2 Over two decades later, additional federal statutes were enacted to address campaign contribution issues. For example, legislation enacted in 1907 sought to prevent corporations and nationally chartered commercial banks from making direct financial contributions to the coffers of candidates for federal office, 3 and legislation enacted in 1910 established requirements for U.S. House candidates to disclose campaign funding information. 4 Careful reading of both of these statutes reveals a common problem: the absence of meaningful enforcement and/or verification mechanisms. In other words, these were patronizing laws that proved to have no genuine enforcement power. In 1925, Congress passed legislation that acted to

Cebula and Durden, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(2), September 2007, 1-16 2 codify and revise prior campaign finance legislation in terms of expenditure limitations and disclosure rules. 5 The shortcoming of this legislation was that enforcement was vested in Congress, so that the statute s provisions were routinely violated [the fox was guarding the henhouse ]. Interestingly, despite this shortcoming, this statute was effectively the basic prevailing campaign finance legislation until 1971. 6 As a prelude to the passage of allegedly major campaign finance reform legislation, it is noteworthy that the first formal PAC [political action committee] was actually created in 1944. This was to be the first of many thousands. 7 In any case, in 1971 Congress passed the Federal Election Campaign Act [FECA]. This law repealed the Corrupt Practices Act [Revised] and allegedly attempted to create a comprehensive framework for the regulation of federal election campaign financing. 8 Among other things, its provisions required full and timely disclosure of funding sources and amounts and set ceilings on contributions from candidates themselves as well as from candidates families. This law also permitted unions to solicit voluntary campaign contributions from union members and permitted corporations to solicit voluntary campaign contributions from both their employees and stockholders; furthermore it permitted union and corporate funds to be used to cover overhead in operating PACs. 9 FECA was amended in 1974. Among its many new provisions was one that established the FEC [Federal Election Commission] to administer campaign laws, with Congress to appoint four of its six Commissioners. Further amendments to the Federal Election Campaign Act were enacted in 1976 and 1979. 10 The 1976 FECA Amendments limited individual contributions to national parties to $20,000 per year and individual contributions to a single PAC to $5,000 per year. 11 Clearly, a potentially major loophole in this law was that if more than one PAC supported the same candidate, the so-called ceilings on individual contributions were de facto at best poorly controlled. The 1979 FECA Amendments increased the in-kind amount that volunteers could contribute to campaigns, raised the floor threshold for reporting contributions from $100 to $200, and effectively prohibited the FEC from conducting random audits of PACs. The 1979 FECA amendments also permitted state and local political parties to support federal candidates for elected office by expending unlimited amounts on campaign materials used by volunteers and on projects such as voter registration drives and transportation of voters to voting booths. Whereas the first PAC was formed in 1944, by 1974, some 608 PACs were registered with the FEC. By 1995, the number of registered PACs had grown to more than 4,000. Since 1995, the number of PACs has continued to rise, reaching a total of 4,867 by 2004 [U.S. Census Bureau (2006, Table 409)]. This fact leads to an interesting [albeit perhaps obvious] question: To what extent have the many billions of dollars raised [in the aggregate] by PACs for political candidates for elected offices and causes succeeded and thus tainted the very reason [s] individual citizens go to the polls to vote? In other words, the question becomes: Does the general public in the U.S. experience a reduced expected benefit from voting because of the influence it perceives PACs exercising over elected officials? These are potentially serious questions for the healthy functioning of democracy in the U.S. as well as for the economy. Of course, as indicated below, the factors influencing voting behavior are very complex and often identification of such factors has proven elusive to investigators. Related to the latter issue per se, the introduction by Downs (1957) of the theory of the rational voter, i.e., the Rational Voter Model (RVM), and the work of Black (1958) are particularly

Cebula and Durden, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(2), September 2007, 1-16 3 pertinent. Indeed, since the introduction of the RVM, there have followed numerous and highly varied studies to expand, improve, and test the RVM or variants thereof in a variety of real world or experimental contexts, including Musgrave (1959), Buchanan and Tullock (1962), Tullock (1967), Riker and Ordeshook (1968), Brazel and Silberberg (1973), Ashenfelter and Kelly (1975), Tullock (1977), Dobra and Tullock (1981), Piven and Cloward (1988), Cox and Munger (1989), Durden (1991), Teixeira (1992), Green and Shapiro (1994), Tullock (1998), Greene and Nikolaev (1999), Lapp (1999), Knack (1999), Putnam (2000), Barreto, Segura, and Woods (2004), Cebula (2004), Feddersen (2004), and Tullock (2006). The complexity of the voting decision and voting behavior is perhaps best exemplified in the path-breaking contribution by Buchanan and Tullock (1962), although an insightful early summary of critical issues involving budgetary determination through voting can be found in Musgrave (1959, esp. pp. 116-135). Concern over low voter participation rates in the U.S. is frequently expressed in the economics literature, the political science literature, the press, and elsewhere. In the words of Putnam (2000, p. 31), With the singular exception of voting, American rates of political participation compare favorably with those in other democracies... Putnam (2000, p. 31) proceeds to observe that We are reminded each election year that fewer voters show up at the polls in America than in most other democracies Putnam (2000, p. 32) further observes that poor voter turnout exists despite the fact that the most commonly cited barrier to voting [ burdensome registration requirements ] has been substantially lowered. Interestingly, the Presidential elections of the years 2000 and 2004 witnessed a reversal of this downward spiral, although whether that downward spiral will resume or not is a priori unknown. It is perhaps encouraging that in the 2006 U.S. general election, the aggregate voter participation rate achieved its highest level for a non-presidential election in over a decade. Clearly, since election outcomes can have very profound implications for societal and government resource allocations, the underlying free-rider problem in the voting/not voting decision process may generate huge social and economic costs. The size of government outlays generally and the specific directions in which public expenditures are directed influence the well being of the society as a whole in both the short run and the long run. In other words, voting in theory can play a critical role in budget determination [Musgrave (1959, p. 116)]. So, What determines voter participation, or the lack of it, in the U.S.? The fundamental concern in the present study is whether PAC contributions to Senate election/re-election campaigns negatively affect voter participation. This study adopts the perspective that the decision as to whether or not to vote involves Rational, self-interested individuals [who] engage in behavior that is not motivated directly [simply] by a benefit-cost calculation [Copeland and Laband (2002, p. 351)] involving the probability of whether their individual votes will determine an election outcome. Within such a context, the central hypothesis investigated in this study is that a greater growth rate in real PAC [political action committee] contributions to U.S. Senate elections campaigns may reduce the expected benefits of voting and voter turnout because such contributions may be perceived as leading to PACs, as opposed to individual voters, having influence over elected officials.

Cebula and Durden, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(2), September 2007, 1-16 4 To allow for other voter-behavior determining factors, it is also argued here that a factor such as the public s strong approval or strong disapproval of the incumbent President per se may positively affect voter turnout. Indeed, it is argued in this study that these factors, along with such other factors as the excitement of the Presidential nomination, campaigning, and election process, an unpopular/controversial, protracted war such as the Vietnam War, the public s dissatisfaction with government, and the inflation and real economic growth performances of the economy may combine to significantly affect aggregate voter turnout and hence the election of public officials whose decisions largely determine the allocation of public funds to the myriad forms of public outlay options that exist. In the interest of relevance, i.e., since the public debate over PACs became especially intense primarily beginning in the year 2000 Presidential primaries, the study period runs from 1960 (the earliest date of availability for at least one of the variables in the analysis) through 2004, the last year for which dependable data for all variables in the analysis are currently available. 2. The Empirical Framework: Expected Benefits from Voting Downs (1957) first introduced the concept of the rational voter, from which the RVM derives. The essential basic premise of this theory/model is that an individual will assess the perceived costs and benefits of voting and will vote only if the latter outweigh the former. Paralleling in principle the RVM, then, the probability that a given eligible voter will actually vote, PROBV, is an increasing function of the expected gross benefits [EGB] associated with voting, ceteris paribus, and a decreasing function of the expected gross costs [EGC] associated with voting, ceteris paribus. Accordingly, it follows that: PROBV = f(egb, EGC), f EGB > 0, f EGC < 0 (1) In interpreting EGB, the present study argues that this concept requires a very broad, i.e., a very inclusive and encompassing, interpretation. For example, in most major elections, the marginal probability that one vote will make the difference is approximately zero. Nevertheless, certain circumstances or factors can potentially increase the expected benefits from voting. For example, when there is an issue (be it economic or non-economic in nature) or a candidate for elected office that an eligible voter feels particularly strongly about, voting may provide subjective benefits to the would-be voter because it can serve as an emotional release or outlet. That release may consist of expressing either approval or disapproval regarding the particular issue or candidate. Alternatively, certain circumstances can potentially decrease the expected benefits from voting. For instance, if a circumstance makes one feel disenfranchised from the government, e.g., if a would-be eligible voter feels that elected officials are responsive to special interest groups and often act with limited or no genuine regard for voters wishes per se, the would-be voter feels a reduced expected gross benefit from voting and therefore shies away from making the effort to vote. Thus, this study explores the perspective that the decision to vote or not vote can be impacted by a host of varying, often subjective, but nonetheless powerful circumstances. To begin, this study asks the following question: Does the voter participation rate increase when voters either strongly approve or strongly disapprove of the perceived job performance of the

Cebula and Durden, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(2), September 2007, 1-16 5 incumbent President? To begin, it is observed that the public s approval rating of the U.S. President has for decades been measured scientifically, adopting sound and comparable polling methodologies. The present study, due to a certain data limitation as explained below, covers the period 1960-2004. Over this 44-year period, the mean public approval rating of the incumbent President was 47.9 out of a possible 100.0, with a standard deviation of 8.9. It is hypothesized in this study that the public has a greater incentive to vote when eligible voters are especially pleased or especially displeased in their perception of the incumbent President s job performance. To measure whether the public is especially pleased or displeased with the President, the binary variable PRESAPP/DIS is introduced. The variable PRESAPP/DIS = 1 during those years when the President s average public approval rating is either very low, defined in this study as the average Presidential approval rating minus at least one standard deviation [i.e., an approval rating of roughly 39 or less], or very high, defined here as the mean Presidential approval rating plus at least one standard deviation [i.e., an approval rating of roughly 57 or more]. Thus, it is hypothesized that voting when one either strongly approves or strongly disapproves of the President provides a subjective benefit because the act of voting has facilitated the expression of strong feelings. Naturally, whereas an approval rating that is either very high or very low is expected to increase voter participation, ceteris paribus, an approval rating exceeding 39 but less than 57 is expected to be associated with greater voter apathy and hence a lower voter turnout, ceteris paribus. Presidential elections offer an opportunity for individual eligible voters to vote for a very powerful and important policymaker [the President] in conjunction with voting for myriad other candidates for public office, as well as a potential host of legislative referenda, popular referenda, and initiatives. Hence, during Presidential election years [as opposed to non- Presidential election years], a given trip to the voting booth provides at effectively zero marginal cost an increased expected gross benefit, the added opportunity/benefit of voting for a Presidential candidate, and hence it provides an increased incentive to vote. Moreover, the prospect of voting in such an important election may invoke a high degree of emotional enthusiasm typically missing in most other election years. Such enthusiasm can be fueled by a variety of circumstances, including such considerations as: the large number of and diverse character of the Presidential primaries and the drama attendant thereto; the national party nominating conventions, complete with speculation over prospective Vice Presidential running mates; controversial issues that arise during Presidential primaries and election campaigns; and issues stressed by the media. Indeed, the psychological rewards/benefits of fulfilling one s civic duty by voting may be even more pronounced during a Presidential election year. Consequently, it is hypothesized in this study that the voter participation rate is increased by the benefits associated with a broad assortment of quantifiable and emotional issues generally associated with voting during the Presidential election years, ceteris paribus. The U.S. military involvement in the Vietnam War, which escalated sharply in 1965, clearly can be regarded as having generated intense emotional responses among the U.S. electorate [(Putnam (2000), Feige (1994)]. The controversy and emotions surrounding the Vietnam War were in part reflected in the following: numerous anti-war demonstrations [including flag burning and antidraft demonstrations], disruptions of national political party conventions where Presidential candidates were being nominated, intense and almost constant hawk versus dove debates, and daily media coverage of POWs, MIAs, casualties, and wounded, amidst the chaos that came

Cebula and Durden, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(2), September 2007, 1-16 6 to represent/symbolize the Vietnam War. Arguably, the Vietnam War created intense emotional responses, including an intensified effort to disengage from the Vietnam War by electing new candidates to key political offices. Indeed, the Nixon election victory over President Johnson in 1968 might even be interpreted in part as an emotional expression on behalf of change. It is hypothesized here that the Vietnam War [VIETNAM] elicited interest levels and emotional reactions that raised voter interest and participation, ceteris paribus: voter participation would be expected to yield a benefit by providing a vehicle for expressing one s feelings and views on this major public issue. It is hypothesized here that greater public dissatisfaction [DIS] with government (as opposed to elected officials per se) acts to discourage voting by eliciting a negative emotional response on the part of voters, a hypothesis that is in principle consistent with arguments in Feige (1994, p. 129). More specifically, if would-be voters feel discouraged by their government because of negative perceptions as to whether government officials can be trusted to fulfill their responsibilities, whether they are dishonest, and whether they waste tax dollars, then would-be voters very likely may react by adopting a negative attitude toward voting, presumably resulting from lower expected gross benefits from voting, consequently, voter turnout would tend to decline, ceteris paribus. To measure this variable, this study adopts the dissatisfaction index, DIS. DIS is constructed as an equally weighted average of three normalized indices reflecting responses to the University of Michigan s Institute for Social Research [ISR] surveys concerning whether government employees can be trusted to do their assigned jobs, whether they are dishonest, and whether government officials waste tax dollars. Values for DIS range from a low of 1.5, for least dissatisfied, to a high of +1.5, for most dissatisfied. As constructed, the DIS index measures the public s attitude toward government in general, as opposed to an attitude toward the President per se or elected officials per se. Feddersen (2004, p. 107) argues that individuals base their voting [participation] decision in part on assessments about the overall macroeconomic health of the economy. Accordingly, it is also hypothesized in this study that the more poorly the economy is performing, e.g., the more slowly the economy is expanding [in real terms], the more interest the public [eligible voters] may have in the outcome of a major election. If indeed the economy is growing too slowly, the public may vote so as to express a wish for change at some level [s] of government because of fear of the unemployment prospects associated with slow real GDP growth. Consequently, it is expected that if real GDP grows too slowly [SLOWGR], the greater may be the expected potential benefits from voting [so as to precipitate change in order to implement more effective economic policies and/or to at least express displeasure with the economy s weak performance] and hence the greater the voter participation rate, ceteris paribus. In this study, any year in which the real GDP grows at an annual rate of less than two percent is treated as a year when real GDP is growing too slowly to prevent increases in the unemployment rate. In such years, the voter participation rate is expected to be higher, ceteris paribus. Naturally, the public s assessment of the performance of the economy could be based on more than just this single criterion. For instance, the inflation rate may be of interest to many voters. Inflation reduces the purchasing power of money and unless nominal wages/income grow more rapidly than inflation, higher inflation reduces real income. Over the study period, nominal wages/income in the U.S. on the average grew at an average annual rate of nearly five percent,

Cebula and Durden, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(2), September 2007, 1-16 7 which reflected the impacts of such factors as COLAs [cost of living adjustments], increased compensation for productivity increases and/or investment in human capital, and/or promotions. Consequently, it is hypothesized in this study that when the annual inflation rate of the CPI exceeds five percent, many eligible voters are more likely to vote in the hope of electing politicians who will pursue policies conducive to lower inflation, ceteris paribus. Voting might also serve as a means to express displeasure over the economy s excessive inflation [INFLDUM]. In either case, the expected gross benefits from voting may rise when inflation exceeds five percent per annum. Finally, there is the central concern of this study: the issue of PAC election campaign contributions, i.e., election [or re-election] campaign contributions by special interest groups, a topic that has received recent attention from Riddel (2003) and Cebula (2007), among others. This is an issue that also attracted considerable attention during the year 2000 Presidential primaries within the context of election campaign finance reform, and, arguably was less of a public concern/political issue prior to the year 2000. From the perspective of this study, given the extraordinary growth in PAC election campaign contributions over the last 30-plus years, it can be argued that such contributions might well give at least some portion of the voting public the impression of influence peddling, i.e., the impression that various special interest groups are gaining influence over elected officials and candidates through contributing funds to their election or re-election campaigns. To the extent that voters or potential voters perceive that such PAC election campaign contributions lead to influence peddling, they may infer that politicians will be more concerned with the needs, concerns, and agendas of their PAC contributors than the needs, concerns, and agendas of the actual voters per se. This argument would seem consistent with Copeland and Laband (2002, p. 358), who observe that when individuals believe they have no say in what government does, they are less likely to vote. Thus, it is hypothesized here that the greater the extent of PAC election campaign contributions, the more disenfranchised voters [or would-be voters] may feel and hence the less the degree to which they may feel inclined to make the effort to vote, ceteris paribus, i.e., some voters may adopt a why bother attitude towards voting. To test this hypothesis, it is argued that the greater the extent of real U.S. Senate PAC election campaign contributions, the lower the voter participation rate, ceteris paribus. Based on the framework described above, the EGB of voting can be described by: EGB = g(presapp/dis, PRESDUM, VIETNAM, DIS, SLOWGR, INFLDUM, PAC), g PRESAPP/DIS > 0, g PRESDUM > 0, g VIETNAM > 0, g DIS <0, g SLOWGR >0, g INFLDUM > 0, g PAC < 0 (2) The framework resulting from substituting equation (2) into equation (1) implies that the empirical investigation of determinants of the aggregate voter participation rate involves estimating the following: VPR t = a 0 + a 1 PRESAPP/DIS t + a 2 PRESDUM t + a 3 VIETNAM t + a 4 DIS t + a 5 INFLDUM t + a 6 SLOWGR t + a 7 PAC t-1 + u (3) where

Cebula and Durden, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(2), September 2007, 1-16 8 VPR t = the aggregate voter participation rate in the U.S. in year t, expressed as a percent; a 0 = constant term; PRESAPP/DIS t = a binary variable to measure strong public approval or strong public disapproval of the President in year t: PRESAPP/DIS t = 1 for those years in which the public s average approval rating of the President was either very low (39 or less out of a possible 100.0) or very high (57 or more on the same scale) and PRESAPP/DIS t = 0 otherwise; PRESDUM t = binary variable for Presidential election years: PRESDUM t = 1 during Presidential election years and PRESDUM t = 0 otherwise; VIETNAM t = a binary variable for the years during which the U.S. was militarily involved in the Vietnam War, such that VIETNAM t = 1 for those years and VIETNAM t = 0 otherwise; DIS t = the level of the public s dissatisfaction with government over year t, as measured by the dissatisfaction index, ranging from 1.5 for least dissatisfied to + 1.5 for most dissatisfied; SLOWGR t = a binary variable reflecting the annual percentage growth rate of real GDP in year t: SLOWGR t = 1 when the percentage growth rate of real GDP is less than two percent in year t and SLOWGR t = 0 when the annual percentage growth rate of real GDP is two percent or more in year t; INFLDUM t = a binary variable indicating whether in year t the annual inflation rate of the CPI exceeded five percent, such that INFLDUM t = 1 during those years and INFLDUM t = 0 otherwise; PAC t-1 =total real PAC contributions to U.S. Senate election or re-election campaigns in year t-1, expressed in millions of 1996 dollars, with the value of PAC treated as equal to zero prior to the 1971 enactment of FECA; u = stochastic error term. The study period runs from 1960-2004. The beginning date is determined by data unavailability for the DIS t variable prior to 1960. The DIS t data were obtained using the studies by Feige (1994) and Cebula and Paul (2002). The VPR t is measured only for even-numbered years. This is because even-numbered years are when all members of the U.S. House of Representatives and one-third of the U.S. Senate are elected and, on alternate even-numbered years [ leap years ] when the President also is elected. The odd-numbered years typically do not correspond to the election of large numbers of significant officials. The VPR data were obtained from the U.S. Census Bureau (2006, Table 407). The VPR and DIS variables are treated as contemporaneous because it is hypothesized here that the greater the current dissatisfaction with government the voting public currently has, the greater the degree to which said dissatisfaction will likely be reflected in current behavior. The values for PAC t-1 are assumed equal to zero until 1971, when FECA effectively opened the door for the establishment of legal PACs. The data for PAC t-1 were obtained from the U.S. Federal Election Commission (2006) and the U.S. Census Bureau (2006,

Cebula and Durden, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(2), September 2007, 1-16 9 Table 413). The data used to construct INFLDUM and SLOWGR were obtained from the Council of Economic Advisors (2006, Tables, B-64, B-2). Finally, the data reflecting the Presidential approval rating surveys were obtained from The American Presidency (2007). Augmented Dickey-Fuller and P-P [Philips-Perron] tests both confirm that the series for variables DIS t and PAC t-1 are stationary only in first differences. Hence, in the estimation provided below, these two variables are expressed in first differences. The VPR series is stationary at the five percent level in levels, reflecting in large part the rise in the voter participation rate in the year 2000 and year 2004 Presidential elections. Given that VPR t is contemporaneous with the dissatisfaction index, DIS t, the possibility of simultaneity bias exists. To account for this possibility, the model in equation (3) was estimated by 2SLS [two-stage least squares], with the instrument being the two-year lag of the maximum marginal federal personal income tax rate, MAX t-2. On economic grounds, the choice of instrument was based on the empirical findings in Cebula and Paul (2002, p. 501) that the public s dissatisfaction with government is an increasing function of the maximum marginal federal income tax rate... On technical grounds, the choice of instrument was based on the finding that DIS t and MAX t-2 are highly correlated, whereas the two-period lagged instrument is not contemporaneous with the error terms in the system. The MAX t-2 data were obtained from the IRS (2007). 3. Empirical Findings Estimating equation (3) by 2SLS, using the White (1980) heteroskedasticity correction, yields: VPR t = +37.5 + 12.8 PRESAPP/DIS t + 11.8 PRESDUM t + 12.6 VIETNAM t - 5.69 zdis t (+3.85) (+6.67) (+5.60) (-3.59) - 2.5 INFLDUM t + 1.7 SLOWGR t 45.3 zpac t-1, DW = 1.86, Rho = 0.04, F =39.55 (4) (-1.70) (+2.31) (-3.00) where terms in parentheses are t-values and z is the first differences operator. In equation (4), six of the seven estimated coefficients exhibit the hypothesized signs, with five being statistically significant at the one percent level and one being significant at the five percent level. The remaining coefficient [that for INFLDUM] fails to have the expected sign but is not significant at the ten percent level. The D-W and Rho statistics imply the absence of serial correlation problems. The F-statistic is significant at beyond the one percent level, attesting to the overall strength of the model. The estimated coefficient on the PRESAPP/DIS variable is positive and significant at the one percent level. This finding suggests, as hypothesized in this study, that when the public strongly approves or strongly disapproves of the job performance of the incumbent President, they turn out in greater numbers than otherwise would be the case to express either that strong approval or strong disapproval. Venting such feelings may generate increased benefits from voting.

Cebula and Durden, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(2), September 2007, 1-16 10 The estimated coefficient on the PRESDUM variable is positive and significant at the one percent level. This confirms the hypothesis that during Presidential election years voter participation rates increase because the outcome [s] of the election is [are] perceived as more important, so that the expected potential benefits from voting are enhanced while presumably reflecting emotions ranging from simple enthusiasm, perhaps almost reminiscent of cheerleading on the one hand to emotional responses [involving arguably greater substance] to candidate positions, the candidates themselves, or party platforms on sensitive issues such as abortion, religion, and the environment, on the other hand. Thus, possibly for multiple reasons, voting in Presidential election years may increase the expected benefit of voting. The coefficient on the VIETNAM variable is positive, as expected, and significant at the one percent level. This finding is perhaps suggestive of a strong emotional pull by the War issue of voters to the polling booths, perhaps in the hope of creating a change in U.S. policy regarding military involvement in Vietnam, i.e., the possibility of ending U.S. involvement in the Vietnam War may have increased the expected benefit/value of voting. Thus, the documented unpopularity of and controversy over the Vietnam War appears to have led to increasing voter participation. The lesson from this result may be that protracted controversial or unpopular wars are likely to induce increased voter participation [and, arguably, of a nature that on balance is anti-incumbent]. The coefficient on the variable DIS is negative, as expected, and significant at the one percent level, presumably suggesting that the more dissatisfied the voting-eligible population is with government in general and perceived government officials trustworthiness, honesty/dishonesty, and use of tax revenues, the more discouraged from participation in the voting process they become. This suggests a form of disappointment and a negative emotional reaction to even bothering to vote, i.e., the DIS variable reflects disillusionment with government [Feige (1994)] and a correspondingly diminished expected gross benefit from voting [Putnam (2000)]. As for the economic dummy variables, the coefficient on the SLOWGR variable is positive and significant at the five percent level. This result suggests that when the growth rate of real GDP is relatively slow [i.e., less than two percent per annum], eligible voters either to some extent may envision greater stakes [greater expected gross benefits] in acting to potentially help ensure the election of politicians whose economic policies may more effectively stimulate economic growth and therefore job growth and employment security and/or may simply use voting to express displeasure over slow real GDP growth. Finally, the estimated coefficient on the INFLDUM variable is negative but not significant at the ten percent level, implying that this variable may not systematically exercise a significant impact on voter turnout. It may well be that because, in addition to the costs imposed by inflation, there may be benefits to inflation, e.g., for the owners of real estate, especially those whose real estate holdings are highly leveraged, the net effect of high inflation on aggregate voter turnout is not significant. Finally, the estimated coefficient on the PAC variable is negative [as hypothesized] and significant at the one percent level. This result would seem to suggest that greater PAC campaign contributions to U.S. Senate elections [or re-elections] leads to reduced voter participation rates. This finding, if valid, might suggest that at least some eligible voters expect lower gross [and hence lower net] benefits from voting due to growing PAC election

Cebula and Durden, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(2), September 2007, 1-16 11 contributions to U.S. Senate races, arguably because they perceive elected officials engaging in influence peddling to those from whom the PAC funds flows. In other words, growing PAC contributions may lead at least some portion of potential voters to feel disenfranchised from the electoral process and the democratic institution of voting because they feel their votes will not gain them sway with their own elected officials, who are busily pandering to their PAC supporters. This finding parallels that obtained for the case of the U.S. Congress by Cebula (2007). To investigate further the voter-participation impact of the factors identified in this model, three variations on the system shown in equation (3) have been estimated by 2SLS, each adopting the White (1980) heteroskedasticity correction. The results of these estimations are provided in columns (1), (2) and (3) of Table 1. As shown in Table 1, 13 of the 17 coefficients are statistically significant with the expected signs at the one percent level, whereas the three of the remaining four coefficients are significant with the expected signs at the five percent level or beyond. Of particular interest is the pattern of results wherein the estimated coefficient on the PAC variable is statistically significant at an acceptable level in all three of these estimates. In sum, then, it appears that the voter participation rate in this expanded rational voter model has been found to be an increasing function of strong public approval or strong public disapproval of the incumbent President, the opportunity to participate in a Presidential election, the Vietnam War [possibly as a surrogate for a protracted unpopular or at least highly controversial war], and possibly a too slowly growing real GDP. Furthermore, and from the perspective of this study, most importantly, the voter participation rate appears to be a decreasing function of the public s dissatisfaction with government and the growth in real PAC Senate election campaign contributions. 4. Conclusion This study has endeavored to identify key aggregate-level determinants of the expected benefits from voting and hence key aggregate voter participation rate determinants in the U.S. so as to help improve understanding of and forecasting of voter turnout. It also has especially focused on the voter-turnout impact of growing real PAC contributions to U.S. Senate election [or reelection] campaigns. Using aggregate time series covering the period 1960-2004, this study has obtained several significant results. First, the voter participation rate tends to be higher when the public either strongly approves or strongly disapproves of the job the President is perceived as doing while in office. Second, the opportunity to vote in a Presidential election appears to induce a greater voter turnout. Third, the greater the public s dissatisfaction with government, i.e., (1) the greater the degree to which the public doubts that government officials can be trusted, (2) the more the public feels government officials are dishonest, and (3) the greater the extent to which the public feels that government wastes tax dollars, the lower the voter participation rate. Fourth, the Vietnam War had a positive and significant impact on voter participation. This issue may have galvanized an otherwise potentially somewhat free-riding, somewhat apathetic public into a voter coalition with a greater propensity to vote in order to promote a specific agenda. This particular finding may be capable of being generalized into a rule of thumb by which it is possible to

Cebula and Durden, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(2), September 2007, 1-16 12 conjecture that any protracted, unpopular war might act to elicit greater voter turnout. Clearly, this factor could yet potentially imply marginally important voter turnout developments in the U.S. in terms of the War in Iraq. 12 Until hostilities involving the U.S. military in Iraq and the Iraqi occupation are both completed, however, this issue may not be ready to be fully investigated in an unbiased fashion. This is all the more true since there is a milieu involving terrorism against the U.S. beginning with September 11, 2001, within which the Iraqi issue must be interpreted. Next, on the purely economics side, there is at least some evidence that if the economy is growing too slowly, voter turnout may increase, presumably to elicit a change towards more stimulatory government economic policies. Finally, and from the perspective of this study, most relevantly, it would appear that the growth of real PAC Senate election campaign contributions has led to a reduction in voter turnout, possibly because such contributions may lead voters to feel politically disenfranchised and to experience a decline or loss in expected benefits from voting, perhaps in the form of expected lost influence over elected officials. In other words, it appears that when individuals believe they have less say in what government does than PACs do, they are less inclined to vote. The findings in this study strongly reinforce the wisdom in achieving genuine and fundamental campaign finance reform in order to strengthen and protect the democratic process in the U.S. Footnotes * Shirley and Philip Solomons Eminent Scholar, Department of Economics, Armstrong Atlantic State University, and Professor Emeritus, Department of Economics, Appalachian State University, respectively. 1. This legislation was entitled the Naval Appropriations Bill of 1867. 2. This de facto extension of the Naval Appropriations Bill of 1867 came in the form of the Civil Service Reform Act of 1883. 3. This statute was the Tillman Act [1907]. 4. This legislation came in the form of the Federal Corrupt Practices Act [1910]. 5. The statute in this case was the Federal Corrupt Practices Act [Revised]. 6. Other potentially useful campaign finance statutes were enacted between 1925 and 1971, including the Hatch Act Amendments [1940] and the Smith-Connally Act [1943]. 7. The very first PAC was actually formed by the CIO in 1944 in its effort to support the reelection of President Franklin Roosevelt. Since the funds were derived from voluntary union member contributions as opposed to the union s treasury, the Smith-Connally Act was not violated. 8. This framework applied to primaries, run-offs, and final elections.

Cebula and Durden, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(2), September 2007, 1-16 13 9. In 1971, Congress also enacted the Revenue Act to supplement FECA. 10. These laws were simply FECA Amendments [1976] and, in 1979, more FECA Amendments. 11. Related to this statute, the reader is referred to the 1976 Supreme Court decision in Buckley v. Valeo 12.The results of the 2006 general election in which (a) the aggregate voter turnout was thehighest it had been in a non-presidential election cycle in over a decade and (b) the Democrats secured majorities in both the U.S. Senate and U.S. House could be interpreted as reflecting just such a public reaction to a protracted and unpopular war. References Ashenfelter, O. and S. Kelley, Jr. 1975. Determinants of Participation in Presidential Elections, Journal of Law and Economics, 18(4), 695-733. Barreto, M. A., G. M. Segura, and N. D. Woods. 2004. The Mobilizing Effect of Majority- Minority Districts on Latino Turnout, American Political Science Review, 98(1), 65-76. Black, D. 1958. The Theory of Committees and Elections, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Brazel, Y. and E. Silberberg. 1973. Is the Act of Voting Rational? Public Choice, 16(1), 51-58. Buchanan, J. M. and G. Tullock. 1962. The Calculus of Consent, Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. Cebula, R. J. 2004, Expressive Voting: Alternative Evidence, Atlantic Economic Journal, 32 (3), 216-221. Cebula, R. J. 2007. PAC Congressional Election Campaign Contributions and Other Political or Economic Influences on the Voter Participation Rate, American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 66(2), 399-412. Cebula, R. J. and C. Paul. 2002. A Note on Determinants of Public Dissatisfaction with Government: Economic and Political Factors Affecting the Public s Attitude toward Government, American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 61(2), 495-501. Copeland, C. and D. Laband. 2002. Expressive Voting, Public Choice, 110(3), 351-363. Council of Economic Advisors. 2006. Economic Report of the President, 2006, Washington, D.C: U.S. Government Printing Office.

Cebula and Durden, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(2), September 2007, 1-16 14 Cox, G. W. and M. C. Munger. 1989. Closeness, Expenditures, and Turnout in 1982 U.S. House Elections, American Political Science Review, 83(1), 217-231. Dobra, J. and G. Tullock. 1981. An Approach to Empirical Measures of Voting Paradoxes, Public Choice, 36(2), 193-194. Downs, A. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy, New York: Harper and Row. Durden, G. 1991. Determining the Classics in Social Choice, Public Choice, 69(3), 265-277. Feddersen, T. J. 2004. Rational Choice Theory and the Paradox of Not Voting, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(1), 99-112. Feige, E. 1994. The Underground Economy and the Currency Enigma, Public Finance/Finances Publiques, 49(1), 119-136. Green, D. P. and I. Shapiro. 1994. Pathologies of Rational Choice Theory: A Critique of Applications in Political Science, New Haven: Yale University Press. Greene, K. V. and O. Nikolaev. 1999. Voter Participation and the Redistributive State, Public Choice, 98(1-2), 213-226. Internal Revenue Service. 2007. www.irs.gov Knack, S. 1999. Drivers Wanted: Motor Voter and the Election of 1996, P.S.: Political Science and Politics, 32(1), 237-243. Lapp, M. 1999. Incorporating Groups into Rational Choice Explanations of Turnout: An Empirical Test, Public Choice, 98(2), 171-185. Musgrave, R. 1959. The Theory of Public Finance, New York: McGraw-Hill. Piven, F. F. and R. A. Cloward. 1988. Why Americans Don t Vote, New York: Pantheon Books. Putnam, R. D. 2000. Bowling Alone, New York: Simon & Schuster. Riddel, M. 2003. Candidate Eco-labeling and Senate Campaign Contributions, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 45(2), 177-194. Riker, W. H. and P. C. Ordeshook. 1968. A Theory to the Calculus of Voting, American Political Science Review, 62(1), 25-42. Schwartz, T. 1987. Your Vote Counts on Account of the Way It Is Counted: An Institutional Solution to the Paradox of Voting, Public Choice, 54(1), 101-121.

Cebula and Durden, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(2), September 2007, 1-16 15 Teixeira, R. 1992. The Disappearing American Voter, Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution. The American Presidency. (2007). www.theamericanpresidency.us/. Tullock, G. 1977. Demand Revealing Processes, Coalitions, and Public Goods, Public Choice, 29 (1), 103-105. Tullock, G. 1998. On Voting: A Public Choice Approach, Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar. Tullock, G. 2006. Some Thoughts on the Voting Process, Atlantic Economic Journal, 34(1), 41-46. Tullock, G. 1967. Towards a Mathematics of Politics, Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. U.S. Census Bureau. 2006. Statistical Abstract of the United States, 2006, Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office. U.S. Federal Election Commission. 2006. FEC Reports on Financial Activity, Party and Non- Party Political Committees, Final Report, Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office. White, H. 1980. A Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator and a Direct Test for Heteroskedasticity, Econometrica, 48(4), 817-838.

Cebula and Durden, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(2), September 2007, 1-16 16 Table 1. Alternative 2SLS Estimations Variable Estimation (1) Estimation (2) Estimation (3) Constant +36.6 +37.72 +36.74 PRESAPP/DIS +13.86*** +13.61*** +14.04*** (+4.34) (+4.24) (+4.23) PRESDUM +11.01*** +11.23*** +10.89*** (+6.20) (+6.26) (+6.28) VIETNAM +12.18*** +12.37*** +12.15*** (+4.93) (+5.25) (+4.94) zdis -59.27*** -57.91*** -59.39*** (-3.88) (-3.58) (-3.85) zpac -4.77** -5.05*** -4.92** (-2.82) (-3.39) (-2.90) SLOWGR +1.45* (+2.30) INFLDUM -1.79 (-1.42) DW 1.88 1.92 1.90 Rho 0.04 0.01 0.02 Terms in parentheses are t-values. ***Statistically significant at the one percent level. **Statistically significant at the 2.5 percent level. *Statistically significant at the five percent level.