Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different?

Similar documents
Migration Policy and Welfare State in Europe

POLICY Volume 5, Issue 8 October RETHINKING THE EFFECTS OF IMMIGRATION ON WAGES: New Data and Analysis from by Giovanni Peri, Ph.D.

The Wage Effects of Immigration and Emigration

ISSUE BRIEF: U.S. Immigration Priorities in a Global Context

Complementarities between native and immigrant workers in Italy by sector.

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications

The Impact of Foreign Workers on the Labour Market of Cyprus

IMPLICATIONS OF WAGE BARGAINING SYSTEMS ON REGIONAL DIFFERENTIATION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION LUMINITA VOCHITA, GEORGE CIOBANU, ANDREEA CIOBANU

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS INTO THE LABOUR MARKET IN EU AND OECD COUNTRIES

Migration and the European Job Market Rapporto Europa 2016

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS & ECONOMETRICS. A Capital Mistake? The Neglected Effect of Immigration on Average Wages

Voter Turnout, Income Inequality, and Redistribution. Henning Finseraas PhD student Norwegian Social Research

NERO INTEGRATION OF REFUGEES (NORDIC COUNTRIES) Emily Farchy, ELS/IMD

How does education affect the economy?

The Labor Market Impact of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University October 2006

Economics of European Integration Lecture # 6 Migration and Growth

ISBN International Migration Outlook Sopemi 2007 Edition OECD Introduction

BRIEFING. International Migration: The UK Compared with other OECD Countries.

Income inequality the overall (EU) perspective and the case of Swedish agriculture. Martin Nordin

Inclusive global growth: a framework to think about the post-2015 agenda

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009

The globalization of inequality

International Migration and the Welfare State. Prof. Panu Poutvaara Ifo Institute and University of Munich

Upgrading workers skills and competencies: policy strategies

Inclusion and Gender Equality in China

Economics Of Migration

Commission on Growth and Development Cognitive Skills and Economic Development

Aid spending by Development Assistance Committee donors in 2015

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

Regional Wage Differentiation and Wage Bargaining Systems in the EU

EDUCATION OUTCOMES EXPENDITURE ON EDUCATION INTERNATIONAL STUDENT ASSESSMENT TERTIARY ATTAINMENT

Taiwan s Development Strategy for the Next Phase. Dr. San, Gee Vice Chairman Taiwan External Trade Development Council Taiwan

Immigration Reform, Economic Growth, and the Fiscal Challenge Douglas Holtz- Eakin l April 2013

Does Immigration Reduce Wages?

The effect of a generous welfare state on immigration in OECD countries

UNDER EMBARGO UNTIL 9 APRIL 2018, 15:00 HOURS PARIS TIME

OECD Health Data 2009 comparing health statistics across OECD countries

Globalisation and flexicurity

Estimating the foreign-born population on a current basis. Georges Lemaitre and Cécile Thoreau

The educational tracks and integration of immigrants reducing blind spots Planning director Kirsi Kangaspunta

Political Skill and the Democratic Politics of Investment Protection

The Transmission of Economic Status and Inequality: U.S. Mexico in Comparative Perspective

An anatomy of inclusive growth in Europe*

GLOBALIZATION AND THE GREAT U-TURN: INCOME INEQUALITY TRENDS IN 16 OECD COUNTRIES. Arthur S. Alderson

Comparative Political Economy. David Soskice Nuffield College

Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries

The Impact of Immigration on Wages of Unskilled Workers

Russian Federation. OECD average. Portugal. United States. Estonia. New Zealand. Slovak Republic. Latvia. Poland

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Discussion comments on Immigration: trends and macroeconomic implications

The Labor Market Impact of Immigration: Recent Research. George J. Borjas Harvard University April 2010

The evolution of turnout in European elections from 1979 to 2009

Size and Development of the Shadow Economy of 31 European and 5 other OECD Countries from 2003 to 2013: A Further Decline

Is This Time Different? The Opportunities and Challenges of Artificial Intelligence

New Approaches to Measuring the Impacts of STI Policy

CO3.6: Percentage of immigrant children and their educational outcomes

LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES

GDP per capita was lowest in the Czech Republic and the Republic of Korea. For more details, see page 3.

Context Indicator 17: Population density

BUILDING RESILIENT REGIONS FOR STRONGER ECONOMIES OECD

Labor Market Policy Core Course: Creating Jobs in a Post- Crisis World. March 28- April 8, 2011 Washington, D.C. -- World Bank HQ- Room I2-250

Immigration and property prices: Evidence from England and Wales

Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany

Employment Outlook 2017

The WTO Trade Effect and Political Uncertainty: Evidence from Chinese Exports

Regional inequality and the impact of EU integration processes. Martin Heidenreich

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IMMIGRATION, JOBS AND EMPLOYMENT PROTECTION: EVIDENCE FROM EUROPE. Francesco D'Amuri Giovanni Peri

USING, DEVELOPING, AND ACTIVATING THE SKILLS OF IMMIGRANTS AND THEIR CHILDREN

The Changing Relationship between Fertility and Economic Development: Evidence from 256 Sub-National European Regions Between 1996 to 2010

Does Immigration Harm Native-Born Workers? A Citizen's Guide

World changes in inequality:

OECD/EU INDICATORS OF IMMIGRANT INTEGRATION: Findings and reflections

The task-specialization hypothesis and possible productivity effects of immigration

INEQUALITY AND POVERTY IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE

Appendix to Sectoral Economies

Economic Growth & Welfare Systems. Jean Monnet Chair in European Integration Studies Prof. PASQUALE TRIDICO

Immigration and the US Wage Distribution: A Literature Review

The Mystery of Economic Growth by Elhanan Helpman. Chiara Criscuolo Centre for Economic Performance London School of Economics

REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY

George J. Borjas Harvard University. September 2008

Tax Competition and Migration: The Race-to-the-Bottom Hypothesis Revisited

Comparative Economic Development

Exposure to Immigrants and Voting on Immigration Policy: Evidence from Switzerland

How Country Reputation affects investment attraction Italy and its «effective government» growing perception

How many students study abroad and where do they go?

Globalization and Inequality : a brief review of facts and arguments

Europe and the US: Preferences for Redistribution

The Labor Market Effects of Immigration and Emigration in. OECD Countries

Migration and Labor Market Outcomes in Sending and Southern Receiving Countries

Discussion Paper Series

UK Productivity Gap: Skills, management and innovation

Chapter 2 Comparative Economic Development

The Israeli Economy: Current Trends, Strength and Challenges

Fafo-Conference One year after Oslo, 26 th of May, Migration, Co-ordination Failures and Eastern Enlargement

WORLDWIDE DISTRIBUTION OF PRIVATE FINANCIAL ASSETS

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

The High Cost of Low Educational Performance. Eric A. Hanushek Ludger Woessmann

Transcription:

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different? Zachary Mahone and Filippo Rebessi August 25, 2013 Abstract Using cross country data from the OECD, we document that variation in immigration variables across member states is significantly larger than the variation of a wide range of economic indicators. We propose a benchmark model in which a social planner chooses immigration policy to maximize the utility of native-born agents. We study how restrictions in tax policy instruments interact with inequality among the native-born to generate dispersion in optimal immigration policies across countries. We extend the analysis to consider two specific policies: family reunification and an immigration tariff. Finally, we compare the optimal policy with a politico-economic equilibrium studied in the literature by Razin et al. (2011). Keywords: Immigration, Fiscal Policy, Redistribution, Taxation 1

Extended Abstract Yearly net migration to OECD countries has nearly tripled in the last 30 years 1. However, immigrant population and policy is hardly uniform across member states. For example, while the US foreign-born population is over-represented at the lower levels of education, immigrants in Canada tend to be over-represented among tertiary education achievers. At the same time, while in the US about 32% of immigrants obtaining permanent residence in 2003 did so through family reunification programs, this percentage was only around 2% for the UK 1. Why is immigration so different across fairly similar economies? Which immigration policy would a social planner choose in these countries? This paper answers these questions. First, we use the OECD s International Migration Outlook tables to document differences in immigrant populations across member countries. Second, we develop a static model in which an unrestricted social planner chooses the size and distribution of the immigrant population. Agents are heterogeneous in their skill level; following Katz and Murphy (1992), hours provided by heterogeneous workers are aggregated as complementary factors in total hours worked in the economy. Using data on labor, capital and output, we compare the differences between efficient immigration policies implied by the model to what we observe in the data. We then investigate how optimal immigration policy changes when the government is constrained to make transfers unconditional on nativity status or skill level, financed through linear taxes. The intuition behind why optimal policy might change is that the planner may not able to redistribute the net benefits of immigration from low income earners to high income earners. An influx of high-skilled immigrants requires this kind of redistribution in order to be accepted by high-skilled natives. Consequently, economies characterized by high initial dispersion of income across skills will tend to reject influxes of high-skilled immigrants, while more egalitarian economies won t. In support of this prediction, we find in the data a negative correlation between the pre-tax gini coefficient and the fraction of high-skilled immigrants. In the final sections we use our framework to consider two specific migration policies: family reunification and an immigration tariff. This work is related to the contributions of Borjas (2003), Borjas and Katz (2007) and Ottaviano and Peri (2006). These papers offer estimates of the impact of immigration on wages in the US economy. We complement their approach by characterizing the set of feasible immigration policies in the limiting case in which immigrants and natives are perfect substitutes. The key point we make is that, in order to evaluate current immigration policy, it is crucial to consider the interaction between the instruments that are available to redistribute the net gains of immigration and the policy s feasibility in terms of voluntary participation by agents. When looking at OECD data, we divide the population in two broad educational attainment groups, as it is standard in the literature 2 ; in the data, we define high skilled agents as those who have completed tertiary education according to the 1997 ISCED 3 classification. We measure the variation across member states of the ratio of immigrants to total population and of the difference in educational attainment of native population and immigrant population. We compare the coefficient of variation (c v 4 ) of these variables with the coefficient of variation of GDP per capita and other economic indicators. We find the following: 1 Source: OECD Migration Outlook 2006 2 See Katz and Murphy (1992), Krusell et al. (2000) and Caselli and Coleman (2006), for example 3 International Standard Classification of Education, Unesco 4 The coefficient of variation represents the standard deviation as a proportion of the arithmetic mean. It is widely used to compare distributions with different means 2

1. The c v of the ratio of immigrants to total population is about 3 times bigger than GNI per capita s c v 2. The c v of the difference in educational attainment is about 14 times bigger than GNI per capita s c v 3. When we focus on a subset of countries that control migration from source countries 5, the 2 previous facts are intact % High Skilled Difference Foreign-Born GNI Country Foreign Native HS F B Population Per Capita Born Born HS NB Ratio (%) PPP Australia 35.8 26.2 9.6 23.6 28960 Austria 18.6 18.0 0.6 13 31020 Belgium 25.4 29.6-4.1 11.4 30760 Canada 46.1 38.8 7.3 18 30500 Denmark 37.9 31.7 6.2 6.3 30250 Finland 27.8 33.6-5.8 3.2 27420 France 21.1 23.6-2.5 10 27470 Germany 18.9 25.5-6.6 13 28120 Greece 19.4 19.6-0.2 10.3 22400 Ireland 45.4 25.5 19.9 11 29740 Italy 11.3 11.1 0.2 2.5 27090 Netherlands 24.2 25.0-0.8 10.6 32070 New Zealand 37.6 32.3 5.3 18.8 22400 Norway 36.4 31.2 5.2 7.8 38520 Portugal 22.2 10.8 11.4 6.7 19280 Spain 29.8 25.4 4.4 5.3 24480 Sweden 29.6 27.3 2.3 12.2 30810 Switzerland 27.6 27.6 0.0 23.5 37070 United Kingdom 34.3 29.3 5.0 9.3 30150 USA 35.0 39.9-4.9 12.8 38400 c v = σ µ 0.32 0.29 2.48 0.51 0.17 Table 1: Differences in Educational Attainment and Relative Size of Immigrant Population across OECD Countries, Year 2003/2004 We also consider alternative measures of economic activity, such as GDP per capita, GNI per worker and Capital Output Ratios (taken from Caselli (2007) and Klenow and Hsieh (2010)). Our findings are robust to these alternative measures. In the model we develop, economic immigration policy is specified as an augmentation in the proportion of skilled and unskilled workers (later extended to include the fraction of this augmentation devoted to family reunifications). The social planner is constrained to make native-born agents at least as well off as in the competitive equilibrium without immigration. Costs and benefits of an influx of immigrants are respectively due to the decreasing returns and the complementarities of the two labor inputs. Potentially, the optimal immigration policy depends on the welfare weights of the objective function 5 For most of the OECD countries in the sample, a significant part of entries is enabled by free mobility agreements. We adopt the definition of the OECD Secretariat of discretionary immigration and focus on the countries for which at least 50% of the 2006 inflow of permanent immigrants was classified as discretionary: Australia, Canada, New Zealand, UK, USA 3

of the planner. In our specification, the optimal policy is independent of the welfare weights when the social planner can use lump sump transfers. In other words, the optimal policy is to admit any immigrant that brings positive net benefits to total welfare. When we limit the planner to use a linear tax on labor income to finance a non-contingent transfer, we show that immigration policy depends on the initial competitive equilibrium allocation. An immigration influx with positive net benefits might be rejected in some economies and allowed in others. A question very close to ours is studied by Razin et al. (2011). They analyze the joint determination of redistributive public spending and immigration policy in a politico-economic equilibrium. Their approach is positive; one of their results is that immigration policy sharply changes as the decisive voter switches from one skill group to another: whatever group represents the majority will restrict the influx of competing workers. Our paper, on the other hand, is about what a government should do when choosing immigration and redistributive policies. Moreover, comparing the unrestricted and constrained efficient policies allows us to highlight the forces underlying the politico-economic equilibria in these types of models. With that insight we then ask what types of additional policies work to relax the constrained problem. References [1] Borjas, George. The Labor Demand Curve is Downward Sloping: Reexamining the Impact of Immigration on the Labor Market. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 118-4 (2003): 1335-1374. [2] Borjas, George, and Katz, Lawrence F. The Evolution of the Mexican-Born Workforce in the United States. in Mexican Immigration to the United States. National Bureau of Economic Research Conference Report, Cambridge Ma (2007) [3] Caselli, Francesco. The Marginal Product of Capital. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 122-2 (2007): 535-568. [4] Caselli, Francesco and Coleman, Wilibur J. II. The World Technology Frontier American Economic Review 96-3 (2006): 499-522. [5] Katz, Lawrence F., and Murphy, Kevin M. Changes in Relative Wages, 1963-1987: Supply and Demand Factors. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 107-1 (1992): 35-78. [6] Klenov, Pete and Hsieh, Chang-Tai. Development Accounting American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2 (2010): 207-223. [7] Krusell, Per; Ohanian, Lee E.; Ros-Rull, Jose -Victor; and Violante, Giovanni L. Capital- Skill Complementarity and Inequality: A Macroeconomic Analysis. Econometrica, 68-5 (2000): 1029-1054. [8] Ottaviano, Gianmarco, and Peri, Giovanni. Rethinking the Effect of Immigration on Wages. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 12496 (2006) [9] Razin, Assaf; Sadka, Efraim; and Suwankiri, Benjarong. Migration and the Welfare State. MIT Press. 2011 4

[10] International Migration Outlook 2006. OECD Publishing. 2006 [11] International Migration Outlook 2007. OECD Publishing. 2007 5