Party Identification and Party Choice

Similar documents
Party Identification and the Vote. Six European Countries Compared

Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate

The Effect of Political Trust on the Voter Turnout of the Lower Educated

Issue Importance and Performance Voting. *** Soumis à Political Behavior ***

Political Integration of Immigrants: Insights from Comparing to Stayers, Not Only to Natives. David Bartram

Chapter 6. Party loyalties

Value Orientations and Party Choice - A Comparative Longitudinal Study of Five Countries

Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization

Party identification, electoral utilities, and voting choice

Social Attitudes and Value Change

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

Cover Page. The handle holds various files of this Leiden University dissertation.

Economic Voting Theory. Lidia Núñez CEVIPOL_Université Libre de Bruxelles

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski

Political or Institutional Disaffection? Testing New Survey Indicators for the Emerging Political Involvement of Youth

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Cohort, Life-Cycle and Period Effects in a Period. of Partisan Dealignment

The Polarization of Public Opinion about Competence

CSES Module 5 Pretest Report: Greece. August 31, 2016

This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and

Georg Lutz, Nicolas Pekari, Marina Shkapina. CSES Module 5 pre-test report, Switzerland

Citizens representation in the 2009 European Parliament elections

Partisan Sorting and Niche Parties in Europe

'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas?

The Demography of the Labor Force in Emerging Markets

Party and Leader Effects in Parliamentary Elections: Towards a Reassessment

Personality traits and party identification over time

Turnout and Strength of Habits

Congruence in Political Parties

Social Change and the Evolution of the British Electorate

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

Voter Turnout, Income Inequality, and Redistribution. Henning Finseraas PhD student Norwegian Social Research

Who says elections in Ghana are free and fair?

The effects of party membership decline

CASTLES, Francis G. (Edit.). The impact of parties: politics and policies in democratic capitalist states. Sage Publications, 1982.

Do parties and voters pursue the same thing? Policy congruence between parties and voters on different electoral levels

Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy?

From Consensus to Competition? Ideological Alternatives on the EU Dimension

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

% & '!%!(%) *+,-,./01,.112

Retrospective Voting

PERCEPTIONS OF CORRUPTION OVER TIME

Failed promises of modernization: Religion, Postmaterialism and Ethnonationalist attitudes in the Netherlands

CSI Brexit 2: Ending Free Movement as a Priority in the Brexit Negotiations

Developing Political Preferences: Citizen Self-Interest

- IPSA World Congress 2016, Poznan - RC Playing the Multilevel Game: Federalism and the Articulation of Power

THE EMOTIONAL LEGACY OF BREXIT: HOW BRITAIN HAS BECOME A COUNTRY OF REMAINERS AND LEAVERS

Supplementary/Online Appendix for:

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One

Part. The Methods of Political Science. Part

Personalization of Politics and Electoral Change in Western Europe (*)

Indifference and Alienation. Diverging Dimensions of Electoral Dealignment in Europe

Religious Voting and Class Voting in. 24 European Countries. A Comparative Study

Corruption as an obstacle to women s political representation: Evidence from local councils in 18 European countries

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences

Comparing Foreign Political Systems Focus Questions for Unit 1

Attitudes towards influx of immigrants in Korea

Ina Schmidt: Book Review: Alina Polyakova The Dark Side of European Integration.

Bachelorproject 2 The Complexity of Compliance: Why do member states fail to comply with EU directives?

Politics A disengaged Britain? Political interest and participation over 30 years

Does Owner-Occupied Housing Affect Neighbourhood Crime?

SHOULD THE DEMOCRATS MOVE TO THE LEFT ON ECONOMIC POLICY? By Andrew Gelman and Cexun Jeffrey Cai Columbia University

Does Political Knowledge Erode Party Attachments?: The Moderating Role of the Media Environment in the Cognitive Mobilization Hypothesis

Social divisions defining voting behavior: impact of cleavages on party choice

Asking about social circles improves election predictions

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 6: An Examination of Iowa Absentee Voting Since 2000

Progressives in Alberta

What factors are responsible for the distribution of responsibilities between the state, social partners and markets in ALMG? (covered in part I)

Perceptions of Corruption in Mass Publics

Polimetrics. Mass & Expert Surveys

The role of Social Cultural and Political Factors in explaining Perceived Responsiveness of Representatives in Local Government.

Three aspects of political sophistication - which one can be blamed for generating bias?

And Yet it Moves: The Effect of Election Platforms on Party. Policy Images

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

Appendix for: The Electoral Implications. of Coalition Policy-Making

Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts:

The fundamental factors behind the Brexit vote

Attitudes towards minority groups in the European Union

A Perpetuating Negative Cycle: The Effects of Economic Inequality on Voter Participation. By Jenine Saleh Advisor: Dr. Rudolph

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group

Elections and Voting Behaviour. The Political System of the United Kingdom

Where Else Does Turnout Decline Come From? Education, Age, Generation and Period Effects in Three European Countries

The Centre for European and Asian Studies

The Influence of Turnout of the Results of the Referendum to Amend the Constitution to include a clause on the Rights of the Unborn

Democratic Support among Youth in Some East Asian Countries

No. 1. THE ROLE OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION IN MAINTAINING HUNGARY S POPULATION SIZE BETWEEN WORKING PAPERS ON POPULATION, FAMILY AND WELFARE

THE ROLE OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION IN MAINTAINING THE POPULATION SIZE OF HUNGARY BETWEEN LÁSZLÓ HABLICSEK and PÁL PÉTER TÓTH

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES,

MODELLING EXISTING SURVEY DATA FULL TECHNICAL REPORT OF PIDOP WORK PACKAGE 5

campaign spending, which may raise the profile of an election and lead to a wider distribution of political information;

Dietlind Stolle 2011 Marc Hooghe. Shifting Inequalities. Patterns of Exclusion and Inclusion in Emerging Forms of Political Participation.

Political socialization: change and stability in political attitudes among and within age cohorts

Agnieszka Pawlak. Determinants of entrepreneurial intentions of young people a comparative study of Poland and Finland

Title: Religious Differences in Wome n s Fertility and Labour Force Participation in France Nitzan Peri-Rotem

3Z 3 STATISTICS IN FOCUS eurostat Population and social conditions 1995 D 3

Income Inequality as a Political Issue: Does it Matter?

Colorado 2014: Comparisons of Predicted and Actual Turnout

Executive summary 2013:2

Migration to and from the Netherlands

Transcription:

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 105 31.1.2005 7:52am 5 Party Identification and Party Choice Frode Berglund, Sören Holmberg, Hermann Schmitt, and Jacques Thomassen 5.1 INTRODUCTION In Chapter 4 we found a decline of the impact of traditional cleavage structures on people s party choice, although this decline is less secular than often assumed. As the strong and lasting relationship between social structure on the one hand and people s political loyalties on the other used to be one of the most essential factors of stability in most European democracies, this development might be a threat to political stability. However, social roots are not the only possible basis for enduring party preferences. An alternative is the direct psychological attachment to a particular party. In the Michigan tradition of electoral research, party identification has the function of ensuring people s lasting attachment to a political party. In the original orthodox view party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with one s preferred political party. As such it is even comparable with religious affiliation (Miller and Shanks 1996: 120). Soon after its introduction the analytical usefulness of the concept of party identification in European electoral research became a matter of dispute. In European elections, party identification and party vote tended to coincide and to change in tandem. Thus, one of the most innovative elements of the use of party identification in electoral research, studying the impact of short-term forces on the vote against the baseline of the normal vote, was hardly applicable in the European context (Butler and Stokes 1969; Kaase 1976; Thomassen 1976). However, why this was the case was a matter of dispute. Paradoxically, one interpretation of why at least the directional component of the concept was less useful in the European context compared to the American, was that party identification was much more powerful in Europe than in the United States. In European parliamentary systems, political parties and not individual politicians are the principal actors in the interaction between voters and governmental institutions, leaving little leeway for individual candidates to run their own campaign for office and offering little incentives for voters to deviate from their party preference in favour of an

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 106 31.1.2005 7:52am 106 Berglund et al. individual candidate from another party. This is quite different from US politics, in particular in presidential elections, where policy stands and characteristics of the candidates have an important weight in addition to their party background. In a parliamentary democracy with its indirect election of the head of government a split of party identification and the actual vote is less likely. Therefore, it is quite understandable that people in Europe hardly deviate from their party identification. However, this does not prove that party identification is not important. Quite the contrary, it is so important that it dominates all other considerations. Still, if there is hardly a difference between people s party identification and their party choice the analytical usefulness of the directional component of party identification is quite limited (Holmberg 1994), even if party identification is more stable than the vote (Berglund 2000). According to a different interpretation of the same phenomenon the measurement of party identification in a European context reflects not much more than people s party preference at a particular point in time. According to the functional model of party identification (Shively 1979) this is because party identification is less functional to European than US voters. In this view, party identification is a cost saving device providing people with a short cut to all kinds of decisions, including the decision for which party or candidate to vote. However, European voters might not have needed party identification as a cost saving device, because that function was already fulfilled by people s ties to a social class or religion, which in turn were strongly associated with a particular political party. Under these conditions, expressed partisanship will be synonymous with the vote and parties as such will not serve as guides to organize behaviour. Whichever the correct, interpretation it is of no consequence for this chapter. In both interpretations the usefulness of the directional component of party identification is rather limited as long as party identification and party choice almost coincide. To what extent is this is one of the research questions to be answered in this chapter. The second dimension of the concept of party identification, the strength or intensity component, has never been controversial. There is a general agreement that a variable measuring degree of party attachment is quite useful, no matter how we interpret party identification (Holmberg 1994: 101). As strength of party identification is related to the stability of party choice, both at the individual and the aggregate level, the evolution of the level of party identification is indicative for the stability of the party system. The logical extension of the argument behind the functional model might be that once the importance of the traditional cleavage structure declines and voters are deprived of their traditional short-cutting device, they will develop an identification with a particular party in the same way as their American counterparts do. In other words, party identification should not necessarily decline in the slipstream of the decline of the relationship between social structure and party system.

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 107 31.1.2005 7:52am Party Identification and Party Choice 107 AQ1 However, it is the very same functional theory that contradicts this prediction. The need for an information cost-saving device is supposed to be a function of the political skills of the voters. Modernization and in particular the cognitive mobilization of citizens have increased these skills. The dramatic spread of education in advanced industrial democracies has produced a qualitative change in the political sophistication of citizens. At the same time, these societies have experienced an information explosion through the mass media. Both developments have led to a substantial decrease of information costs. Because of this cognitive mobilization, more voters now are able to deal with the complexities of politics and make their own political decisions. Thus, the functional need for partisan cues to guide voting behaviour is declining for a growing number of citizens (Dalton 1984). As a consequence, we should expect a decline in the level of party identification. In principle, testing this hypothesis requires not more than an assessment of the development of the level of party identification over time. The hypothesis predicts a secular decline of party identification in advanced industrial democracies. An advantage of the selection of countries in our study is that all six are advanced industrial democracies at about the same level of development. Modernization theory therefore would predict a more or less similar secular decline of party identification in all six countries. This hypothesis will be tested in Section 5.2. However, even if the development of the level of party identification is consistent with what the theory of modernization predicts, this does not necessarily prove that this development is caused by the mechanisms supposed in functional theory. This theory is based on specific assumptions at the micro-level, which are anything but uncontested (Barton and Döring 1986). In Section 5.3 we will elaborate these assumptions and test to what extent the assumed relations at the micro-level do exist in our data. The theory of modernization tries to explain changes in politics based on developments in society. As such one might call it a sociological approach, devoid of a political component in the explanans. As a reaction to this apolitical approach, an alternative explanation of the development of party identification has been proposed emphasizing developments in the political context, in particular in the supply side of politics, rather than social changes. Schmitt and Holmberg (1995) for instance introduce and test the hypothesis that developments and fluctuations in the level of party identification can be explained by simultaneous fluctuations in the level of polarization and the degree of issue conflict between political parties. This approach does not necessarily lead to different predictions than the theory of modernization. In the early end of ideology debate a gradual decline of ideological political differences was predicted as a logical consequence of the decrease of the importance of the cleavage structure. As far as the decline in the level of party identification is a consequence of such a gradual depolarization, it should be a secular decline, just as predicted by the theory of modernization. However, polarization can fluctuate from one election to the other and differ

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 108 31.1.2005 7:52am 108 Berglund et al. across countries at the same level of modernization. Therefore, in contrast to the theory of modernization, it can explain non-linear fluctuations in the level of party identification. In Section 5.4 we will further discuss this theoretical perspective and test it. Section 5.5 is devoted to party identification as an independent variable: Has modernization and/or a possible decrease in ideological polarization made it less closely tied to the vote? 5.2 THE EVOLUTION OF PARTY IDENTIFICATION The question whether or not a secular decline in the level of party identification has occurred in advanced industrial democracies and whether modernization is an underlying cause of decline, has been the subject of several previous comparative studies. Schmitt and Holmberg (1995), having studied the developments in fourteen West European countries and the United States until 1992, came to the conclusion: If there is an overall tendency, it is of loosening party bonds. But specific developments, by country and party, are so varied that any general overall view disguises more than it discloses. On the basis of a larger number of countries and a longer time span, regressing the year of the survey on trends in partisanship, Dalton (2000a) comes to a less ambiguous conclusion. He finds negative trends in seventeen of the nineteen advanced industrial democracies represented in his study. In this chapter we will see to what extent the trends in partisanship in the six countries included in our study confirm these trends. Limiting ourselves to these six countries might have the disadvantage of a smaller database, but on the other hand it clearly has two major advantages. First, Dalton objects to the study by Schmitt and Holmberg that they include countries which have not yet become advanced industrial societies, and that many time series are too short to reveal effects of cognitive mobilization. An analysis based on national election surveys from the United Kingdom, Denmark, Germany, the Netherlands, Norway, and Sweden, avoids these problems. All are old democracies, they were traditional industrial societies in the 1960s and have transformed into advanced industrial societies in the 1990s. Second, the limitation to six countries enables us to study the development in these countries in more detail. The development of the level of party identification for each of the six countries is presented in Fig. 5.1. In two countries the development is pretty much in line with what the modernization thesis would predict. These countries are the United Kingdom and Sweden. Although the development in neither country is strictly monotonous, there can hardly be a dispute about the direction of change: down we go (Holmberg 1999). In the United Kingdom the decline started in the early 1970s, and continued for more than a decade. The decline came to a halt in the 1980s, that is, in the Thatcher years, but went further in the 1990s. The pattern in Sweden is very similar, although the development over time is a little bit different.

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 109 31.1.2005 7:52am Party Identification and Party Choice 109 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 Germany Sweden UK Norway Netherlands Denmark Fig 5.1. The evolution of the level of partisanship After an initial decline in the late 1960s, the trend stabilized in the 1970s, to be followed by a continuous decline ever since. In the other three countries the development is more complex. In Norway a secular decline can be observed since 1980, but this decline was preceded by an increase in the 1970s after an initial decline in the 1960s. Neither in Denmark nor in the Netherlands can a clear trend be observed. After a sudden decline in the early 1970s, in 1973 to be precise, when all of a sudden the party system was shaken up, the level of party identification slowly clambered in Denmark, but went down again in the 1990s. In the Netherlands a sudden increase in the 1980s interrupts a trend that otherwise is a negative one. The German trend starts out at about 30 per cent in 1961, reaches its highest level well above 50 per cent in 1972, but then continuously declines, falling back to the 30 per cent mark again with the major exception of the reunification election in 1990. So we find compelling evidence that partisanship is declining over time. In all countries partisanship is lower in the late 1990s than in the 1960s and the early 1970s. This is consistent with the theory of modernization. However, it is also clear that partisanship has developed in a more complex way than the modernization thesis would predict. At least part of the development seems to be due to nation-specific characteristics, like Reiter (1989) suggested. It is hard to link the various patterns in the development of partisanship between countries to one general explanation associated with modernization, at least if time is taken as an

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 110 31.1.2005 7:52am 110 Berglund et al. indicator of the process of modernization. It seems more plausible that the fluctuations and deviations from a linear trend are due to periodical effects and country-specific events. Given the limited explanatory power of the theory of modernization 1 we will continue our analysis by two consecutive steps. First, in Section 5.3, we will test the micro-theory underlying modernization theory. Second, in Section 5.4, we will in the spirit of Przeworski and Teune see to what extent we can replace what seem to be nation-specific causes by more general variables. 5.3 DEALIGNMENT AND COGNITIVE MOBILIZATION In order to test the validity of the underlying assumptions of modernization theory at the micro-level we first need to specify which aspects of modernization are relevant. These can be derived from functional theory. The functional model argues that partisanship is becoming less relevant for electorates and predicts a lasting loss of loyalties to political parties in general. Current theories of mass politics proposed that party identification had a functional value for citizens in industrial societies, as parties provided political cues that guided them through the complex world of politics, not just regarding the vote, but also in shaping public opinion and in evaluating political events (Campbell et al. 1960). Party identification was of special importance for a certain segment of the electorate, as partisanship provides a clear and low-cost voting cue for the unsophisticated voter (Converse 1975). As political sophistication was not considered to be widespread in industrial society (Converse 1964), the functional value of party identification was considered to be high. One consequence of the transition to advanced industrial societies is that the functional value of partisanship will decrease. The transition brings about a radical improvement of citizens political resources. First, because of a sharp rise in the level of education and second, because the media explosion leads to an increase in the amount of (political) information available. Thus, the media explosion occurs at a moment when citizens are becoming more capable of processing the information they receive. As sophisticated citizens do not need political guidance from parties, this development should lead to a decline of partisanship. This process is usually referred to as the process of cognitive mobilization. According to Dalton (1984: 267) this implies that ever more citizens possess the skills and resources necessary to become politically engaged with little dependence on external cues. In addition, cognitive mobilization implies a psychological involvement in politics. However, in our view a psychological involvement in politics should not be included in the definition of cognitive mobilization. Cognitive mobilization literally emphasizes cognitive aspects more than psychological involvement: the second element of Dalton s definition of cognitive mobilization. Also, the main argument of the functionalist model is

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 111 31.1.2005 7:52am Party Identification and Party Choice 111 that modernization leads to a politically more sophisticated electorate that no longer needs the cost-saving device of partisanship to find their way in the world of politics. In this argument political involvement might be considered a possible consequence rather than a factor of cognitive mobilization. Therefore, we will limit the definition of cognitive mobilization to the cognitive element and operationalize it by the level of education. Once we accept this operational definition, cognitive mobilization can only be a cause of a possible decline of party identification when the following conditions are met: 1. The level of education has been increasing over time. 2. There is a stable negative relationship between educational level and the level of party identification; that is, the higher the education, the lower the level of party identification. When we test these hypotheses, nationally established measures of education are used and recoded into the trichotomy: primary, secondary, and higher education. In Table 5.1 the development of the level of education is indicated by the percentage of people having received higher education. Obviously, in all countries the level of education has been increasing over time. Therefore, the first condition for cognitive mobilization being a cause of declining partisanship is met. The second condition refers to the relationship between education and party identification. As can be seen in Table 5.2, education does have a negative effect on the level of party identification. At least all regression coefficients point in the expected direction. However, the effect is not significant in Germany and the Netherlands. In the United Kingdom, Norway, and Sweden it has been declining over time. Only Denmark shows a more or less stable and significant effect. Table 5.3 enables us to look at the relationship between education and partisanship in more detail. This table confirms that at least in the United Kingdom, Denmark, Norway, and Sweden the findings are consistent with the cognitive mobilization hypothesis in the sense that there are relatively more independents among people with higher education than among less educated people. However, in the Netherlands and particularly in Germany the pattern contradicts the hypothesis. Also, in the United Kingdom, Norway, and Sweden the differences between the different levels of education have become smaller. This is mainly due to a decline of partisanship among people with a low education. This again is the opposite of what the cognitive mobilization hypothesis predicts. It might be obvious that the level of education is a function of age. The level of education among the population at large has been increasing due to generation replacement. Younger cohorts are much better educated than older cohorts. At the same time age is considered as the most important factor in the development of party identification, not because age in itself is important, but because it is a proxy for the length of time people have had experience with a particular party or the length of time people have been able to confirm their identification with a

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 112 31.1.2005 7:52am 112 Berglund et al. Table 5.1. The development of education (Figures are % highly educated)* Denmark Germany Netherlands Norway Sweden United Kingdom 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 2 1965 11 1966 1967 1968 7 1969 14 1970 15 3 1971 8 1972 9 10 1973 15 10 1974 5 1975 1976 14 16 1977 9 13 14 1978 1979 12 20 6 1980 11 1981 17 16 1982 23 1983 12 10 1984 13 1985 17 25 1986 19 1987 12 7 1988 30 1989 19 19 1990 20 16 1991 21 1992 7 1993 25 1994 21 20 23 23 1995 1996 1997 24 11 1998 32 23 28 1999 2000 2001 14 *Estimates are based on nation specific indictors of higher education.

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 113 31.1.2005 7:52am Party Identification and Party Choice 113 Table 5.2. Education and strength of party identification (Figures are regression coefficients, controlled for age and political interest)* Denmark Germany Netherlands Norway Sweden United Kingdom 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 0.13 1966 1967 1968 0.21 1969 0.20 1970 0.16 1971 0.04 1972 0.01 1973 0.16 0.19 1974 0.21 1975 1976 0.02 0.22 1977 0.04 0.16 1978 1979 0.15 0.16 0.15 1980 1981 0.05 0.12 1982 0.15 1983 0.01 1984 0.10 1985 0.16 0.18 1986 0.06 1987 0.03 1988 0.16 1989 0.15 1990 0.08 0.07 1991 0.07 1992 1993 0.03 1994 0.09 0.00 0.03 0.15 1995 1996 1997 0.01 0.06 1998 0.16 0.03 0.06 0.11 1999 2000 2001 0.08 0.09 *Bold coefficients are significant at the 0.01 level. Party identification is coded: 1. independent; 2. weak identification; 3. strong identification. Due to a different wording in the Norwegian questionnaire, the coding in 1997 is 1. independent; 2. party identification. Education is coded: 1. primary; 2. high school; 3. higher education.

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 114 31.1.2005 7:52am 114 Berglund et al. Table 5.3. Partisanship and education (Figures are % independents at different educational levels and Pearson s r) Election year % primary % secondary % higher Pearson s r all Pearson s r under 30 United Kingdom 1964 16 19 32 0.06 0.02 1970 19 25 31 0.08 0.01 1974 25 28 39 0.06 0.01 1979 29 34 44 0.08 0.04 1983 37 41 36 0.00 0.07 1987 38 40 33 0.01 0.06 1992 37 39 41 0.02 0.06 1997 43 40 37 0.04 0.04 2001 34 42 40 0.06 0.07 Denmark 1977 44 49 54 0.07 1979 38 48 48 0.09 0.09 1984 70 78 75 0.04 0.06 1990 43 53 53 0.08 0.05 1994 45 54 60 0.12 0.05 Germany 1972 39 36 34 0.04 0.01 1976 52 39 34 0.14 0.12 1980 58 45 43 0.12 0.17 1983 60 57 43 0.09 0.10 1987 56 54 52 0.03 0.04 1990 48 42 39 0.07 0.02 1994 69 66 61 0.06 0.12 1998 65 60 46 0.15 0.16 1971 67 60 59 0.06 0.13 Netherlands 1977 66 71 57 1981 67 66 64 0.02 0.05 1986 58 61 60 0.02 0.06 1989 67 74 67 0.02 1994 69 68 61 0.06 0.18 1998 71 75 71 0.01 0.08 Norway 1965 22 32 33 0.10 0.04 1969 32 42 53 0.14 0.08 1973 33 37 49 0.10 0.08 1977 23 34 36 0.11 0.10 1981 24 31 34 0.08 0.01 1985 24 33 37 0.10 0.01 1989 29 40 46 0.12 0.03 1993 37 46 44 0.04 0.12 1997 45 50 42 0.02 0.12 Sweden 1968 49 45 56 0.12 0.02 1970 45 49 52 0.15 0.05 1973 56 56 61 0.14 0.03 1976 48 53 52 0.14 0.03

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 115 31.1.2005 7:52am Party Identification and Party Choice 115 Table 5.3. (Contd.) 1979 36 55 54 0.12 0.02 1982 52 51 54 0.10 0.01 1985 56 59 66 0.16 0.08 1988 63 60 65 0.14 0.03 1991 71 65 67 0.05 0.02 1994 69 67 66 0.12 0.02 1998 76 74 68 0.10 0.07 particular party (Converse 1969, 1976). On the other hand, in the context of the party decline thesis, it has been claimed that the life cycle thesis is no longer valid for the post-war generation. Being better educated they are less likely to develop partisanship and something that does not come into being cannot be confirmed either. Regardless which interpretation is correct, it is obvious that in order to assess the net effect of education on partisanship one should control for age. The results of such an analysis are presented in the last column of Table 5.3, where the correlation between education and partisanship for the youngest generation is shown. As far as we are able to discern the predicted relationship in at least some countries, this is no longer the case among the youngest generation. At first, the correlations are lower than among the population at large and then over time turn into the wrong direction. This means that among younger generations people with a lower instead of a higher level of education tend to turn their back to political parties. Taking all evidence together there is little support for the cognitive mobilization hypothesis and thus for the theory of modernization. Therefore, in Section 5.4 we will turn to the possible alternative explanation of changes in partisanship, focusing on the political context rather than on changes in society. 5.4 PARTY POLARIZATION AND PARTY IDENTIFICATION Schmitt and Holmberg (1995) tested four political factors as possible causal agents behind decreasing levels of partisanship the degree of party polarization, the extent of ideological conflicts, the intensity of issue differences, and the evolution of new parties and found positive, yet weak relationships. The decline in the strength of party identification tended to be related to weakening party polarization, declining ideological conflicts, diminished issue differences, and increases in the number of political parties. We will not replicate their study in this context. We will, however, test two related hypotheses. Hypothesis number one is tested on the aggregated macrolevel using elections as the unit of analysis. It specifies that across time and across countries party identification at election time is higher the more polarized political parties are.

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 116 31.1.2005 7:52am 116 Berglund et al. This hypothesis implies that if polarization goes up, partisanship will go up as well and go down if polarization decreases. The hypothesis that the development of party identification is related to the political context is somewhat at odds with the orthodox perspective on party identification as originally developed by the Michigan School of Electoral Research (Campbell et al. 1960) and more recently maintained by Miller and Shanks (1996). In this view party identification is seen as a deep psychological attachment rooted in early-adult socialization and as hardly sensitive to fluctuations in the political context. However, a more revisionist view on party identification sees it as the result of a running tally of retrospective evaluations of party performance (Fiorina 1981). According to this latter view party identification is supposed to vary with the political institutional context rather than with the social structure of society (Huber et al. 2004). Our hypothesis states that people s degrees of party attachment will vary between elections depending on the nature of party competition. The second hypothesis of this section refers to the micro-level and states that people s degree of party identification is related to the extent that they perceive ideological differences between relevant political parties. It states that people who experience larger differences between parties tend to develop stronger party attachments. In order to determine how polarized a party system is at a particular election, we use two data sources. One is the familiar left right differential derived from the content analyses of party manifestos (see Chapter 2; also Budge et al. 2001). The other one relies on survey evidence and takes the distance between the mean left right self-placement of party voters as a measure of polarization. Moreover, we consider the left right distance between the two major parties as well as that of the two polar parties (among those that reached parliamentary representation) as separate and distinct indicators of polarization. With regard to the level of party identification, finally, we look at the proportions of all identifiers and proportions of strong identifiers as two different criteria. The data in Table 5.4 prove that it is indeed the case that the proportion of party identifiers in national electorates covaries with left right polarization. Over six countries and about fifty elections, we find that the more polarized a party system is, the more numerous party identifiers are (see first row of Table 5.4). There is clear evidence that party polarization leads to a higher level of party identification no matter what criterion we apply with one exception: Overall partisanship seems to drop when the ideological distance between the voters of polar parties increases. All other coefficients are positive, two of them statistically significant despite the limited number of cases: Large distances between the two polar parties go along with high proportions of strong party identifiers both according to manifesto data (r ¼ 0:42) and survey evidence (r ¼ 0:32). Our first hypothesis implies that variations in polarization within countries across time should lead to variations in the level of party identification. However,

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 117 31.1.2005 7:52am Party Identification and Party Choice 117 Table 5.4. Left right polarization and party identification. Pearson s r and n (¼ number of elections) in parentheses MRG-based left right distance two big parties MRG-based left right distance two polar parties Survey-based left right distance two big parties Survey-based left right distance two polar parties All identifiers þ0.13 (61) þ0.18 (61) þ0.24 (46) 0.27 (46) Strong identifiers þ0.21 (59) þ0.42 (59) y þ0.29 (44) 0.32 (44)* United Kingdom all identifiers 0.45 (10) 0.59 (10) þ0.38 (7) þ0.38 (7) strong identifiers 0.49 (10) 0.60 (10) þ0.41 (7) þ0.41 (7) Denmark all identifiers þ0.07 (10) þ0.03 (10) þ0.49 (7) þ0.60 (7) strong identifiers 0.12 (9) 0.09 (9) þ0.88 (6)* þ0.67 (6) Germany all identifiers 0.05 (11) þ0.05 (11) þ0.76 (8)* 0.04 (8) strong identifiers 0.42 (8) 0.44 (8) þ0.73 (8)* 0.24 (8) Netherlands all identifiers 0.18 (9) þ0.30 (9) þ0.53 (7) þ0.74 (7) strong identifiers þ0.30 (9) þ0.50 (9) þ0.43 (7) þ0.67 (7) Norway all identifiers 0.51 (10) 0.07 (10) 0.44 (7) 0.20 (7) strong identifiers 0.63 (9) 0.21 (9) 0.33 (6) 0.06 (6) Sweden all identifiers þ0.11 (11) 0.52 (11) þ0.20 (10) þ0.33 (10) strong identifiers þ0.69 (14) y þ0.24 (14) þ0.31 (10) þ0.41 (10) Source: European Voters Data File; the M(anifesto) R(esearch) G(group) database (Budge et al. 2001); and the data collected and reported in the appendix tables of Schmitt 2002. Note: *p ¼ 0:05; y p ¼ 0:01 the empirical evidence with regard to this specification of the hypothesis is less convincing. The within-country diachronic perspective is conducive to a variety of different patterns. If we start at the bottom of Table 5.5 Sweden is characterized by a positive co-variation between polarization and partisanship: all but one coefficients seem to indicate that polarization indeed produces partisanship. However, things are exactly the other way round just across the border in Norway: There, rising ideological polarization is accompanied by a decrease of partisanship no matter what criterion we look at. Findings for the Netherlands are similar to the Swedish: the higher the polarization, the more the identification. In the German findings, the particular importance of the two major parties stands out: the farther apart SPD and CDU/CSU voters are ideologically, the more partisanship there is. In Denmark, manifesto-based measures of polarization are hardly correlated with partisanship, while survey-based indicators are: the higher

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 118 31.1.2005 7:52am 118 Berglund et al. Table 5.5. Perception of left right polarization between the two major parties and party identification Country Two major parties Election Perceived left right distance by strength PID (Pearson s r) Number of cases United Kingdom Labour, Conservatives 2001 0.18 2221 Denmark S, Venstre 1994 0.10 1801 Germany SPD, CDU/CSU 1980 0.13 1055 1983 0.15 920 1987 0.20 1215 1990 0.06 765 1998 0.12 1546 Netherlands PvdA, CDA 1981 0.12 1468 1982 0.05 674 1986 0.06 1239 1989 0.13 1429 1994 0.06 516 1998 0.09 1596 Norway Labour, Conservatives 1973 0.08 892 1977 0.08 1344 1981 0.13 1350 1985 0.06 1923 1989 0.15 1982 1993 0.09 1870 Sweden S, M 1979 0.25 2416 1982 0.25 2592 1985 0.18 2535 1988 0.23 2395 1991 0.23 2326 1994 0.19 2154 1998 0.20 1959 the ideological distance between party electorates, the more partisanship we find. For the United Kingdom, finally, the strange finding is that polarization as measured by party manifesto data goes along with declining partisanship, while survey-based polarization coincides with rising partisanship. It is evident that things are considerably less uniform in individual countries, than one would expect on the basis of the findings of the pooled analysis. Obviously, there are factors intervening in the association between polarization and identification which cannot be controlled for in the bivariate design of the current analysis 2.

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 119 31.1.2005 7:52am Party Identification and Party Choice 119 In order to test the second hypothesis, in all six countries and across all elections, we created an individual level variable measuring how people perceived the ideological distance on the left right scale between the Social Democratic Party and the largest of the Conservative parties. This perceived polarization variable turned out to be positively correlated, if only modestly, with people s strength of party attachment in each election studied in each country. Perceptions of large differences go along with stronger degrees of party identification (see Table 5.5). Of course, correlations do not prove causality. In theory, the relationship could as well have been shaped by self-rationalizations, for example, that people who are strong party identifiers tend to see, and perhaps want to see, large differences between parties. Lacking good panel data we can not disprove this counterargument, but we have tried to strengthen our test by controlling in multiple regressions for a couple of other variables that we know are, or might be, related to the strength of party identification, for example, people s age, but also level of education. These regression controls did not alter the conclusion. There is a significant relationship between people s perceptions of party conflicts and degrees of partisanship even after relevant controls have been applied. Voters who perceive large party differences tend to have, and maybe also tend to develop, stronger party identifications. The conclusion of our endeavours in this section is fairly obvious. The pooled analysis clearly indicates that ideological polarization between parties does go along with partisanship, even though this conclusion is not warranted in each country and according to each indicator. What is more: We were able to demonstrate on the level of the individual voter that perceptions of ideological polarization are conducive to partisanship (or caused by it as may well be the case). 5.5 PARTY IDENTIFICATION AND THE VOTE In this section we change our analytical perspective and look at party identification as an independent rather than as the dependent variable. Is it still the overdeterministic predictor of party choice that it was claimed to be in some of the early publications on European voting behaviour? Or has its impact on the vote been declining over time? We will determine the proportion of loyalists, that is, identifiers who actually vote for their party, for each national election represented in our database. Those who don t are called defectors. Simple as this strategy may sound, it is still a matter of dispute what the appropriate percentage base should be. There are two basic options: all identifiers or only those who actually went to vote. The all-identifiers-option treats non-voting as a silent exit option; in the onlyvoters-option, these silent defectors are disregarded. We will pursue both paths and start with the former.

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 120 31.1.2005 7:52am 120 Berglund et al. In the six countries in this study the proportion of party identifiers who actually support their party in an election varies between 70 and 82 per cent during the 1990s (see Table 5.6). In Table 5.6 Germany, Sweden, and the United Kingdom the number of loyalists has significantly declined since the 1970s. In Denmark and Norway developments are less spectacular, whereas in the Netherlands, party loyalty has gone up. In the 1990s, on average three in four West European citizens vote for the party they identify with. However, things look somewhat different if we restrict our analysis to only those identifiers who actually turned out and went to vote. Compared to the easy way out into abstention, voting for another party is clearly a harder criterion for identifying defection rates. And as one would expect, loyalists in this perspective are more numerous, defectors less numerous. But still, in the 1990s, one in seven party identifiers who turn out and vote, do vote for another party than the one they identify with (see Table 5.7). This proportion as well has risen over the past decades in five of the six countries in our study. Denmark is a clear exception. In the 1960s and early 1970s, on average only one in ten identifiers who voted, failed to support their party. So from this perspective as well, party identification and party choice seem to have become more independent than they were a few decades ago. 5.6 CONCLUSION In this chapter we tested the validity of two alternative theoretical perspectives on the evolution of party identification. According to the first perspective which is based on the theory of modernization, we should expect a secular decline of the level of party identification. The simple reason is that modern citizens educated and politically skilful as they are do not need anymore the cue of party identification in order to participate meaningfully in an election. The second perspective focuses on political rather than social correlates of party identification and predicts less linear developments. Adversary politics, to use Samuel Finer s term, is supposed to be favourable for the development of partisanship while the opposite of it a broad political consensus across the major parties is expected to suppress the development of party identification. Whereas the first perspective predicts a linear decline of partisanship, the second one does not, unless we would expect a linear decline of polarization, which we do not (see Chapter 2). At first sight our findings seem to be consistent with the modernization perspective. Party identifiers have become less numerous over time. However, developments are anything but monotonous in most countries. Also, we found that the micro-theory underlying the theory of modernization is not corroborated. Contrary to what we should expect, cognitive mobilization does not lead to a lower level of party identification.

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 121 31.1.2005 7:52am Party Identification and Party Choice 121 Table 5.6. Proportion of loyalists among all identifiers (i.e. including those who did not vote or can not tell which party; figures are %)* Denmark Germany Netherlands Norway Sweden United Kingdom 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 81 1965 84 1966 77 1967 1968 87 1969 85 1970 86 74 1971 68 1972 88 1973 78 85 85 1974 75 1975 75 1976 78 90 87 1977 78 72 87 1978 1979 81 89 75 1980 88 1981? 85 1982? 86 1983 87 74 1984 1985 86 85 1986? 1987 86 76 1988 82 1989 72 83 1990 81 72 1991 79 1992 77 1993 76 1994 82 80 75 82 1995 1996 1997 81 70 1998 81 77? 77 1999 2000 2001 68 *Empty spaces indicate that the respective information is not available. A? indicates that the recoding of the data does not allow to produce the figure in question.

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 122 31.1.2005 7:52am 122 Berglund et al. Table 5.7. Proportion of loyalists among voting identifiers (i.e. excluding those who did not vote or can not tell which party; figures are %) Denmark Germany Netherlands Norway Sweden United Kingdom 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 91 1965 89 1966 90 1967 1968 93 1969 91 1970 95 90 1971 91 1972 92 1973 81 92 93 1974 86 1975 87 1976 85 96 91 1977 87 93 96 1978 1979 88 93 88 1980 94 1981 82 94 1982 93 92 1983 93 87 1984 1985 96 90 1986 86 1987 92 86 1988 90 1989 86 92 1990 90 86 1991 86 1992 87 1993 89 1994 88 88 82 89 1995 1996 1997 89 87 1998 85 84 83 85 1999 2000 2001 87

THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 123 31.1.2005 7:52am Party Identification and Party Choice 123 However, the evidence supporting the second perspective is equally ambivalent. In line with what we expected there is some effect of left right polarization on partisanship. Both the analysis of aggregate and individual-level data confirm that politics matters. The more polarized a party system is, the more partisans we find. But again, these political correlates of the development of party identification are modest at best, and cannot fully explain what is going on in the six West European countries under study. In the final step of our analysis we treated party identification as an independent variable, and tried to assess its predictive power for party choice. On average three in four partisans actually support the party they identify with, while one in four abstain from voting or vote for another party. If we restrict this analysis to voters, the respective proportion rises to six in seven: one in seven voting identifiers vote for another party than the one they identify with. But irrespective of the way we define the denominator, party identification has lost some of its predictive power for party choices over the past decades. Where does all of this lead us to? We believe there are a few insights that we have added to the body of knowledge in this domain. One is that there is indeed no monotonous decline in partisanship. Although party identification is on the way down in all countries investigated, the patterns in this evolution are very country-specific. Therefore, theoretical perspectives predicting a similar secular decline of party identification across advanced western democracies, like the theory of modernization does, can at best explain part of the story. But the same applies to theoretical perspectives trying to explain fluctuations in the level of party identification by the political context. Political polarization is one factor in the evolution of partisanship, but certainly not the only one and perhaps not even a very powerful one. A final conclusion is that partisanship and the vote have become more independent over the past decades in Western Europe, which makes party identification potentially a more powerful analytical instrument than it was found to be in the early European election studies. How useful it is as an analytical instrument depends on the extent to which it is possible to explain deviations from voters party identification or normal vote. However, that question is beyond the scope of this chapter. Notes 1. The results from logistic regressions with partisanship as dependent variable and time as explanatory variable (data not shown) prove that not in a single case time explains more than 6 per cent of the variance (pseudo-r 2 ). 2. see Schmitt 2002 for a more complex study design. Author Query [AQ1] The year is 1994 in the list?