With the assistance of: Deborah Pickett Philip Deluty Andrew Caranfil Kwan Kirn

Similar documents
INTERNATIONAL TRADE. To accompany the Georgia International Business Curriculum. CTAE Resource Network, Instructional Resources Office, 2010

Declining Industries, Mechanisms of Structural Adjustment, and Trade Policy in Pacific Basin Economies. Hugh Patrick. Working Paper No.

AFTA as Real Free trade Area

Economics of the Trans- Pacific Partnership (TPP)

Rationalization of Tariffs: Some Lessons From International Experience 1

Preview. Chapter 9. The Cases for Free Trade. The Cases for Free Trade (cont.) The Political Economy of Trade Policy

SINO-ASEAN ECONOMIC INTEGRATION AND ITS IMPACT ON INTRA-ASEAN TRADE

(2) TRADE POLICY FRAMEWORK

Globalization and its Impact on Poverty in Pakistan. Sohail J. Malik Ph.D. Islamabad May 10, 2006

Beyond Recrimination: Perspectives on U.S. - Taiwan Trade Tensions, by Jimmy W. Wheeler

Chapter 10 Trade Policy in Developing Countries

Chapter Organization. Introduction. Introduction. Import-Substituting Industrialization. Import-Substituting Industrialization

Chapter 7. Government Policy and International Trade

a) keeping money at home b) reducing unemployment c) enhancing national security d) equalizing cost and price e) protecting infant industry (X)

Chapter 11. Trade Policy in Developing Countries

Recent trade liberalization efforts, including the North American Free Trade Agreement

The term developing countries does not have a precise definition, but it is a name given to many low and middle income countries.

The 1989 TDRI Year-End Conference

Governments in the advanced industrialized countries have progressively opened

International Economics Day 2. Douglas J Young Professor Emeritus MSU

Trade Theory and Economic Globalization

FH Aachen University of applied sciences. Module: International Business Management Professor Dr. Ulrich Daldrup

Reading Essentials and Study Guide

RULES OF ORIGIN. Chapter 9 1. OVERVIEW OF RULES. Figure 9-1

Economic Development: Miracle, Crisis and Regionalism

October 2006 APB Globalization: Benefits and Costs

Benefits and costs of free trade for less developed countries

U.S.-Latin America Trade: Recent Trends

WORLD ECONOMIC EXPANSION in the first half of the 1960's has

International Business

The Future of the World Trading System

International Business 7e

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

Conclude Doha: It Matters!

ECON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES Instructor: Dr. Juergen Jung Towson University. J.Jung Chapter 18 - Trade Towson University 1 / 42

TRADE POLICY REVIEW OF SOUTH AFRICA 1-2 JUNE GATT Council's Evaluation

The World Trade Organization and the future of multilateralism Note Key principles behind GATT general principle rules based not results based

Brazil, Cuba & Mexico

China and WTO. Negotiation for WTO membership in a changing environment. Dr. Ma Xiaoye Academy for World Watch, Shanghai

MARK2071: International and Global Marketing Overview

Last time. Development and colonial Latin America Political Independence Neo-colonial (post independence) development

Should Pakistan liberalize trade with India against the backdrop of an FTA with China? A Comparative Advantage Analysis for the Manufacturing Sector

Summary of Democratic Commissioners Views

Globalisation and Open Markets

Trade, Border Effects, and Regional Integration between Russia s Far East and Northeast Asia

Global Economic Prospects 2004: Realizing the Development Promise of the Doha Agenda

At the end of Chapter 27, you will be able to answer the following questions:

How Far Have We Come Toward East Asian Community?

EMBARGO: TRADE LIBERALIZATION AND ECONOMIC REFORM. benefiting most from protection, such as the motor vehicle and electronics

RULES OF ORIGIN CHAPTER 10 A. OVERVIEW OF RULES 1. BACKGROUND OF RULES. Chapter 10: Rules of Origin

SERVICES, INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND THE MAJOR ISSUES OF THE URUGUAY ROUND

Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

Summary of the Results

Cambridge International Examinations Cambridge International General Certificate of Secondary Education

WHICH ROAD TO LIBERALISATION? A FIRST ASSESSMENT OF THE EUROMED ASSOCIATION AGREEMENTS C. dell Aquila e M. Kuiper

Nominal and Effective Rates of Protection by Industry in Pakistan: A Tariff Based Analysis

Non-tariff barriers. Yuliya Chernykh

WTO Dispute Settlement: Obligations and Opportunities of the TBT/SPS

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Trade Basics. January 2019 Why Trade? Globalization and the benefits of trade By Dr. Robert L. Thompson

Summary of key points

GEMERAL AGREEMENT ON ON 17 September 1986 TARIFFS AND TRADE

The Comparative Advantage of Nations: Shifting Trends and Policy Implications

Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? Income Growth and Poverty

Chapter 18 Development and Globalization

The End of Textiles Quotas: A case study of the impact on Bangladesh

Geoeconomic and Geopolitical Considerations

SOME FACTS ABOUT MEXICO'S TRADE

OF MULTILATERAL TRADE NEGOTIATIONS

The Development of FTA Rules of Origin Functions

The North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) has raised Mexico s

International Trade Revised: November 8, 2012 Latest version available at

ADDRESS U. S. SENATOR ALLEN J. ELLENDER TO THE INTERNATIONAL CONVENTION OF SUGAR CANE TECHNOLOGISTS NEW ORLEANS, LOUISIANA NOVEMBER 1, 1971

POLI 12D: International Relations Sections 1, 6

Full clear download (no formatting errors) at:

RESTRICTED MTN.GNG/W/28 COMMUNICATION FROM THE CHAIRMAN OF THE GROUP OF NEGOTIATIONS ON GOODS TO THE TRADE NEGOTIATIONS COMMITTEE

Cancún: Crisis or Catharsis? Bernard Hoekman, World Bank 1. September 20, 2003

A view from Europe, as compared with the US, about the impact of China and India on the world economy

Marc Lee Economist Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives -- BC Office CANADA-U.S. CUSTOMS UNION: A CRITICAL ASSESSMENT

The future of the WTO: cooperation or confrontation

CRS Report for Congress

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE POST MFA PERFORMANCE OF DEVELOPING ASIA. John Whalley. Working Paper

Japan s growing Asia focus: Implications for Korea

United States Regional and Bilateral Trade Agreements

DEVELOPMENT AID IN NORTHEAST ASIA

MULTILATERAL TRADE NEGOTIATIONS THE URUGUAY ROUND

Chapter Six. The Political Economy of International Trade. Opening Case. Opening Case

The Significance of Trade Integration among Developing Countries: A Comparison between ASEAN and AMU

Ch. 6 Free Trade. Organizing the Marketplace Introduction to International Relations

Chapter 5: Internationalization & Industrialization

EMERGING PARTNERS AND THE SCRAMBLE FOR AFRICA. Ian Taylor University of St Andrews

International Business Economics

General Interpretative Note to Annex 1A

ECON 436: International Trade TRADE ESSAY FINAL DRAFT

International Economics, 10e (Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz) Chapter 2 World Trade: An Overview. 2.1 Who Trades with Whom?

UNITED STATES CERTAIN METHODOLOGIES AND THEIR APPLICATION TO ANTI-DUMPING PROCEEDINGS INVOLVING CHINA

State Trading and Agricultural Trade: New Rules and Policy Options DRAFT FOR DISCUSSION

The Nanning-Singapore Economic Corridor:

This document relates to item 4.5 of the provisional agenda

CHOICES The magazine of food, farm, and resource issues

Transcription:

THE IMPACT OF INDUSTRIAL COUNTRY PROTECTIONISM ON SELECTED LDCs Maurice Ernst Jimmy U. Wheeler With contributions by George von Furstenberg Perry Wood Catherine Albrecht Bang Nam Jeon With the assistance of: Deborah Pickett Philip Deluty Andrew Caranfil Kwan Kirn Hudson Institute, Inc. Herman Kahn Center 5395 Emerson Way P.O. Box 26-919 Indianapolis, IN 46226

KEY JUDGMENTS Industrial country protectionism affecting the seven LDCs covered by this study has clearly increased in the 1980s, although there have also been instances of liberalization. The most important specific areas of increased protection are: o The application of quotas in the United States and the European Community (EC) to exports of steel from South Korea, Brazil, and Mexico. o The tightening of quotas for textiles and clothing under the umbrella of the Multifiber Arrangement (MFA); this affects all seven countries of the study. o The large increase in anti-dumping and subsidy investigations by the United States, and to a lesser extent by the EC--from 58 per year in 1979-81 to 129 per year in 1982-84--involving a wide variety of products. o Increased protection of the sugar industry in the U.S., the EC, and Japan, resulting in a substantial decline in net imports from the developing countries from 5.2 million tons in 1977-79 to almost zero in 1983-85), with detrimental effects on Brazil and the Philippines. o An increase in tariff escalation and some non-tariff barriers for other raw and processed agricultural products. On the other hand, the quotas and other restrictions imposed by the U.S. on non-rubber footwear in the mid-1970s were allowed to expire or were removed during the 1981-83 period. The measurable direct impact of increased protectionism on the export earnings of the seven subject countries was small, ranging between one and four percent of total exports. Tables 1-7 summarize the impact. The major reason for the small impact is that most of the more important new restrictions took the form of quotas, not tariffs. Like tariffs, quotas raise prices in the countries imposing them. But, unlike tariffs, the windfalls from these higher prices are received by the exporting country. These so-called quota rents partly offset, and in some cases more than offset, the reductions in the volume of exports due to the quotas. Only some quota rents are reflected in our impact estimates; those would be even smaller if a complete estimate of quota results had been possible. The direct impact of protectionist measures was also reduced through a variety of adjustments by the exporting countries. For example:

11 o o Brazil shifted some 15 percent of its steel exports from the U.S., Western Europe, and other markets to China, which paid much lower prices. Several countries shifted the mix of their textile and clothing exports from items that were constrained by quotas to other that were not, and also shifted exports to non-mfa markets. In some countries, notably Brazil, government subsidies buffered producers of affected products (e.g. alcohol), and helped to sustain exports, at least temporarily (e.g. sugar), although at substantial cost to the budget. In other countries, however, notably the Philippines, government policies tended to reinforce the impact of restrictions on output. The long-term impact of recent protectionism is almost certainly greater than the short-term impact, but is impossible to quantify. Even though resources can be reallocated away from heavily protected areas, losses in efficiency may be substantial. This is particularly true when protection prevents the expansion of major industries in which one or more of the subject LDCs has a strong comparative advantage. Such industries include: steel in South Korea and Brazil, frozen orange juice in Brazil, textiles and clothing in South Korea. Protection also has affected the policies of these countries in a variety of ways. In Brazil, increased protectionism has caused losses equivalent to some two percent of export revenues, and even larger losses in national income, but there is no evidence that it has significantly affected production or employment. Faced with protectionist measures, the Brazilians have been as quick to adjust their markets and their product mix, as they had been to expand exports rapidly prior to the imposition of protection. Because of its small dependence on foreign trade, Brazil has substantial flexibility in shifting between domestic and foreign markets. By the same token, long-standing, deep-seated, and inward-looking economic policies and traditions of economic nationalism make Brazil more likely than most other LDCs to react strongly to foreign protection. Indeed, should the current dispute over Brazil's informatica policy lead to serious U.S. retaliation, Brazil may well turn toward even more comprehensive foreign trade and internal controls and become less cooperative with foreign creditors. For Mexico, the impact of industrial country protectionism has been recent and small (1-2 percent of export revenues). Mexico has hardly begun to try to penetrate industrial country markets outside the United States, and even there protectionism against Mexican goods was minimal until the 1980s. This is because of Mexico's predominant reliance on oil exports and its lack of success in developing exports of manufactured goods beyond those arising from foreign direct investments in Mexico. Recent protectionist measures, however, have had a substantial impact on the Mexican steel industry, whose

Ill exports have fallen by half (nearly $100 million), and where output and employment have declined. There have also been small effects on producers of fruit and vegetables, cement, glass, and a few other items. Unlike Brazil, Mexico has been unable to find new foreign markets for restricted products or to shift to other domestic markets, so that export losses have generally resulted in production losses. U.S. protectionism has not yet become a top policy issue in Mexico, and it is unlikely that the kinds of protection imposed to date will have much impact on Mexico's turn toward a more liberal import regime or on its policy emphasis on export diversification. For South Korea, the effects of protectionism have been mixed. Although the steel industry receives large quota rents in the U.S. market (prices of exports to the U.S. exceed average prices for steel exports to other markets by over 10 percent) and has had some success in shifting exports to other markets (in competition with other similarly affected countries), its long-term development is being constrained by protection. South Korea could expand textile and clothing exports if quotas had not been tightened. The rapid growth of shoe exports after U.S. quotas were allowed to expire in 1981 clearly shows that they had restricted export volume severely, although volume loss had been offset by quota rents. Overall, losses of only one to three percent of export revenues can be attributed to new protectionist measures. Income and output losses were even smaller in both absolute and share terms, since South Korea has been so flexible in adjusting to trade barriers. More generally, U.S. protective measures, including the anti-dumping and anti-subsidy investigations are causing serious concern in South Korea and are reinforcing the government's basic feelings of vulnerability. Although U.S. protectionism is politically sensitive, the South Koreans are not likely to change their economic policies in any substantial way, because they do not believe that they have any viable alternative to reliance on export-expansion and close relations with the U.S. Their reaction to U.S. protectionism has been and will be to try harder to sell in the U.S., while trying to diversify exports and markets. They will also be more reluctant to liberalize imports, although they will respond to U.S. pressures for reforms when the gains appear to outweigh the risks. In the Philippines, increased protection of industrial countries' sugar industries threatens to have a devastating impact on the Philippine sugar industry. Philippine sugar exports have fallen by more than half in volume since the late 1970s (from 1.7 million tons in 1980 to 0.6 million tons in 1985). The value of sugar exports has begun to decline and will fall much more when the long-term contracts fortuitously signed during the latest sugar price boom run out, with major impacts on regions of the country facing serious political unrest. Some losses have resulted from textile and clothing quotas, and tariff escalation on raw and processed agricultural products exports are also important constraints. Even though the estimates of export revenue losses are higher as a share of total export than for some of the other countries (4-5 percent), foreign protection is not one of the

major issues facing the Philippine government, which has far more difficult and basic problems to worry about. But if domestic economic conditions do not improve, protection could begin to play an important role in debt negotiations. In Malaysia, apart from textile restrictions, EC and Japanese restrictions on imports of oils and wood, and tariff escalation, foreign protectionism has not been a major political issue. Rather, it has been an increasingly serious annoyance, especially concerning access to the U.S. market, about which most Malaysian exporters are not very knowledgeable. The identifiable costs of protection are low (0.5 to 1.6 percent of export revenues). Because Malaysia's long-run development depends greatly upon its ability to move into exports of higher value-added, processed agriculture products, however, restraints on these products could raise costs considerably in the future. Even at present, the drop in oil prices and the slump in some other commodity markets has increased political sensitivity to foreign protectionism. Pakistan has been mainly concerned about protection faced by cotton, cotton textiles and clothing, even though its ability to fill quotas varies widely among products. Cotton, rice, and wheat subsidies in the industrial countries also receive considerable attention. Due to the large share of exports represented by cotton, textiles and clothing, direct export losses due to protection are larger as a share of total exports than for most of the other countries studied (3-7 percent). The business community is clearly growing increasingly concerned about protectionism and shows a tendency to link it to broader political issues, such as the security relationship with the U.S. vis-a-vis the USSR, and Afghanistan. While the government tends to have a broader perspective, this trend should be of concern to U.S. policymakers. Indonesia has not encountered any substantial increase in industrial country protection, but is pushing harder against existing barriers as it tries to upgrade and diversify its non-oil exports. The drop in oil prices makes both new and old increasingly important. Estimated losses from recent or increased barriers total some 0.8 to 2.2 percent of the somewhat depressed 1985 export revenue. Japanese restrictions and EC tariff quotas on plywood are hindering the expansion of that industry in Indonesia. Problems with manufactured exports are due more to Indonesian inexperience than to protectionist reactions, but this is not the perception of many Indonesians. Moreover, the impact of foreign protectionism on Indonesia's economic policy may be disproportionately large, because it enhances the arguments of the economic nationalists in the government (mainly in Sekeng and the sectoral ministries), who believe Indonesia should turn inward once again rather than undertake economic reforms to promote exports. Beyond its direct and indirect effects on the individual LDCs, industrial country protectionism causes major costs to the economies of industrial

countries, and large and growing distortions in the global economy. The nature of contemporary trade restrictions is such, moreover, that there are few obstacles to their further expansion. For the most part, these restrictions take the form of so-called voluntary agreements to restrict exports, or of ad hoc administrative decisions by importing governments. Because of GATT rules, these restrictions rarely take the form of overt tariffs or unilaterally imposed quotas. The problems with negotiated quantitative restrictions is that important interests on both sides gain: the affected industry in the importing country through higher prices and possibly production and employment in the short-term; and the affected industry in the exporting country through guaranteed higher prices in the restricted market. Moreover, these quantitative restrictions are generally administered in the exporting country by allocating export quotas among existing exporters, who consequently gain assured markets and protection against possible new competitors. It is no wonder then that such agreements can be negotiated, and there is consequently a high risk that more such agreements will be negotiated in the future. The expansion of administrative discretion, especially in the United States, with respect to determination of subsidies and dumping, also has detrimental affects. These actions can greatly disrupt a firm's exports, even though no subsidies or dumping are eventually found. Recent bills before Congress and possible future bills would make this problem far worse. With respect to the implications of increased protectionism for other aspects of U.S. policy, the following points can be made: o o o o So far at least, the increase in protectionist barriers has not been large enough to appreciably affect the economic growth of or the allocation of resources in the seven subject LDCs. Losses in income represent only a fraction of one percent of GDP. The direct impact on export earnings (1 to 3 percent) also has not been large enough to significantly reduce the ability of these seven countries to service their foreign debt. However, the indirect policy impact, especially in Brazil and the Philippines, could be sufficient to induce a much tougher stance towards creditor countries and banks. The use of "voluntary" agreements to establish quotas on exports of various products is inconsistent with the U.S. policy of trying to promote trade liberalization and the general move toward more market-oriented policies in the LDCs. These measures favor existing firms over new firms, encourage cartelization, and especially induce governments to impose tighter controls over the affected industries. Quantitative restrictions on such LDC exports as steel indirectly provide substantial benefits to countries, such as the Peoples

vi Republic of China, which take advantage of the dumping that the restrictions encourage--for example the Chinese pay some 30 percent less than average export prices for Brazilian steel products. Over time, growing quantitative restrictions force the affected countries to accelerate the development of higher value-added industries, and stimulate non-covered countries to invest in restricted industries to take advantage of the rents created. Both imply accelerated competition in industries and products that already face adjustment problems. In turn, this has led to more complex and costly government controls that have distorting effects, especially in agriculture, textiles, and steel.

vn Table 1 IMPACT OF RESTRICTIONS, SUMMARY: BRAZIL A. DIRECT IMPACT (LOSSES) ON 1. PRODUCT AREA (MIL. US$) EXPORT EARNINGS* NATIONAL INCOME* REAL STEEL 100-150 100-150 0 TEXTILES & CLOTHING 20-50 20-50 20-50 SUGAR Unclear 200-250 0 ALCOHOL 50-100 50-100 0 OTHER PRODUCTS 200-300 200-300 100-200 TOTAL 400-600 600-800 150-250 2. TOTAL AS A PERCENT OF: 1.5-2.3 0.4-0.5 0.1 B. INDIRECT IMPACT o POTENTIAL GAINS IN ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY DUE TO GROWING EXPORTS IN HIGHLY COMPETITIVE INDUSTRIES (STEEL, SUGAR, ORANGE JUICE) ARE FOREGONE. o RISK OF NATIONALISTIC REACTION BRINGING INWARD-LOOKING IMPORT SUBSTITUTION POLICIES DETRIMENTAL TO LONG-TERM ECONOMIC GROWTH. o RISK OF REACTIONS RESULTING IN HARDER LINE ON DEBT SERVICING. BASED ON 1984-85 DATA.

vm Table 2 IMPACT OF RESTRICTIONS, SUMMARY: MEXICO A. DIRECT IMPACT (LOSSES) EXPORT EARNINGS* ON NATIONAL INCOME* REAL GNP* 1. PRODUCT AREA (MIL. US$) STEEL OTHER TOTAL 2. TOTAL AS A PERCENT OF: 1-1.4 0.2 0.1-0.2 ioo 100-200 200-300 100 100-200 200-300 100 100-200 200-300 B. INDIRECT IMPACT o LITTLE IF ANY IMPACT ON ECONOMIC AND TRADE POLICY, WHICH ARE DESIGNED TO PROMOTE EXPORT DIVERSIFICATION AND LIMITED IMPORT LIBERALIZATION. o LITTLE IMPACT ON DEBT SERVICE POLICIES OR CAPABILITIES. *BASED ON 1984-85 DATA.

IX Table 3 IMPACT OF RESTRICTIONS, SUMMARY: THE PHILIPPINES A. DIRECT IMPACT (Losses) EXPORT EARNINGS* ON NATIONAL INCOME* REAL GNP* 1. PRODUCT AREA (MIL. US$) RAW & PROCESSED AGRICULTURE (EXCEPT SUGAR) 50 SUGAR 100 TEXTILES & CLOTHING 50-100 TOTAL 2. TOTAL AS A PERCENT OF: B. INDIRECT IMPACT 200-250 3.7-4.7 50 100 50-100 200-250 0.8-0.9 50 100 50-100 200-250 0.6-0.8 INCREASED ECONOMIC STRESS IN POLITICALLY UNSTABLE AREAS. STRENGTHENING OF ANTI-U.S. POLITICAL GROUPS. WEAKENING OF CABINET MEMBERS AND OTHERS WHO SUPPORT BOTH DOMESTIC AND TRADE LIBERALIZATION. *BASED ON 1984 DATA.

X Table 4 IMPACT OF RESTRICTIONS SUMMARY: PAKISTAN, 1984-85 A. DIRECT IMPACT (LOSSES) EXPORT EARNINGS* ON NATIONAL INCOME* REAL GDP* 1. PRODUCT AREA (MIL. US$) -- TEXTILE & CLOTHING 2. TOTAL AS PERCENT OF: $60-120 2.1-4.2 60-120 0.2-0.3 30-60 0.1-0.2 B. INDIRECT IMPACT o INTENSIFY DOMESTIC POLICY BIAS TOWARDS, AND NATIONAL ADVANTAGES OF, LARGE TEXTILE AND CLOTHING FIRMS BY PERMITTING THEM TO CARTELIZE THE MARKET WITH PRIVILEGED ACCESS TO QUOTA RIGHTS. o SOME SHIFT TO HIGHER VALUE PRODUCTS WITHIN QUOTA AREA THAT IS ACCELERATING FROM A VERY SMALL BASE. o INCREASES ATTRACTIVENESS AMONG THE BUSINESS COMMUNITY OF OVERTURES FROM THE U.S.S.R. TO GRANT SPECIAL ECONOMIC PRIVILEGES IN RETURN FOR IMPORTANT POLITICAL CONCESSIONS. o INTENSIFIES THE DISTRUST OF U.S. INTENSIONS AND LONG-TERM COMMITMENT TOWARDS PAKISTAN.

XT Table 5 IMPACT OF RESTRICTIONS SUMMARY: MALAYSIA 1984-85 A. DIRECT IMPACT (LOSSES) EXPORT EARNINGS* ON NATIONAL INCOME* REAL GNP* 1. PRODUCT AREA (MIL. US$) RAW & PROCESSED AGRICULTURE TEXTILES & CLOTHING TOTAL 2. TOTAL AS A PERCENT OF: 50-150 20-100 70-250 0.5-1.6 50-150 20-100 70-250 0.3-1.0 25-75 5-25 30-100 0.1-0.3 B. INDIRECT IMPACT EMERGING PERCEPTION OF GROWING BARRIERS TO THESE INDUSTRIES MOST SUITABLE TO SERVE AS THE BASIS FOR FUTURE GROWTH. GROWING PERCEPTION THAT NEWCOMERS SUCH AS MALAYSIA ARE FACING UNFAIR DISCRIMINATORY TREATMENT COMPARED TO THE INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES AND THE NICs, IN LARGE PART DUE TO FRUSTRATION OVER ECONOMIC ADJUSTMENTS IN THE U.S. AND WESTERN EUROPE. INCREASE OF MALAYSIA'S RELIANCE ON THE ASEAN FRAMEWORK TO INCREASE ITS NEGOTIATING STRENGTH. EXPLICIT POLICY BY BOTH GOVERNMENT AND INDUSTRY TO DIVERSIFY MARKETS.

xn Table 6 IMPACT OF INCREMENTAL RESTRICTIONS, SUMMARY: INDONESIA A. DIRECT IMPACT (Losses) 1. PRODUCT AREA (MIL. US$) ON EXPORT EARNINGS* NATIONAL REAL INCOME* WOOD & WOOD PRODUCTS TEXTILES & CLOTHING RAW & PROCESSED AGRICULTURE TOTAL 2. TOTAL AS A PERCENT OF: B. INDIRECT IMPACT 0-50 70-200 75-150 145-400 0.8-2.2** 0.2-0.6 0-50 50-175 75-150 125-375 0.1-0.3 0-50 50-150 37-750 87-275 o UNDERMINES THE POSITION OF THOSE GOVERNMENT OFFICIALS PUSHING FOR ECONOMIC LIBERALIZATION AND A MORE OPEN TRADING POLICY, AND MAY IMPEDE THE ADOPTION OF POLICIES NEEDED FOR LONG-TERM EMPLOYMENT GROWTH. o WEAKENS WHAT LITTLE INFLUENCE THAT THE U.S. AND OTHER INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES HAVE ON INDONESIAN POLICY. *BASED ON 1984-85 DATA. **2.5 TO 6.8 PERCENT OF NON-OIL/LNG EXPORTS

xm Table 7 IMPACT OF RESTRICTIONS SUMMARY: SOUTH KOREA 1984-1985 A. DIRECT IMPACT (LOSSES) ON EXPORT EARNINGS* NATIONAL INCOME* REAL GNP* 1. PRODUCT AREA (MIL. US$) TEXTILES & CLOTHING IRON & STEEL FOOTWEAR ITEMS NOT EXPLICITLY ESTIMATED $100-250 $160-400 (SMALL GAIN) $100-200 $100-250 $160-400 $50-100 $75-150 $100-150 $25-50 TOTAL 2. TOTAL AS A PERCENT OF: $360-850 1.2-2.8 $310-550 0.5-0.9 $200-350 0.2-0.4 B. INDIRECT IMPACT LOSSES OF POTENTIAL ECONOMIC AND TRADE GROWTH AS RESOURCES ARE DIVERTED FROM HIGHLY COMPETITIVE INDUSTRIES. FORCED SHIFT OF INVESTMENT INTO HIGHER VALUE-ADDED PRODUCTS, AND THE POSSIBLE ACCELERATION OF FUTURE TRADE FRICTIONS IN SOME OF THOSE PRODUCTS. POLITICIZATION OF TRADE POLICYMAKING AS POLITICAL SYSTEMS SLOWLY OPEN, WITH A STRONG NEGATIVE REACTION OF PERCEIVED UNFAIRNESS IN POLICY CHANGES. o A CLEAR SHIFT IN GOVERNMENT AND COMPANY POLICY TO DIVERSIFY EXPORT MARKETS AND PRODUCTS, REDUCE SUBSIDIES, INFORM THE DOMESTIC INDUSTRY ON ANTI-DUMPING LAWS (ESPECIALLY IN THE U.S.), AND TO BECOME MUCH MORE POLITICALLY ACTIVE IN THE INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES.

XV ABOUT THE AUTHORS Maurice C. Ernst Vice President for Economics, Hudson Institute Dr. Emst is responsible for the planning, management and review of Hudson's policy research studies on domestic and international issues involving economic and related political and social analyses. Before joining the U.S. government, Dr. Ernst taught economics at Adelphi College and American University. During more than 30 years in intelligence he worked on most areas of the world and most major economic issues. He began his intelligence career with the Department of State, Bureau of Intelligence and Research, joined CIA in 1954 as an economist, served as Director of CIA's Office of Economic Research and, most recently, was National Intelligence Officer for Economics. Jimmy W. Wheeler Director, Economic Studies, Hudson Institute Jimmy W. Wheeler is an economist specializing in the application of economic analysis to public policy and corporate planning. Since joining Hudson Institute in 1977, Mr. Wheeler has been project director or co-author of studies on international trade; international finance; world energy issues; the U.S. and Japanese economies; and political/economic prospects for various industrial and developing countries. In the national security area, he has participated in studies on mobilization, civil defense, and nuclear proliferation, among others. Mr. Wheeler's publications include: Western Economics in Transition: Structural Change and Adjustment Policies in Industrial Countries with Irving Leveson (Westview Press, 1980); The Competition: Dealing with Japan with T. Pepper and M.E. Janow (Praeger, 1985); and Western European Adjustment to Structural Economic Problems (University Press of America, Inc.; forthcoming, 1987), with Marie-Josec Drouin and Maurice Ernst.