Another look at the Concept of "Overpopulation"

Similar documents
Religion and demographic behaviour in Ireland. Economic and Social Research Institute.

CHAPTER 1 POST-WAR MIGRATION FROM CYPRUS TO BRITAIN

Chapter 11 - Population

Fiscal Impacts of Immigration in 2013

Population and Migration. Chapters 2 and 3 Test Review

1. A Regional Snapshot

Grade 9 Geography Chapter 15 - Population. 1. What are the four general ways in which the population of Canada increases and decreases?

Population Change and Public Health Exercise 8A

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern

BRIEFING. The Impact of Migration on UK Population Growth.

MIGRATION AND DEVELOPMENT: THE KERALA EXPERIENCE. S Irudaya Rajan K C Zachariah

RECENT CHANGING PATTERNS OF MIGRATION AND SPATIAL PATTERNS OF URBANIZATION IN WEST BENGAL: A DEMOGRAPHIC ANALYSIS

Britain s Population Exceptionalism within the European Union

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

11. Demographic Transition in Rural China:

Dangers of Using Aggregated Data for Understanding Socio-Demographic Realities of the Gulf Region

Standard Note: SN/SG/6077 Last updated: 25 April 2014 Author: Oliver Hawkins Section Social and General Statistics

The Implications of New Brunswick s Population Forecasts

Introduction: The State of Europe s Population, 2003

POPULATION PROJECTIONS FOR COUNTIES AND METROPOLITAN STATISTICAL AREAS CALIFORNIA. Walter P. Hollmann, State of California, Department of Finance

Economic and Social Council

A Socio-economic Profile of Ireland s Fishery Harbour Centres. Castletownbere

Transparency, Accountability and Citizen s Engagement

CHAPTER 11 POPULATION TRENDS AND ISSUES

Population and Migration Estimates

PROJECTING THE LABOUR SUPPLY TO 2024

GDP per capita was lowest in the Czech Republic and the Republic of Korea. For more details, see page 3.

Population and Demographic. Tensions

Richard Bilsborrow Carolina Population Center

GLOBALIZATION, DEVELOPMENT AND POVERTY REDUCTION: THEIR SOCIAL AND GENDER DIMENSIONS

3 November Briefing Note PORTUGAL S DEMOGRAPHIC CRISIS WILLIAM STERNBERG

Economics Of Migration

Population projections. and. the Financing of Education

CARIBBEAN EXAMINATIONS COUNCIL

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group

Irish Emigration Patterns and Citizens Abroad

Population and Migration Estimates

SS 11: COUNTERPOINTS CH. 13: POPULATION: CANADA AND THE WORLD NOTES the UN declared the world s population had reached 6 billion.

Part IV Population, Labour and Urbanisation

Projecting transient populations. Richard Cooper, Nottinghamshire County Council. (Thanks also to Graham Gardner, Nottingham City Council) Background

Population Projection Alberta

Geo Factsheet September 2000 Number 97

QUANTITATIVE ANALYSIS OF RURAL WORKFORCE RESOURCES IN ROMANIA

PRESENT TRENDS IN POPULATION DISTRIBUTION

Net immigration lower than in the previous year in 2017

International Migration and Development: Proposed Work Program. Development Economics. World Bank

Population, Health, and Human Well-Being-- Portugal

Journal of the Statistical and Social Inquiry Society of Ireland Vol. XXVII, Part I

GROWTH OF SCHEDULED CASTE POPULATION

Immigration and the Demographics of the United States

STRENGTHENING RURAL CANADA: Fewer & Older: The Coming Population and Demographic Challenges in Rural Newfoundland & Labrador

POPULATION AND MIGRATION

STATEMENT OF PATRICIA A. BUCKLEY, PH.D. SENIOR ECONOMIC ADVISOR U.S

People. Population size and growth. Components of population change

Immigrants are playing an increasingly

reformscotland.com Taking Scotland out of the immigration target

3. Does the economy need immigration?

EMPLOYMENT AND POPULATION ADJUSTMENT IN RURAL AUSTRALIA. Anne Margaret Garnett

Population & Migration

The Impact of Foreign Workers on Labour Productivity in Malaysian Manufacturing Sector

How s Life in Ireland?

UC Santa Barbara CSISS Classics

Bringing the Census to schools

POLITICAL AUTHORITY AND PERFECTIONISM: A RESPONSE TO QUONG

INFOSTAT INSTITUTE OF INFORMATICS AND STATISTICS Demographic Research Centre. Population in Slovakia 2004

Economy Profile 2017 Moldova

Immigration and Employment:

6.1 Population Density & Global Patterns "Population Density" on pages of your text book. Page 2

A Socio economic Profile of Ireland s Fishing Communities. The FLAG South West Region including Castletownbere Harbour Centre

DEMOGRAPHIC SHOCKS: THE VIEW FROM HISTORY. DISCUSSION

WHAT IS THE ROLE OF NET OVERSEAS MIGRATION IN POPULATION GROWTH AND INTERSTATE MIGRATION PATTERNS IN THE NORTHERN TERRITORY?

TEMPORARY AND CIRCULAR MIGRATION IN AUSTRIA A STATISTICAL ANALYSIS BASED ON THE POPULATION REGISTER POPREG ( )

8. United States of America

PREPARING TO DO THE MATH

APES Chapter 10 Study Guide. 1. How can the population change in a particular year be calculated?

LITHUANIAN POPULATION AFTER THE SOCIO-ECONOMIC TRANSITION

Statistics Update For County Cavan

PARTY VOTE LEAKAGE IN WARDS WITH THREE CANDIDATES OF THE SAME PARTY IN THE SCOTTISH LOCAL GOVERNMENT ELECTIONS IN 2012

To Sow One Acre More: Childbearing and Farm Productivity in the Antebellum North

Context Indicator 17: Population density

Population structure 2017

PI + v2.2. Demographic Component of the REMI Model Regional Economic Models, Inc.

Librarian Salaries: Have they kept pace with inflation? Denise M. Davis, Director Office for Research & Statistics American Library Association

Sleepwalking towards Johannesburg? Local measures of ethnic segregation between London s secondary schools, /9.

Rural Manitoba Profile:

Demography. Demography is the study of human population. Population is a dynamic open systems with inputs, processes and outputs.


BIRTHPLACE ORIGINS OF AUSTRALIA S IMMIGRANTS

CER INSIGHT: The biggest Brexit boon for Germany? Migration. by Christian Odendahl and John Springford 11 December 2017

1. GEOGRAPHIC ANALYSIS OF POPULATION Population & Migration

Issues of Migration in Nagaland

AP Human Geography Pacing Guide

STRENGTHENING RURAL CANADA: Fewer & Older: The Coming Demographic Crisis in Rural Ontario

STRENGTHENING RURAL CANADA: Fewer & Older: Population and Demographic Crossroads in Rural Saskatchewan. An Executive Summary

Demo-economic restructuring in South-Muntenia development region. Causes and effects on the regional economy

Migration and HIV/AIDS in Rural Areas: The Case of De-urbanization in Parts of Zambia.

Introduction and overview

Irish emigrant perspectives on emigration. Research report on the welfare experiences of Irish emigrants in association with the GAA

The Jordanian Labour Market: Multiple segmentations of labour by nationality, gender, education and occupational classes

Women Work Participation Scenario in North 24-Parganas District, W.B. Ruchira Gupta Abstract Key Words:

Transcription:

Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin Library in accordance with publisher policies. Please cite the published version when available. Title Another look at the Concept of "Overpopulation" Author(s) Walsh, Brendan M. Publication date 1968-10 Publication information Economic Development and Cultural Change, 17 (1): 95-98 Publisher The University of Chicago Press Link to online version Item record/more information http://www.jstor.org/stable/1152588 http://hdl.handle.net/10197/1494 Downloaded 2018-09-24T14:32:47Z The UCD community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters! (@ucd_oa) Some rights reserved. For more information, please see the item record link above.

Another Look at the Concept of "Overpopulation" Brendan M. Walsh Tufts University Kamerschen's concept of "overpopulation" seems to have survived the initial discussion in this journal and elsewhere.1 This apparent vitality seems to me to be attributable rather to lack of cogency in the criticisms that have been voiced than to the soundness of the original idea. Before too much effort is expended on the construction of Kamerschen's index or too much weight placed on the conclusions based on its use, it might be valuable to try to discuss some of the idea's fundamental weaknesses. Briefly, Kamerschen suggests that "overpopulation" may be simply and fairly reliably measured by constructing an index defined as the Total Dependency Ratio (TDR), where TDR = (100) (population aged 65 and over + population aged under 20)/(population between 20 and 65). Apart from the ease with which the TDR may be constructed, the following virtues are claimed for this index: first, "overpopulation" as defined by this index is a better measure of "population 'pressure' "2 than any other single statistic available; secondly, in some ways the TDR may represent an improvement over the income-per-person measure of economic welfare, primarily because the TDR has certain "dynamic" properties supposedly absent from the income-per-person concept3 (from the terms of Kamerschen's subsequent argument, these dynamic properties appear to be the superior predictions about an economy's future growth rates that may be made on the basis of the TDR). The TDR should provide a rule-ofthumb test for the existence of what we all presumably agree to call population "pressure," and it should also be useful as a supplement to the national-income-per-person concept, especially for making predictions about the economy's future. Some arbitrary critical level for the TDR has to be set, and countries may then be classified as "overpopulated" or "not overpopulated" on the basis of the values of their TDR. Kamerschen tentatively sets the critical value at 100, above which lies overpopulation. No implication is made about the extent of overpopulation. Although not relying on theoretical justifications for the use of the TDR, Kamerschen does suggest some reasons for its validity.4 First, he 95

Economic Development and Cultural Change suggests that those aged over 65 and under 20 are relatively immobile and less able to adjust to economic incentives than the population aged between 20 and 65. While this conclusion is probably justified for those aged over 65, it is certainly not justified for those aged, say, between 14 and 19: empirical studies of migration have found that that mobility is generally high for those in the latter age group.5 Secondly, it is asserted that Intuitively it seems reasonable to feel that as the number of economically unproductive workers increases relative to the productive group, i.e., the dependency ratio increases, a country would have more of a population problem.6 The implication is that the TDR measures the ratio of "unproductive workers" to "productive workers" in a population. Of course, the TDR was not defined in terms of the age distribution of the labor force, nor in terms of the ratio of "productive workers" to "unproductive workers," but simply in terms of the age distribution of the total population. To assume that the age distribution of the total population reflects the distribution of the population between producers and nonproducers fully evades the crucial problem of defining and measuring the productive labor force in an underdeveloped country, a problem which has preoccupied many economists in recent years. Damaging though this fault may be, it is at least defensible as a crude approximation which would have the virtue of making the measurement of "overpopulation" much easier, if less meaningful. To accept, however, without comment Bogue's boundaries of demarcation between active and dependent population is inexcusably arbitrary and casual: Bogue's index was for use as a demographic device for the United States, and it properly reflects the present U.S. conventions with regard to entry into and retirement from the labor force.7 To apply this index to the underdeveloped countries and to hope that economic meaning can be extracted from it is clearly to sidestep all the issues that attend the definition and measurement of overpopulation. Of course, Kamerschen does not place too much emphasis on the theoretical justifications for the use of the TDR; instead, he emphasizes that his index has considerable support from the available empirical data, although he admits that it may be possible to find exceptions to his claims about it.8 Faced with this sort of methodological vacuum, it may be difficult to disprove anything to Kamerschen's satisfaction, since his thesis has been hedged to such an extent that it may not admit of proof or disproof. A further look at the data is in order, however. In the various cases he discusses in which the TDR test suggests that "overpopulation" does not exist, while the income per person test suggests that the nation is underdeveloped, Kamerschen is pleased to report that in almost all cases the countries in question performed well in terms of growth of real income per person in the subsequent period, and this ap- 96

Brendan M. Walsh parently supports the claims made for the superior "dynamic" qualities of the TDR. While not wishing to get involved in an example-counterexample contest, least of all when it entails the comparison of demographic and economic statistics for the underdeveloped countries, it may be useful to point out that since the TDR is a purely demographic construct, it is possible for it to rise above the critical level as a result of forces that are not clearly related to any usual concept of "overpopulation" nor to the future course of national income. A country with European-level death and birth rates, a slowly growing, stationary, or even falling total population could assume the demographic profile necessary to yield a TDR > 100, if heavy and persistent emigration occurred in the 20-65 age group of its population. There is nothing in this set of circumstances to suggest overpopulation, unless one is willing to accept emigration as a sign of this problem (Kamerschen explicitly rejects this), nor does it imply anything about the future course of the country's income. All that is necessary is that a substantial gap exist between this country's income and the income of some other country to which immigration is not restricted. The sufficient condition is that the country's population should have reacted to this income gap through heavy and persistent emigration that was selective of those in the 20-65 age group. In point of fact, the only country in which these circumstances have combined in recent history is Ireland, although migration of sufficient intensity may well have given many regions within the larger, richer nations the necessary population profile. (In fact, Bogue records a TDR of 99.9 for the rural farm population of the United States in 1950.9) Between 1956 and 1961, the population of the Republic of Ireland fell at an annual rate of 0.56 percent: the annual crude birth rate was 21.2, the crude death rate was 11.9, and the net emigration rate was 14.8 per 1,000 population.10 Almost 80 percent of this emigration was from the population aged 20-65. In 1961 the TDR for Ireland was 102.4 (or 100.8 on Kamerschen's earlier definition), thus just passing the "overpopulation" test, despite the falling population, despite being the country with the lowest population density in Europe, and despite the $740 level of income per person in 1964. From the "dynamic" viewpoint the TDR fares no better in this case: Ireland's real income per person grew at an annual average rate of 4 per cent in the four years after 1961. The unusual Irish population structure is, of course, a serious problem and raises very interesting economic and social problems.l1 Emigration from Ireland may, in fact, be related to the very high fertility rates that are prevalent there, as well as to the low level of income in Ireland relative to the United Kingdom. But these are separate issues, involving a more detailed discussion of the concept of "overpopulation" than this debate has provided to date. The example of Ireland is adduced here merely to underline the fact that it is theoretically possible and historically verified that a country may pass Kamerschen's test and still not be overpopulated in any of the ways in which this term is generally used. 97

Economic Development and Cultural Change The Irish case also serves to provide a counterexample to the "dynamic" claims of the TDR. The upshot of this discussion is inevitably negative. The only conclusions that appear to emerge relate to research strategy: instead of looking for easy ratio tests to enable us to define "overpopulation," the most profitable course would seem to be to construct theoretical models of the interrelations between population growth and income growth and to test these models by established econometric techniques. 1 Cf. David R. Kamerschen, "On an Operational Index of'overpopulation,'" Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 12, No. 1 (January 1965), pp. 169-87; and Gordon A. Marker, "Comments on an Operational Index of 'Overpopulation,"' Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 15, No. 2 (April 1967), pp. 336-38, with a "Reply" by Kamerschen, pp. 338-41, as well as the references cited in the last two items. 2 Kamerschen, "On an Operational Index...," op. cit., p. 171. 3 Ibid. 4 Ibid., p. 174. 5 For a bibliography of migration studies, cf. Gunnar Olsson, Distance and Human Interaction, A Review and Bibliography (Philadelphia: Regional Science Research Institute, 1965). 6 Kamerschen, "On an Operational Index...," op. cit., p. 174. 7 According to footnote 8 of Kamerschen's "Reply"(op. cit.), he is not really sure just how he wishes to define the TDR: "Presumably this group [those aged exactly 65] should be included in the numerator." (In his calculations this group was completely omitted from both numerator and denominator!) In my definition of the TDR I have taken this footnote into account, but in the calculation of the TDR I give the figure that results from both definitions. 8 Kamerschen, "On an Operational Index...," op. cit., p. 186. 9 Cf. Donald J. Bogue, The Population of the United States (Glencoe, Ill.: Free Press, 1959), p. 102. 10 Cf. Ireland, Central Statistics Office, Census of the Population of Ireland 1961, Vol. 2, Table 10; and for national income data, Statistical Abstract of Ireland, 1965, Table 235. 11 For examples, cf. P. Kaim-Caudle, Social Policy in the Irish Republic (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1967). Volume 17 Number I? by the University of Chicago All rights reserved