The Fiscal Cost of Low-Skill Immigrants to State and Local Taxpayers

Similar documents
BACKGROUNDER. National Academy of Sciences Report Indicates Amnesty for Unlawful Immigrants Would Cost Trillions of Dollars

Immigration. Immigration and the Welfare State. Immigrant and Native Use Rates and Benefit Levels for Means-Tested Welfare and Entitlement Programs

New public charge rules issued by the Trump administration expand the list of programs that are considered

New Findings on the Fiscal Impact of Immigration in the United States

Amnesty and Continued Low-Skill Immigration Will Substantially Raise Welfare Costs and Poverty

Based on our analysis of Census Bureau data, we estimate that there are 6.6 million uninsured illegal

Unauthorized Immigration: Is it really a fiscal burden for. California?

POVERTY in the INLAND EMPIRE,

Mission: [The Social Security

How Should Immigration Affect the Economy? A D A M M. Z A R E T S K Y

This analysis confirms other recent research showing a dramatic increase in the education level of newly

Immigrant Demands on Public Benefits

Providing Health Care for Illegal Immigrants: Understanding the House Health Care Bill

Immigrants are playing an increasingly

The Fiscal Costs of the U.S. Refugee Admissions Program at the Federal, State, and Local Levels, from

Immigrants Access. Who Remains Eligible for What? JILL D. MOORE

Written Testimony of

HOUSE RECONCILIATION BILL TARGETS FOOD STAMP PROGRAM FOR CUTS

DOWNLOAD PDF AN ACCOUNT OF THE RECEIPTS AND EXPENDITURES OF THE UNITED STATES FOR THE YEAR 1809.

Fiscal Impacts of the Foreign-Born Population

Immigration in Utah: Background and Trends

Government data show that since 2000 all of the net gain in the number of working-age (16 to 65) people

Gauging the Impact of DHS Proposed Public-Charge Rule on U.S. Immigration

By Leighton Ku, Shawn Fremstad and Matthew Broaddus

Social Security Administration (SSA): Budget Issues

Department of Legislative Services

Immigration and the U.S. Economy

Immigration s Impact on American Workers

Counting for Dollars: The Role of the Decennial Census in the Geographic Distribution of Federal Funds

Migrants Fiscal Impact Model: 2008 Update

Examining the Congressional Budget Office Cost Estimate of the Senate Immigration Bill By Sharon Parrott and Chad Stone

Who is Leaving the Food Stamp Program? An Analysis of Caseload Changes from 1994 to 1997

THE DECLINE IN WELFARE RECEIPT IN NEW YORK CITY: PUSH VS. PULL

Immigration, Income Tax, and Social Assistance

EPI BRIEFING PAPER. Immigration and Wages Methodological advancements confirm modest gains for native workers. Executive summary

Testimony of Shannon Benton Executive Director The Senior Citizens League

Potential Economic Impacts in Oregon of Implementing Proposed Department of Homeland Security No Match Immigration Rules

Robert Haveman For Poverty 101 June, 2018 Research Training Policy Practice

Poverty in New York City, 2005: More Families Working, More Working Families Poor

INTRODUCTION TO THE FEDERAL BUDGET PROCESS by Martha Coven and Richard Kogan

Does Immigration Raise or Lower Taxes?

THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF ADMINISTRATIVE ACTION ON IMMIGRATION

Committee on National Statistics Division of Behavioral and Social Sciences and Education WATER SCIENCE AND TECHNOLOGY BOARD

Fiscal Impacts of Immigration in 2013

BY Rakesh Kochhar FOR RELEASE MARCH 07, 2019 FOR MEDIA OR OTHER INQUIRIES:

CRS-2 it for the revenues it would have collected if it had charged full postage to groups Congress has chosen to subsidize. This report covers the co

The Benefits of Immigration: Addressing Key Myths

Growth of the Social Security Earnings Suspense File Points to the Rising Cost of Unauthorized Work To Social Security

Immigration and the US Economy:

SUPPLEMENTAL NOTE ON SENATE SUBSTITUTE FOR HOUSE BILL NO. 2258

HOW THE POTENTIAL 2013 ACROSS-THE-BOARD CUTS IN THE DEBT-LIMIT DEAL WOULD OCCUR by Richard Kogan

Introduction to the Federal Budget Process

Latinos in Saratoga County. Trudi Renwick Senior Economist Fiscal Policy Institute April 26, 2008

Using data provided by the U.S. Census Bureau, this study first recreates the Bureau s most recent population

September 15, Summary

LEGACIES OF THE WAR ON POVERTY

Does Immigration Help or Hurt Less-Educated Americans? Testimony of Harry J. Holzer before the U.S. Senate Judiciary Committee

Where can I get help? SNAP Facts by Population

Poverty Profile. Executive Summary. Kingdom of Thailand

Elizabeth M. Grieco, Patricia de la Cruz, Rachel Cortes, and Luke Larsen Immigration Statistics Staff, Population Division U.S.

Paying Their Way and Then Some

The Economic Benefits of Closing Educational Achievement Gaps

Economic Security. For information on the resources used, please contact Dawn Juker at or call (208)

Older Immigrants in the United States By Aaron Terrazas Migration Policy Institute

1. PUBLIC DEBT LIMIT INCREASE 2. CORPORATE MINIMUM TAX

C urrent federal benefits eligibility for immigrants is largely shaped by the 1996

Changing Times, Changing Enrollments: How Recent Demographic Trends are Affecting Enrollments in Portland Public Schools

Backgrounder. This report finds that immigrants have been hit somewhat harder by the current recession than have nativeborn

Unauthorized Aliens in the United States: Estimates Since 1986

Immigration Reform, Economic Growth, and the Fiscal Challenge Douglas Holtz- Eakin l April 2013

Rural Welfare Reform. Lessons Learned. Leslie A.Whitener, Robert Gibbs, Lorin Kusmin,

SOCIAL SECURITY ADMINISTRATION

CHAPTER 18: ANTITRUST POLICY AND REGULATION

Immigrants, Welfare Reform, and the U.S. Safety Net. Marianne Bitler UC Irvine. Hilary W. Hoynes UC Davis

ASSESSING IMPLEMENTATION OF THE 2002 FARM BILL S LEGAL IMMIGRANT FOOD STAMP RESTORATIONS

Understanding Immigration:

How s Life in the United States?

Immigrants and Public Benefits in Texas

Congressional Budget Action for Fiscal Year 2012 and its Impact on Education Funding Jason Delisle, Federal Education Budget Project

Youth at High Risk of Disconnection

Replacing the Undocumented Work Force

GDP per capita was lowest in the Czech Republic and the Republic of Korea. For more details, see page 3.

Congressman Tom Reed and the Plan to Cut Social Security

The Costs of Illegal Immigration to Tennesseans

Testimony prepared by. Triada Stampas. for the. Committee on Health. on a

Unemployment Rises Sharply Among Latino Immigrants in 2008

CRS Report for Congress

Pulling Open the Sticky Door

State Estimates of the Low-income Uninsured Not Eligible for the ACA Medicaid Expansion

A Barometer of the Economic Recovery in Our State

After analyzing data, foundation finds 28 million a more likely figure

Lessons from the U.S. Experience. Gary Burtless

Po ver t y Myt h s. The truth about four of the most persistent myths about poverty in America. 4thworldmovement.org

International Migration and Development: Proposed Work Program. Development Economics. World Bank

How to Fix. Utah s state capitol: An anti-illegalimmigration. similar to the one shown on page 19 was introduced in the Utah House on February 1.

Testimony. Douglas W. Elmendorf Director Before the Subcommittee on the Legislative Branch Committee on Appropriations United States Senate

The Threat Continues. Medicaid, the Budget, and Deficit Reduction: The Bottom Line: Our Message on Medicaid and the Super Committee Process

Rural Virginia: Issues and Opportunities

THE CONSORTIUM stimulating self-sufficiency & stability scholarship

Extrapolated Versus Actual Rates of Violent Crime, California and the United States, from a 1992 Vantage Point

Transcription:

214 Massachusetts Ave. N.E Washington D.C. 20002 (202) 546-4400 www.heritage.org CONGRESSIONAL TESTIMONY The Fiscal Cost of Low-Skill Immigrants to State and Local Taxpayers Testimony before The Subcommittee on Immigration Committee on the Judiciary United States House of Representatives May 17, 2007 Robert Rector Senior Research Fellow Domestic Policy Studies The Heritage Foundation

My name is Robert Rector. I am Senior Research Fellow for Welfare and Family Issues at The Heritage Foundation. The views I express in this testimony are my own, and should not be construed as representing any official position of The Heritage Foundation. Summary This testimony provides a fiscal analysis of households headed by immigrants without a high school diploma. The testimony refers to these households as low-skill immigrant households. My analysis, in particular, focuses on the harmful fiscal impact of low skill immigrants on state and local governments. In FY 2004 there were around 4.5 million low-skill immigrant households in the U.S. containing 15.9 million persons. About 60 percent of these low-skill immigrant households were headed by legal immigrants and 40 percent by illegal immigrants. The analysis presented here measures the total benefits and services received by these lowskill immigrant households compared to the total taxes paid. In FY 2004, the average low skill immigrant household received $30,160 in direct benefits, means-tested benefits, education, and population-based services from all levels of government. By contrast, low-skill immigrant households paid only $10,573 in taxes in FY 2004. A household s net fiscal deficit equals the cost of benefits and services received minus taxes paid. The average low-skill household had a fiscal deficit of $19,588 (expenditures of $30,160 minus $10,573 in taxes). At the state and local level, the average low skill immigrant household received $14,145 in benefits and services and paid only $5,309 in taxes. The average low skill immigrant households imposed a net fiscal burden on state and local government of $8,836 per year. The fiscal burden imposed by low skill immigrant households is slightly greater at the state and local level than at the federal level. The annual fiscal deficit for all 4.54 million low skill immigrant households at the state and local level in 2004 was $49.1 billion. Over the next ten years the state and local fiscal deficit caused by low skill immigrants on state and local governments will approach a half trillion dollars. Current federal immigration policy permits a massive inflow of both legal and illegal low skill immigrants to enter and reside in the U.S. This imposes a massive unfunded mandate on state and local government which much bear the costs of that immigration flow. Giving amnesty to illegal immigrants would increase the costs outlined in this testimony. Some 50 to 60 percent of illegal immigrants lack a high school degree. Granting amnesty or conditional amnesty to illegal immigrants would, overtime, increase their use of means-tested welfare, Social Security and Medicare. Fiscal costs would go up significantly in the short term but would go up dramatically after the amnesty recipient 1

reached retirement. Based on my current research, I estimate that if all the current adult illegal immigrants in the U.S. were granted amnesty the net retirement costs to government (benefits minus taxes) could be over $2.5 trillion. Recent proposed immigration legislation in the Senate and House will raise costs on the taxpayers at all levels of government. By granting amnesty to illegal immigrants (who are overwhelmingly low skilled) and creating massive new guest worker programs which would bring millions of additional low skill families into the nation, such legislation, if enacted, would impose massive costs on the U.S. taxpayer. Types of Government Expenditure To ascertain the distribution of government benefits and services, my analysis begins by dividing government expenditures into four categories: direct benefits; meanstested benefits; educational services; and population-based services. Direct Benefits Direct benefit programs involve either cash transfers or the purchase of specific services for an individual. Unlike means-tested programs (described below), direct benefit programs are not limited to low-income persons. By far, the largest direct benefit programs are Social Security and Medicare. At the state and local level, the major direct benefit programs are Unemployment Insurance and Workmen s Compensation. Overall, government spent $840 billion on direct benefits in FY 2004; of this $57.6 billion was state and local spending. Means-Tested Benefits Means-tested programs are typically termed welfare programs. Unlike direct benefits, means-tested programs are available only to households below specific income thresholds. Means-tested welfare programs provide cash, food, housing, medical care, and social services to poor and low-income persons. The federal government operates over 60 means-tested aid programs. 1 The largest of these are Medicaid; the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC); food stamps; Supplemental Security Income (SSI); Section 8 housing; public housing; Temporary Assistance to Needy Families (TANF); the school lunch and breakfast programs; the WIC (Women, Infants, and Children) nutrition program; and the Social Services Block Grant (SSBG). Many means-tested programs, such as SSI and the EITC, provide cash to recipients. 1 Congressional Research Service, Cash and Noncash Benefits for Persons with Limited Income: Eligibility Rules, Recipient and Expenditure Data, FY2002 FY 2004, March 27, 2006. The value of Medicaid benefits is usually counted in a manner similar to Medicare benefits. Government does not attempt to itemize the specific medical services given to an individual; instead, it computes an average per capita cost of services to individuals in different beneficiary categories such as children, elderly persons, and disabled adults. (The average per capita cost for a particular group is determined by dividing the total expenditures on the group by the total number of beneficiaries in the group.) 2

Others, such as public housing or SSBG, pay for services that are provided to recipients. Overall, the U.S. spent $564 billion on means-tested aid in FY 2004. 2 Of this, $158.4 billion was state and local spending. Public Education Government provides primary, secondary, post-secondary, and vocational education to individuals. In most cases, the government pays directly for the cost of educational services provided. Education is the single largest component of state and local government spending, absorbing roughly a third of all state and local expenditures. The average per pupil cost of public primary and secondary education is now around $9,600 per year. Overall, federal, state, and local governments spent $590 billion on education in FY 2004. Of this $530.8 billion was state and local spending. Population-Based Services Whereas direct benefits, means-tested benefits, and education services provide discrete benefits and services to particular individuals, population-based programs generally provide services to a whole group or community. Population-based expenditures include police and fire protection, courts, parks, sanitation, and food safety and health inspections. Another important population-based expenditure is transportation, especially roads and highways. A key feature of population-based expenditures is that such programs generally need to expand as the population of a community expands. (This quality separates them from pure public goods, described below.) For example, as the population of a community increases, the number of police and firemen will generally need to expand in proportion. In its study of the fiscal costs of immigration, The New Americans, the National Academy of Sciences argued that if a service remains fixed while the population increases, a program will become congested, and the quality of the service for users will deteriorate. Thus, the National Academy of Sciences uses the term congestible goods to describe population-based services. 3 Highways are an obvious example of this point. In general, the cost of population-based services can be allocated according to an individual s estimated utilization of the service or at a flat per capita cost across the relevant population. Government spent $662 billion on population-based services in FY 2004. Of this $481 billion was state and local spending. Exclusion of Public Goods and Interest on Government Debt from Calculations 2 This spending figure excludes means-tested veterans programs and most means-tested education programs. 3 National Research Council, The New Americans: Economic, Demographic, and Fiscal Effects of Immigration, National Academy Press, Washington, D.C., 1997, p. 303 3

The four expenditure categories described above can be termed immediate benefits and services. There are two additional spending categories, which are not relevant to immigrants. They are: Interest and other financial obligations resulting from prior government activity, including interest payments on government debt and other expenditures relating to the cost of government services provided in earlier years; and Pure public goods, which include national defense, international affairs and scientific research, and some environmental expenditures. Unlike the first four spending categories, expenditures on public goods, debt and other financial obligations are fixed and are largely independent of the level or type of immigration flow into the U.S. The entry of legal or illegal immigrants into the U.S. will not cause expenditures in these two categories of expenditure to increase, therefore these two categories of expenditure are not included in the fiscal burden calculation for lowskill immigrants presented in this testimony. The Declining Education Levels of Immigrants Current immigrants (both legal and illegal) have very low education levels relative to the non-immigrant U.S. population. As Chart 1 shows, some 50 percent, and perhaps as many as 60 percent, of illegal immigrant adults lack a high school degree. 4 Among legal immigrants the situation is better, but a quarter still lack a high school diploma. Overall, a third of immigrant households are headed by individuals without a high school degree. By contrast, only nine percent of non-immigrant adults lack a high school degree. The current immigrant population, thus, contains a disproportionate share of poorly educated individuals. These individuals will tend to have low wages, pay little in taxes and receive above average levels of government benefits and services. There is a common misconception that the low education levels of recent immigrants is part of a permanent historical pattern, and that the U.S. has always brought in immigrants who were poorly educated relative to the native born population. Historically, this was not the case. For example, in 1960, recent immigrants were no more likely than were non-immigrants to lack a high school degree. By contrast, in 1998, recent immigrants were almost four times more likely to lack a high school degree than were non-immigrants. 5 4 Jeffrey S. Passel, The Size and Characteristics of the Unauthorized Migrant Population in the U.S.: Estimates Based on the March 2005 Current Population Survey, Pew Hispanic Center, March 7, 2006. See also Jeffrey S. Passel, Unauthorized Migrants: Numbers and Characteristics, Pew Hispanic Center, June 14, 2005. Steven S. Camarota, The High Cost of Cheap Labor: The Impact of Illegal Immigration on the Federal Budget, Center for Immigration Studies, August, 2004. 5 George J. Borjas, Heaven s Door: Immigration Policy and the American Economy, Princeton New Jersey, Princeton University Press, 1999, p. 27. 4

Percent of Adults Who Are High School Dropouts Chart 1 49% 25% 9% Illegal Immigrants Legal Immigrants Native-Born Persons Source: Pew Hispanic Center As the relative education level of immigrants fell so did their relative wage levels. In 1960, the average immigrant male in the U.S. actually earned more than the average non-immigrant man. As the relative education levels of subsequent waves of immigrants fell, so did relative wages. By 1998, the average immigrant earned 23 percent less than the average non-immigrant. 6 Recent waves of immigrants are disproportionately low-skilled because of two factors. For years, the U.S. has had a permissive policy concerning illegal immigration: the 2000 mile border with Mexico has remained porous and the law prohibiting the hiring of illegal immigrants has not been enforced. This encourages a disproportionate flow of low-skill immigrants because few college educated workers are willing to undertake the risks and hardships associated with crossing the southwest U.S. deserts illegally. Second, the legal immigration system gives priority to family reunification and kinship ties rather than skills; this focus also significantly contributes to the inflow of low-skill immigrants into the U.S. Fiscal Deficit at All Levels of Government Looking at federal, state and local benefits combined, the average low skill immigrant household received $30,160 per household in direct benefits, means-tested benefits, education, and population-based services in FY 2004. By contrast, as Chart 2 6 Ibid., p. 8 5

shows, total federal, state, and local taxes paid by low-skill immigrant households came to $10,573 per household in 2004. The average fiscal deficit per low skill immigrant household was $19,588. Dropout Households Receive More Than Three Dollars in Benefits for Every Dollar Paid in Taxes Chart 2 $30,160 $19,588 $10,573 Average Taxes Paid Note: Figures refer to average per household amounts Source: Appendix Tables 4 and 5 Average Benefits: Direct Benefits, Means-Tested Benefits, Education, Population-Based Services Net Fiscal Deficit Age Distribution of Benefits and Taxes among Low-Skill Immigrants Chart 3 separates the 4.5 million low-skill immigrant households into six categories based on the age of the immigrant head of household. It shows benefits received and taxes paid at each age level. For each age category, the benefits received by low-skill immigrant households exceed the taxes paid. These figures belie the notion that government can relieve financial strains in Social Security and other programs simply importing younger immigrant workers. The fiscal impact of an immigrant worker is determined far more by skill level than by age. Low-skill immigrant workers impose a net drain on government finance as soon as they enter the country and add significantly to those cost every year they remain. Actually, older low-skill immigrants are less costly to the U.S. taxpayer since they will be a burden on the fisc for a shorter period of time. 6

Benefits Received and Taxes Paid by Low-Skill Immigrant Households by Age of Head of Household Taxes Paid Immediate Benefits and Services Received $25,485 $34,371 $30,785 $26,942 $37,537 Chart 3 $14,295 $10,830 $12,861 $14,525 $10,702 $8,365 $4,581 Head of Household Under 25 Head of Household 25 to 34 Head of Household 35 to 44 Head of Household 45 to 54 Head of Household 55 to 64 Head of Household 65 or Older Note: Immediate Benefits include Direct and Means-Tested Benefits, Public Education, and Population-Based Services Source: Appendix Table 6 Fiscal Impact at the Federal Level Low-skill immigrant households generate a fiscal deficit at both the federal level and the state and local level. As Chart 3 states, at the federal level, low-skill immigrant households receive, on average, $14,145 per year in benefits and pay $5,309 in taxes. This amounts to nearly three dollars in benefits for each dollar of taxes paid. The fiscal deficit (benefits received minus taxes paid) equaled $8,836 per household per year. Dropout Households Receive More Than Three Dollars in Federal Benefits for Every Dollar Paid in Taxes Chart 4 $14,145 $8,836 $5,309 Average Federal Taxes Paid Average Federal Benefits: Direct Benefits, Means- Tested Benefits, Education, Population- Based Services Net Federal Fiscal Deficit 7

Fiscal Impact at the State and Local Level The fiscal impact is actually somewhat larger at the state and local level than at the federal level. As Chart 4 shows the average low-skill immigrant household received $16,016 in state and local benefits while paying $5,263 in taxes. This amounts to over three dollars of benefits for each dollar of taxes paid. The state and local fiscal deficit (benefits received minus taxes paid) equaled $10,753 per household per year. Dropout Households Receive More Than Three Dollars in State & Local Benefits for Every Dollar Paid in Taxes $16,016 Chart 5 $10,753 $5,263 Average State & Local Taxes Paid Average State & Local Benefits: Direct Benefits, Means-Tested Benefits, Education, Population-Based Services Net State & Local Fiscal Deficit State and Local Benefits and Services Chart 5 shows the state and local benefits received by the average low-skill immigrant household. Public education costs at $7,737 per household represent nearly half of these expenditures. The second largest expenditures is means-tested welfare. State and local governments run few of their own welfare programs, but they are required to financially contribute to many of the 60 different federal means-tested programs, such as Medicaid or the Temporary Assistance to Needy Families (TANF). The low-skill immigrant share of these expenditures came to $2,957 per household per year. Police and fire protection was the third largest category of spending at $2,198 per household. Other state and local expenditures included transportation ($572 per household); unemployment insurances and worker s compensation ($488 per household); and sewer and utilities ($411 per household). 8

State and Local Government Expenditures for Benefits and Services for Households Headed by Immigrants Without A High School Diploma Chart 6 Total Benefits and Services $16,016 Health Services, $245 Sewers, Utilities, and Environment, $411 Transportation, $572 Other, $538 Police and Fire Protection, $2,198 Parks and Recreation, $268 Unemployment and Workmen's Compensation, $488 Administrative Expenses, $602 Means-Tested Welfare, $2,957 Public Education, $7,737 Average Expenditure Per Household State and Local Taxes and Revenues Chart 6 shows that low-skill immigrant households pay an average of $5,263 per household in state and local taxes. Sales and excise taxes ($1,706 per household) are the largest categories followed by property taxes ($1,618 per household). Annual lottery ticket purchases are estimated to be $714 per household. State individual income taxes are only a small portion of taxes paid ($431 per household). 9

State and Local Taxes Paid by Households Headed by Immigrants Without a High School Diploma Chart 7 Total Taxes and Revenue $5,263 Other Taxes, $147 Motor Fuels Taxes, $194 Unemmployment & Workmens' Compensation, $453 Corporate Profits Tax, $132 Individual Income Tax, $431 Lottery Ticket Purchases, $714 Property Taxes, $1,618 Sales & Excise Tax, $1,706 Average Expenditure Per Household Aggregate Annual Net Fiscal Costs In 2004, there were 4.54 million low-skill immigrant households. The average net fiscal deficit per household for federal, state and local spending combined was $19,588. This means that the total annual fiscal deficit (total benefits received minus total taxes paid) for all 4.54 million low-skill immigrant households together equaled $89.1 billion. Over half of this fiscal deficit occurs at the state and local level. The annual fiscal deficit for all low skill immigrant households at the state and local level in 2004 10

was $49.1 billion. Over the next ten years the state and local fiscal deficit will approach a half trillion dollars. Net Fiscal Cost of All Low-Skill Immigrants to the State & Local Taxpayer Chart 8 $491 Billion Net Fiscal Cost $49.1 Billion Single Year Net Cost for 4.5 Million Low-Skill Immigrant Households Ten Year Cost for 4.5 Million Low-Skill Immigrant Households Estimation Methodology The methodology used for the state and local fiscal estimates in this testimony is fully explained in my recent publication, The Fiscal Cost of Low Skill Households to the U.S. Taxpayer. 7 The analysis is based on three core methodological principles: comprehensiveness; fiscal accuracy; and transparency. Comprehensiveness The analysis seeks to cover all government expenditures and all taxes and similar revenue sources for federal, state and local governments. Comprehensiveness helps to ensure balance in the analysis; if a study covers only a limited number of government spending programs or a portion of taxes, the omissions may bias the conclusions. Fiscal accuracy A cardinal principle of the estimation procedure employed for each expenditure program or category in the analysis is that, if the procedure is replicated for the whole U.S. population, the resulting estimated expenditure will equal actual expenditures on the program according to official budgetary documents. The same principle is applied 7 Robert Rector, Christine Kim, Shanea Watkins, The Fiscal Cost of Low-Skill Households to the U.S. Taxpayer, Heritage Special Report, Sr-12, The Heritage Foundation, Washington, D.C. April 4, 2007. 11

to each tax and revenue category. Altogether, the estimating procedures used in this paper, if applied to the entire U.S. population, will yield figures for total government spending and revenues that match the real life totals presented in budgetary sources. Transparency Specific calculations were made for 30 separate tax and revenue categories and over 60 separate expenditure categories. Since conclusions can be influenced by the assumptions and procedures employed in any analysis, we have endeavored make the mechanics of the analysis as transparent as possible to interested readers by describing the details of each calculation in the monograph. 8 Data on receipt of direct and means-tested benefits were taken from the U.S. Census Bureau s Current Population Survey (CPS). Data on attendance in public primary and secondary schools were also taken from the CPS; students attending public school were then assigned educational costs equal to the average per pupil expenditures in their state. Public post-secondary education costs were calculated in a similar manner. Wherever possible, the cost of population-based services was based on the estimated utilization of the service by low-skill immigrant households. For example, the low-skill immigrant households share of highway expenditures was assumed, in part, to equal their share of gasoline consumption as reported in the Bureau of Labor Statistics Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX). When data on utilization of a service were not available, the estimated low-skill immigrant households share of population-based services was assumed to equal their share of the total U.S. population. Sales, excise, and property tax payments were based on consumption data from the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX). For example, if the CEX showed that low-skill immigrant households accounted for 10 percent of all tobacco product sales in the U.S., those households were assumed to pay 10 percent of all tobacco excise taxes. Federal and state income taxes were calculated based on data from the CPS. Corporate income taxes were assumed to be borne partly by workers and partly by owners; the distribution of these taxes was estimated according to the distribution of earnings and property income in the CPS. CPS data generally underreport both benefits received and taxes paid somewhat. Consequently, both benefits and tax data from the CPS had to be adjusted for underreporting. The key assumption in this adjustment process was that households headed by immigrants without a high school diploma (low-skill immigrant households) and the general population underreport benefits and taxes to a similar degree. Thus, if food stamp benefits were underreported by 10 percent in the CPS as a whole, then lowskill immigrant households were also assumed to underreport food stamp benefits by 10 percent. In the absence of data suggesting that low-skill and high-skill households underreport at different rates, this seemed to be a reasonable working assumption. The 8 Robert Rector, The Fiscal Cost of Low-Skill Households to the U.S. Taxpayer, op. cit. 12

New Americans study of immigration by the National Academy of Sciences also adjusted for under-reporting in its fiscal analysis. Estimating Taxes and Benefits for Illegal Immigrant Households By most reports, there were some 11 million illegal immigrants in the U.S. in 2004. 9 About 9.3 million of these individuals were adults. 10 Roughly 50 to 60 percent of these illegal adult immigrants lacked a high school degree. 11 About ninety percent of illegal immigrants are reported in the CPS. 12 This testimony covers only those illegal immigrants reported in the CPS and does not address the remaining ten percent not counted by Census. Of the 4.5 million low-skill immigrant households analyzed in this report an estimated 41 percent were headed by illegal immigrants. 13 Households headed by illegal immigrants differ from other immigrant households in certain key respects. Illegal immigrants themselves are not eligible for means-tested welfare benefits, but illegal immigrant households do contain some 3 million children who were born inside the U.S. to illegal immigrant parents; these children are U.S. citizens and are eligible for and do receive means-tested welfare. Most of the tax and benefits estimates presented in this paper are unaffected by a low-skill immigrant household s legal status. For example, children in illegal immigrant households are eligible for, and do receive, public education. Similarly, nearly all the data on direct and means-tested government benefits in the CPS is based on a household s self report concerning receipt of each benefit by family members. Because eligibility for some benefits is limited for illegal immigrants, illegal immigrants will report lower benefit receipt in the CPS, thus, in most cases, this analysis automatically adjusts for the lower use of government and benefits by illegal immigrants. In a few isolated cases, the CPS data does not rely on a households self-report of receipt of benefits but imputes receipt to all households who are apparently eligible based on income level. The most notable example of this practice is the Earned Income tax Credit. Since illegal immigrant households are not eligible for the EITC, the CPS procedure assigns EITC benefits to illegal immigrant households which have not, in fact, been received by those households. To compensate for this mis-allocation of benefits, my analysis reduces the EITC benefits received by low-skill immigrant households by the portion of those households which are estimated to be illegal (roughly 40 percent). Similarly, the CPS assumes all laborers work on the books and pay taxes owed. CPS therefore imputes federal and state income taxes and FICA taxes based on household earnings. But most analyses assume that some 45 percent of illegal 9 Passel, 2005, op. cit., p. 2. 10 Ibid., p 6. 11 Passel, 2004, p.23 12 Passel, 2004, p. 4. 13 Information provided by Steven A. Camarota of the Center for Immigration Studies 13

immigrants work off the books, paying neither individual income nor FICA taxes. 14 The present analysis adjusts the estimated income and FICA taxes paid by low-skill immigrant households downward slightly to adjust for the off the books labor of lowskill illegal immigrants. The Net Retirement Costs of Amnesty to Illegal Immigrants Giving amnesty to illegal immigrants would increase the costs outlined in this testimony. Some 50 to 60 percent of illegal immigrants lack a high school degree. Granting amnesty or conditional amnesty to illegal immigrants would, overtime, increase their use of means-tested welfare, Social Security and Medicare. Fiscal costs would go up significantly in the short term but would go up dramatically after the amnesty recipient reached retirement. Based on my current research, I estimate that if all the current adult illegal immigrants in the U.S. were granted amnesty the net retirement costs to government (benefits minus taxes) could be over $2.5 trillion. The calculation of this figure is as follows. In March 2006, there were 9.3 million adult illegal immigrants in the U.S. Most illegal immigrants are low-skill. On average, each elderly low-skill immigrant creates a net cost (benefits minus taxes) for the taxpayer of about $17,000 per year. (This includes federal state and local government costs.) If the government gave amnesty to 9.3 million illegal immigrants, most of them would eventually become eligible for Social Security and Medicare benefits or Supplemental Security Income and Medicaid benefits. However, not all of the 9.3 million adults given amnesty would survive till age 67. Normal mortality rates would probably reduce the population by roughly 15 percent before age 67. That would mean 7.9 million individuals would reach 67 and enter retirement. Of those reaching 67, the average life expectancy would be around 18 years. The net governmental cost (benefits minus taxes) of these elderly individuals would be around $17,000 per year. Over eighteen years of expected life, costs would equal $306,000 per elderly amnesty recipient. A cost of $306,000 per amnesty recipient times 7.9 million amnesty recipients would be $2.4 trillion. These costs would hit the U.S. taxpayer at exactly the point that the Social Security system is expected to go into crisis. This is a preliminary estimate based on my ongoing research. More research should be performed, but I believe policy makers should examine these potential costs 14 Randy Capp, Everett Henderson, Jeffry S. Passel, and Michael Fix, Civic contributions Taxes Paid by Immigrant in the Washington, DC Metro Area,The Urban Institute, May 2006, footnote 3 on page 6. http://www.urban.org/uploadedpdf/411338_civic_contributions.pdf; Jeffrey S. Passel, Rebecca L. Clark, Immigrants in New York: Their Legal Status, Income and Taxes, Urban Institute, 1998, http://www.urban.org/publications/407432.html. Steve Camarota, The High Cost of Low Skill Labor, Center for Immigration Studies, op.cit. 14

carefully before rushing to grant amnesty, Z visas or earned citizenship to the current illegal immigrant population. Amnesty proponents may argue that some of these individuals will go home without getting benefits, or before they reach retirement age. Though perhaps valid, that argument only emphasizes how expensive amnesty recipients would be; the longer they remain in the country the greater the cost to the taxpayer. Potential Economic Gains and Losses from Low Skill Immigration While the fiscal consequences of low skill immigration are strongly negative, it is possible that low skill immigrants create economic benefits that partially compensate for the net tax burdens they create. For example, it is frequently argued that low skill immigration is beneficial because low skill immigrants expand the economy of gross domestic product (GDP). While it is obviously true that low skill immigrants enlarge the GDP, the problem with this argument is that the immigrants themselves capture most of the gain from expanded production in their own wages. Metaphorically, while low skill immigrants make the American economic pie larger, they themselves consume most of the pie slice their labor adds. This dilemma can be illustrated with the following example. Imagine a factory employing ten workers. One day, an eleventh worker is added and factory output goes up by 10 percent. The increase in factory output (equivalent to growth in GDP) appears quite beneficial, but from the perspective of the original ten factory workers, the relevant question is whether that extra output caused their wages to rise. The answer is probably no, in fact, in some circumstances their wages may fall. Merely adding extra workers to a factory or an economy does not magically cause the incomes of previous workers to go up. If simply adding laborers to an economy would automatically raise everyone s standard of living within the economy, economic development would be a remarkably easy task. The nations with the fastest population growth would soon have the most affluent citizens. Unfortunately, high quality economic growth (economic growth that raises overall living standards) is far more difficult to achieve. Adding more laborers does not automatically increase the standard of living of the existing citizenry; to raise living standards it is necessary to raise the output of the average worker. The central issue in the debate over the costs and benefits of low skill immigration is not whether such immigration makes the U.S. GDP larger (clearly it does), but whether low skill immigration raises the post tax income of the average non-immigrant American. Given the very large net tax burden that low skill immigrants impose on U.S. society, such immigrants would have to raise the incomes of non-immigrants to a remarkable degree to have a net beneficial effect. But there is little evidence to suggest that low skill immigrants increase the incomes of non-immigrants. The National Academy of Sciences, for example, estimated that all immigration produces a net economic gain of 15

only $1 to $10 billion per year; this gain is the result of a reduction in consumer prices that is driven be a decline in wages for low skill non-immigrant workers. Conclusion Understanding of the fiscal consequences of low skill immigration is impeded by a lack of understanding of the scope of government financial redistribution within U.S. society. It is a common misperception that the only individuals who are fiscally dependent (receiving more in benefits than they pay in taxes) are welfare recipients who perform little or no work, and that as long as an individual works regularly he must be a net tax producer (paying more in taxes than his family receives in benefits). In reality, the present welfare system is designed primarily to provide financial support to low income working families; moreover, welfare is only a modest part of the overall system of financial redistribution operated by the government. Current government policies provide extensive free or heavily subsidized aid to low skill families (both immigrant and non-immigrant) through welfare, Social Security, Medicare, public education and many other services. At the same time government requires these families to pay little in taxes. This very expensive assistance to the least advantaged American families has become accepted as our mutual responsibility for one another, but it is fiscally unsustainable to apply this system of lavish income redistribution to an inflow of millions of poorly educated immigrants. It is sometimes argued that since higher-skill immigrants are a net fiscal plus for the U.S. taxpayers while low-skill immigrants are a net loss, the two cancel each other out and therefore no problem exists. This is like a stock broker advising a client to buy two stocks, one which will make money and another that will lose money. Obviously, it would be better to purchase only the stock that will be profitable and avoid the money losing stock entirely. Similarly, low-skill immigrants increase poverty in the U.S. and impose a burden on taxpayers that should be avoided. Current immigration practices, both legal and illegal, operate like a system of trans-national welfare outreach bringing millions of fiscally dependent individuals into the U.S. This policy needs to be changed. U.S. immigration policy should encourage high-skill immigration and strictly limit low-skill immigration. In general, government policy should limit immigration to those who will be net fiscal contributors, avoiding those who will increase poverty and impose new costs on overburdened U.S. taxpayers. Recent proposed legislation in the Senate and House will do exactly the opposite. By granting amnesty to illegal immigrants (who are overwhelmingly low skilled) and creating massive new guest worker programs which would bring millions of additional low skill families into the nation, such legislation, if enacted, would impose massive costs on the U.S. taxpayer. * * * * * * * * * * * * * * * 16

The Heritage Foundation is a public policy, research, and educational organization operating under Section 501(C)(3). It is privately supported, and receives no funds from any government at any level, nor does it perform any government or other contract work. The Heritage Foundation is the most broadly supported think tank in the United States. During 2006, it had more than 283,000 individual, foundation, and corporate supporters representing every state in the U.S. Its 2006 income came from the following sources: Individuals 64% Foundations 19% Corporations 3% Investment Income 14% Publication Sales and Other 0% The top five corporate givers provided The Heritage Foundation with 1.3% of its 2006 income. The Heritage Foundation s books are audited annually by the national accounting firm of Deloitte & Touche. A list of major donors is available from The Heritage Foundation upon request. Members of The Heritage Foundation staff testify as individuals discussing their own independent research. The views expressed are their own, and do not reflect an institutional position for The Heritage Foundation or its board of trustees. 17