Causes of Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations,

Similar documents
The Relevance of Politically Relevant Dyads in the Study of Interdependence and Dyadic Disputes

All s Well That Ends Well: A Reply to Oneal, Barbieri & Peters*

The Classical Liberals Were Half Right (or Half Wrong): New Tests of the Liberal Peace, *

Dyadic Hostility and the Ties That Bind: State-to-State versus State-to-System Security and Economic Relationships*

The System Made Me Stop Doing It. The Indirect Origins of Commercial Peace

INDUCING AND SUPPRESSING CONFLICT IN INTERACTIVE INTERNATIONAL DYADS

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset.

Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies

Towards a Continuous Specification of the Democracy-Autocracy Connection. D. Scott Bennett The Pennsylvania State University

Democracy and the Settlement of International Borders,

A Re-assessment of Democratic Pacifism at the Monadic Level of Analysis

Violence Prediction. Christopher Murray, ed., Encyclopedia of Public Health (San Diego, CA: Academic Press, forthcoming 2003) Bruce Russett

Trade, Interdependence and its Effect on Interstate Conflict: The Case of the East African Region. Hailay Gebretinsae Beyene 1

The ~Ir!Relevance of Militarized Interstate Disputes for International Trade

University of Georgia, Athens, Georgia, USA

Trade Does Promote Peace: New Simultaneous Estimates of the Reciprocal Effects of Trade and Conflict

Trade Does Promote Peace: New Simultaneous Estimates of the Reciprocal Effects of Trade and Conflict*

Democracy and Trade: Ties of Interest and Community

CONSTRUCTING MULTIVARIATE ANALYSES (OF DANGEROUS DYADS)

Welcome to the Club: IGO Socialization and Dyadic Arms Transfers

THE EFFECTS OF THE SECURITY ENVIRONMENT ON MILITARY EXPENDITURES: POOLED ANALYSES OF 165 COUNTRIES,

Just War or Just Politics? The Determinants of Foreign Military Intervention

INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS

Conflict Emergence and Escalation in Interactive International Dyads

The Joint Democracy Dyadic Conflict Nexus: A Simultaneous Equations Model

Constructing Multivariate Analyses (of Dangerous Dyads)

Openness and Internal Conflict. Christopher S. P. Magee Department of Economics Bucknell University Lewisburg, PA

Exploring the Impact of Democratic Capital on Prosperity

Exploring Operationalizations of Political Relevance. November 14, 2005

Trade Networks and the Kantian Peace. Han Dorussen and Hugh Ward. University of Essex. 5 May 2007

The networked peace: Intergovernmental organizations and international conflict

A SUPPLY SIDE THEORY OF THIRD PARTY CONFLICT MANAGEMENT

Editorial Manager(tm) for British Journal of Political Science Manuscript Draft

Democratic Inefficiency? Regime Type and Sub-optimal Choices in International Politics

The Impact of Conflict on Trade Evidence from Panel Data (work-in-progress draft)

The Influence of International Organizations on Militarized Dispute Initiation and Duration 1

Interdependence, the spirit of commerce, and natural resources

Research Note: The Effects of the International Security Environment on National Military. Expenditures: A Multi-Country Study.

War, Alliances, and Power Concentration

Declining Benefits of Conquest? Economic Development and Territorial Claims in the Americas and Europe

General Deterrence and International Conflict: Testing Perfect Deterrence Theory

Being Gulliver: Diversionary War, Political Capital, and U.S. Intervention in Militarized Disputes. 10,957 Words

The Influence of International Organizations on Militarized Dispute Initiation and Duration. Megan Shannon University of Mississippi

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

Democratic vs. Capitalist Peace: A Test in the Developing World

Winning with the bomb. Kyle Beardsley and Victor Asal

The Impact of Conflict on Trade Evidence from Panel Data

Great Powers, Hierarchy, and Endogenous Regimes: Rethinking the Domestic Causes of Peace

Economic Interdependence and Armed Conflict: Some Qualifications of the Liberal Case

Democratic Peace Theory

Dangerous Dyads Revisited: Democracies May Not Be That Peaceful after All

The Ties that Bias Specifying and Operationalizing Components of Dyadic Dependence in International Conflict

THE JAMES A. BAKER III INSTITUTE FOR PUBLIC POLICY

Appendix: Regime Type, Coalition Size, and Victory

Incomplete Democratization and the Outbreak of Military Disputes

Peter Katzenstein, ed. The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics

Allying to Win. Regime Type, Alliance Size, and Victory

Power, Proximity, and Democracy: Geopolitical Competition in the International System

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

American Political Science Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American Political Science Review.

"The Costs of Reneging: Reputation and Alliance Formation"

POWER TRANSITIONS AND DISPUTE ESCALATION IN EVOLVING INTERSTATE RIVALRIES PAUL R. HENSEL. and SARA MCLAUGHLIN

VETO PLAYERS AND MILITARIZED INTERSTATE CONFLICT

How to Intervene in Civil Wars: Strategic Interests, Humanitarianism, and Third-Party Intervention. Sang Ki Kim University of Iowa

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One

Public Opinion on Geopolitics and Trade: Theory and Evidence. IPES November 12, 2016

International Institutions

Institutions and Collective Goods

Permanent Friends? Dynamic Difference and the Democratic Peace. 1 January Abstract

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict,

The terrorist attacks on the World Trade Center and the Pentagon in 2001 revealed

Leader Change and the World Trade Organization The Impact on Leader Turnover on the Onset and Resolution of International Trade Disputes

How do domestic political institutions affect the outcomes of international trade negotiations?

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES?

WEB APPENDIX. to accompany. Veto Players and Terror. Journal of Peace Research 47(1): Joseph K. Young 1. Southern Illinois University.

Hearing on the U.S. Rebalance to Asia

The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

PROBLEMS OF CREDIBLE STRATEGIC CONDITIONALITY IN DETERRENCE by Roger B. Myerson July 26, 2018

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each


Perilous Polities? Regime Transition and Conflict

Trade Blocs, Trade Flows, and International Con ict

Strengthening Protection of Labor Rights through Preferential Trade Agreements (PTAs)

go to war. Institutions & democracy. Critiques of the democratic peace. One of the most widely accepted findings/theories in IR.

Dublin City Schools Social Studies Graded Course of Study American History

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

The 2017 TRACE Matrix Bribery Risk Matrix

Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia. Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware. and

Democratic International Governmental Organizations Promote Peace

International Migration and Military Intervention in Civil War

1 Introduction. Cambridge University Press International Institutions and National Policies Xinyuan Dai Excerpt More information

The Liberal Peace Revisited: The Role of Democracy, Dependence, and Development in Militarized Interstate Dispute Initiation,

Reanalysis: Are coups good for democracy?

Theory, Data, and Deterrence: A Response to Kenwick, Vasquez, and Powers*

Trade, Border Effects, and Regional Integration between Russia s Far East and Northeast Asia

Territorial Integrity Treaties and Armed Conflict over Territory *

Last time we discussed a stylized version of the realist view of global society.

International Law and the Settlement of Territorial Claims in South America, Paul R. Hensel John Tures

Transcription:

Paper presented at the 2001 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco, CA Causes of Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations, 1885-1992 John R. Oneal University of Alabama Bruce Russett Yale University July 1, 2001 Authors note: We thank Michael Berbaum, Håvard Hegre, J. Lew Silver, Frances Oneal, and Peter van den Dugen for helpful advice on difficult issues, and the institutions that supported this research: the Ford Foundation, the Norwegian Nobel Institute, and the U.S.-Norway Fulbright Foundation for Educational Exchange. Earlier versions of the paper were presented at the workshop on Globalization and Armed Conflict of the European Consortium on Political Research, Copenhagen, April 15-19, 2000; the Norwegian Nobel Institute, May 11, 2000; and the annual meeting of the Peace Science Society (International), New Haven, CT, October 28, 2000.

Causes of Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations, 1885-1992 Abstract: Whereas single-equation analyses have provided important evidence for the Kantian theory of peace, a satisfactory evaluation of the theory requires establishing the causal direction among the variables. Here we focus on the dynamics of reciprocal causation between economic interdependence and interstate conflict over the period 1885-1992. Using distributed-lag analyses, we find that trade does have a substantively important, causal effect in reducing militarized disputes between dyads, especially serious conflict involving military fatalities. Militarized disputes also cause a reduction in trade, as liberal theory predicts. Our analyses indicate that democracy and joint membership in intergovernmental organizations, too, have important pacific benefits. Democratization does not increase the incidence of interstate disputes; and contrary to realists expectations, allied states are not less conflict-prone than those that are unallied. Democracies and members of international organizations have higher levels of trade, but allies do not, ceteris paribus.

Causes of Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations, 1885-1992 In Perpetual Peace (1927 [1795]), Immanuel Kant suggested that international peace could be established on a foundation of three elements: republican constitutions, cosmopolitan law embodied in free trade and economic interdependence, and international law and organizations. This was a visionary proposal. There were very few democracies in the world in the late 1700s and no international organizations as we now know them. There was trade, of course; but most countries followed mercantilist principles: subordinating the economy to the interests of the state, seeking economic independence when possible, and pursuing economic gains through the use of force. Though Kant presented his ideas over 200 years ago, it has only recently become possible to evaluate his philosophical proposal scientifically. In this article we focus on the causal character of the relations between the Kantian influences and peace by analyzing pooled dyadic time series. Over the past twenty years, research on the causes of war has progressed rapidly by examining relations of pairs of states (dyads) observed through time. The analysis of dyadic time series marks an important advance over previous research at either the global or the state level. Attention to the behavior of pairs of states directly addresses the questions of greatest concern to political scientists and policy makers alike: which states are likely to fight one another, and which will remain at peace? Thus dyadic studies escape the ecological fallacy that plagued previous research at the systemic level. At the same time, unlike investigations of the behavior of individual nations, dyadic analyses easily accommodate variables that are inherently relational in character, including those central to realist theories of world politics: the balance of power and the existence of an alliance. 1

Though dyadic analyses have added to our understanding of international relations, few have exploited the dynamic information contained in the pooled time series. Here we do that by asking whether the Kantian influences trade, institutionalized democracy, and joint memberships in intergovernmental organizations (IGOs) affect the likelihood of militarized interstate disputes, holding constant the influence of past conflicts. Answers to these questions, when interpreted in the light of theory, give us important insights into the causal forces shaping interstate relations. This is important if we are to recommend to policy makers that they promote democracy and trade internationally and participate in international organizations as means of increasing the prospects for peace. Previous research on the Kantian peace is suggestive but not conclusive on this point. It is likely that there are important reciprocal relations between the Kantian influences (and some realist variables) and the probability of interstate violence. A history of conflict may cause a nation to restrict personal liberties or even suspend democracy, becoming a garrison state (Lasswell 1941). Similarly, states willingness to participate in IGOs with others may depend on the tenor of their relations, and this causal link may dominate the effect of international organizations on the likelihood of conflict: states may share membership in many IGOs only when they have a history of peaceful relations, and these shared associations may have no causal influence on the prospects for continued peace. The problem of reciprocal causation is most evident, however, when we consider the interaction of economic interdependence and peace. Kant and other classical liberals expected states to be constrained from resorting to force when they share important commercial relations precisely because conflict would threaten their interdependence and jeopardize the gains from trade. Economic agents are unlikely to trade and invest abroad if military conflict is a serious risk. To clarify the causal effects of democracy, interdependence, and intergovernmental organizations on the likelihood of dyadic conflict, we use regression analyses that incorporate 2

distributed lags of important liberal and realist variables as well as the dyad s history of conflict. These tests are in the spirit of Granger s test of causality. Granger (1969) proposed that a variable X might be a cause of Y if past values of X can be used to predict Y more accurately than using past values of Y alone. Using data for the period 1885-1992 regarding nearly 10,000 pairs of states, we determine if past values of the Kantian influences allow a better prediction of the current likelihood of a dyadic dispute than the history of their past disputes and other controls. We also take advantage of the information in our pooled time series to address other questions regarding the dynamics of interstate relations. We determine whether the process of democratization (Mansfield and Snyder 1995, 1996) or expectations regarding future economic relations (Copeland 1996, 2000) affect the prospects for peace, thus expanding our comprehension of the stability of the Kantian system. Finally, we examine the dynamics of the balance of power by evaluating power-transition theory (Organski and Kugler 1980). The Kantian Peace In an examination of the period 1885-1992, Russett and Oneal (2001) estimate the chance of a dyadic dispute as a function of the following factors: the character of the states political regimes, the economic importance of their bilateral trade, the number of IGOs in which they shared membership, whether the two states were allied, and the bilateral balance of power. They estimated the importance of these influences while controlling for contiguity, the distance separating the two states, and whether one state in the dyad was a major power. Strong support for liberal theory emerged. Compared with a typical pair of states, the annual probability of a militarized interstate dispute falls by 33 percent if the level of democracy in the less democratic state in the dyad the state less constrained politically is higher by one standard deviation, all other variables held constant. Economic interdependence, too, limits the use of force. The probability of a dispute drops by 43 percent, compared to the typical dyad, if both states are economically dependent on 3

their commercial relations. And a dense network of involvement in IGOs is associated with a 24 percent reduction in conflict. This discussion of the independent effects of the three Kantian elements understates the benefits of Kant s prescription for peace because, in reality, democracy or interdependence or involvement in IGOs does not normally increase while the others remain constant. As Kant anticipated, these elements of the liberals political and economic program are integrally related. By institutional and normative means, the leaders of democratic states are constrained from resorting to force against other democracies; but democracy, because it recognizes and encourages individual liberty and responsibility, fosters entrepreneurship and the expansion of commerce beyond a nation s boundaries. As the economic activities of citizens make countries interdependent, there is need for institutions that can regulate and facilitate commercial relations. International law and organizations are the natural response. Thus there is a logical sequence that links the freedom of citizens in democratic states to expanding commerce over a widening geographical area and to the growth of international institutions. 1 If all the Kantian influences are increased simultaneously, the probability of a dispute drops 71 percent below the rate for the typical pair of states (Russett and Oneal 2001). These strong results in support of the democratic peace and the constraining influence of economically important trade are consistent with other recent research. The separate peace among democracies has been substantiated in a great variety of tests over the years. Chan (1997), Ray (1998), and Russett and Starr (2000) survey this vast literature. There have been fewer investigations of the benefits of economic interdependence, but support for the liberal view is extensive and growing; McMillan (1997), Copeland (2000), and Mansfield and Pollins (2001) provide useful surveys. The contribution of international organizations, on the other hand, has not been widely examined and the results are less consistent. 4

Bennett and Stam (2000) provide a particularly valuable independent assessment of the Kantian peace. They use several alternative estimators and specifications, and they control for several other influences thought to affect the incidence of dyadic conflict. Their tests include an indicator that conflict is likely based on the game-theoretic model proposed by Bueno de Mesquita and Lalman (1992). This is important because many regard that model of the strategic behavior of self-interested, expected-utility maximizers as the most sophisticated theory of interstate conflict. Bennett and Stam s results are consistent with the democratic peace in all twelve of their tests involving non-directed dyads. 2 Economic interdependence is significantly related to peaceful relations in nine of the twelve: the same number as the indicator of whether a dyad includes a major power and more than any other theoretically interesting variable except democracy. Joint membership in IGOs was not statistically significant in any test, but this is due in part to their sample of cases. Bennett and Stam include all possible pairs of states. Evidence for the pacific benefits of IGOs is much greater when analysis is restricted to politically relevant dyads (Oneal and Russett 1999b). It is also greater, even in analyses of all possible pairs of states, if the increasing trend in the number of international organizations through time is factored out. The evidence supports a good prognosis because democracy is likely to continue to spread and interdependence to grow. A reduction in interstate violence would be a by-product of the rational pursuit of people s self-interested desire for freedom and prosperity. It is encouraging that peace does not depend on moral conversion. The prospects for peace are good, as Kant (1927 [1795]) noted, as long as even devils can calculate. Of course, realist principles still dominate interstate relations outside the Kantian system: overwhelming power does reduce the likelihood of conflict (Kugler and Lemke, eds. 1996). But as weapons of mass destruction became accessible to more and more states it is essential to find a safer, more sure foundation for a peaceful international system. Democracy, interdependence, and international organizations offer this promise. 5

Accounting for Reciprocal Relations If we are to have confidence in this prognosis and encourage policies promoting liberal institutions and values, we must be as sure as science will allow that the Kantian influences cause a reduction in interstate conflict. Of course, as Hume cautioned, we can never establish causal relations beyond doubt; but we must do what we can to guard against the possibility that causality runs only from peace to the Kantian factors, or that the correlations are spurious because of the influence of some third factor. Indeed, as noted earlier, it is likely that there are important reciprocal relations between democracy, interdependence, and involvement in IGOs, on the one hand, and peace, on the other. This is most evident in the case of commerce: in the liberal view, it is the fear that conflict will disrupt beneficial commerce that leads a state to refrain from using military force against another. Thus the relationship between interdependence and peace is expected to be reciprocal: each is endogenously determined; neither is exogenously given. 3 Russett and Oneal (2001: ch. 6) recognize these and other elements of endogeneity, but do not test for it beyond single equations with lagged variables. They find that the effect of a militarized dispute on dyadic trade is modest. Conflict does reduce commerce, as expected; but the decline is only 8 per cent. 4 That is substantially weaker than the lagged effect of trade on disputes which they report. This is some evidence that economically important trade really does reduce conflict and is not just a consequence of previous, peaceful interstate relations; but it is hardly decisive. We need to consider the reciprocal relation more carefully. Various analysts (Pollins 1989a,b; Gowa and Mansfield 1993) show that trade is influenced by states' security interests. There are two ways this may occur. First, a state is apt to restrict commerce with its adversaries, fearing that they will use the economic gains from trade to threaten its interests. Unless the benefits of trade are exactly equal, one side gains more resources, relative to its partner, that could be devoted to the military. Thus, states must be concerned with the relative 6

gains from trade, not just their absolute benefits. In times of war especially, states seek to prevent their citizens from "trading with the enemy." Commerce between states at war was not uncommon in earlier centuries (Barbieri and Levy 1999), but modern states are more effective in limiting such activity. 5 States can also act against countries with which they are not actually at war, for example, by limiting the sale of goods that are considered strategic: key raw materials or technological products with possible military applications. Many such restrictions were imposed on East-West trade during the cold war, and the United States retains significant limitations on trade with China, Russia, and other countries, as well as a virtually complete embargo on trade with Cuba, Iran, Iraq, Libya, and North Korea. Trade with adversaries is also limited by the self-interested actions of businessmen, even without government sanctions. Entrepreneurs, as rational actors, will reduce trade when they see their goods or their lives are endangered by military hostilities. At a minimum, they will seek a greater margin of profit or more complete insurance coverage to compensate for the risk; but these actions raise costs and lower demand, reducing commerce. Secondly, security interests affect the pattern of trade because states often seek to increase their economic interdependence with those with whom they have good relations. They promote trade with states deemed reliable sources of key products like food, raw materials, and militarily important technology; just as they may discourage it, by various barriers, with adversaries and potential enemies (Krasner 1978). Trade among the members of an alliance is generally thought to be greater than expected on purely economic grounds because they need not fear that the economic gains that arise from their commercial relations will be used for hostile purposes. Indeed, Gowa (1994) and Mansfield and Bronson (1997a,b) find that states do trade more with their allies than with neutrals or adversaries. Morrow, Siverson, and Tabares (1998, 1999), however, report that this relationship is not robust. It is certainly important, however, to determine whether interdependence has important pacific benefits when the influence of alliances is held constant. 7

While states may be reluctant to trade with states that may become their adversaries (Grieco 1988), most states most of the time are not actively adversarial. Then, liberals argue, it is the absolute gains accruing to each trading partner that primarily motivates their behavior (Snidal 1991). Indeed, Morrow (1997) shows analytically that relative gains should rarely impede trade even between potential adversaries. But the incentives for trade are undoubtedly greatest for countries that enjoy peaceful relations. Such countries can enter into relationships of economic interdependence to improve their standards of living without worrying much about which gains more. In Powell s (1991: 1313) words, If the use of force is no longer at issue, then a state s relative loss will not be turned against the state. Relative gains no longer matter, and cooperation now becomes feasible. In addition, the absolute gains that result from trade increase each state s security vis-à-vis potentially hostile third parties. Of course, private actors have their own incentives to trade when states enjoy a stable peace. In a good review of the literature, Reuveny (2000: 37) says that, because trade and conflict plausibly affect each other, studies which neglect that interaction are likely to be misspecified. Thus, simultaneity and dynamic modeling ought to become routine features of future studies. Several efforts have been made to address this issue. At the systemic level, Mansfield (1994) estimated a system of two simultaneous equations, one predicting the level of global trade and the other the number of wars in the international system. Early dyadic investigations (Polachek (1980, 1997) used two-stage and three-stage least squares regression analysis in recognition of the reciprocal relation between trade and conflict. Recently, Kim (1998) used simultaneous equations to disentangle the reciprocal relations between bilateral trade and dyadic interstate conflict, 1950-85. Her work is particularly important because she has a large number of cases and considers only militarized disputes and war (not political tensions). She concludes that the effect of trade on conflict is stronger than the effect of conflict on trade. This concurs with Hegre and Kim s (2000) 8

analysis of economic openness (the total trade-to-gdp ratio) and involvement in military conflict at the national level of analysis. Beck et al. (1998) propose an alternative method to deal with the effect of past conflict on the current probability of a dispute. They note that the time series of pooled analyses are not composed of independent observations, violating one of the assumptions of regression analysis. Beck et al. suggest borrowing the insight central to statistical hazard models and estimating the effects of theoretically interesting variables while controlling for the length of time that has elapsed since the dyad s last dispute. With this technique, they find that democracy has important pacific benefits but that the bilateral trade-to-gdp ratio no longer is significantly related to a reduced probability of conflict. Since then, it has been demonstrated that, with longer time series or a variety of alternative specifications, the benefits of economically important trade are statistically significant and substantively important even controlling for the history of dyadic disputes (Oneal and Russett 1999a, 1999b, 2001; Bennett and Stam 2000; Hegre 2000; Mousseau 2000; Gartzke, Li, and Boehmer 2001). Neither a system of simultaneous equations (or the related techniques of two- and threestage least squares analysis) nor controlling for the years of peace since a dyad s most recent conflict (using either hazard analysis or Beck et al. s (1998) method) is fully satisfactory. The first approach depends on the assumption that the reciprocal effects are simultaneous; i.e., that conflict in a particular year affects trade only in the same year and vice versa (Wold 1981). It seems more likely that the occurrence of a militarized dispute in one year will affect decisions by investors and traders for a number of years into the future. This is Beck et al. s essential insight. But important commercial relations, too, may have a long-term effect: the likelihood of conflict will be lower for a dyad with a long history of close economic ties, even if it were recently involved in a dispute, than if the two states had never been interdependent. Controlling for the years of peace does not allow 9

for this possibility. Indeed, it assumes that the number of years elapsed since the last dispute is independent of the influences of the theoretical variables included in the regression analysis (Beck and Tucker 1996). It is much more likely that the years of peace that a dyad has enjoyed is itself a function of the past character of the two states political systems, the level of their trade, etc. 6 The problem inherent in simply controlling for the years of peace is particularly evident in the case of interdependence. Trade falls with the occurrence of a dispute. Commerce rises over time after a dispute has ended as traders confidence in the durability of peace increases. Thus commercial relations are expected, on theoretical grounds, to be correlated with the years of peace. It is not surprising, then, that the statistical significance of interdependence often declines in the presence of such a control. Decisions on how to treat temporal dependence must take into account the theory being tested as well the methodological problems to be resolved, as Bennett (1999), too, observes. A distributed-lags model, based on Granger-causality testing, is an additional way to address the issue of endogeneity. Using Granger s (1969) logic, democracy, economically important trade, etc. can plausibly be considered causes of peace if their past values can be used to predict the current likelihood of a dispute more accurately than using dyads histories of disputes alone. The statistical test establishes precedence among the variables, and theory provides the causal connection. A distributed-lags model has several advantages. First, it does not assume that reciprocal effects are simultaneous but allows for conflict to affect the likelihood of conflict over a period of years. Second, it controls for temporal dependence in a manner that is substantially richer and more complete than a count of the time elapsed since the last dispute. In estimating the current likelihood of conflict, it can distinguish, for example, between a dyad that enjoyed an extended period of peace and then experienced a military dispute from a pair of states that had a dispute every year for many years. Third, it allows the past values of the variables of theoretical interest to 10

influence the current likelihood of conflict. Thus, long-term benefits of interdependence, etc. that ameliorate the harmful effects of a recent conflict can be detected. Fourth, it provides some protection against accepting a spurious correlation as evidence of a causal relation, because the lagged indicators of dyads involvement in militarized disputes act as proxies for explanatory variables omitted from the regression equation (Burkhart and Lewis-Beck 1994). Finally, and not least important, it is simple to implement. Gasiorowski and Polacheck (1982) looked at political conflict and cooperation between the United States and the Warsaw Pact using Granger tests; and Reuveny and Kang (1996, 1998) used vector autoregression analysis of the political relations of 16 and 19 dyads respectively. Gasiorowski and Polacheck found that trade reduces the incidence of conflict, independent of past levels of violence; Reuveny and Kang s results were more mixed. We focus on militarized interstate disputes, not political conflict of a non-violent nature, and employ the technique of lagged variables on a much longer period and for many more dyads: all states in the system for which data are available. That is important, because, as Reuveny (2000) notes, the relationship may vary substantially across dyads, so a small sample may not capture an important relationship. In widening the sample, we lose the opportunity to model separately the behavior of exporters, importers, and governments, and of variation across goods, as Reuveny urges. At present, the data necessary to do this for many dyads do not exist. Historical Domain, Key Variables, and Sources of Data We analyze dyadic interstate behavior, 1885-1992, for all dyads. Thus we examine the Kantian peace over a long period before the cold war and a few years after. All but the first year of World War I and II are omitted because bilateral trade data are fragmentary, as they are for the immediate postwar years, 1919-20 and 1946-49. Omitting all but the first year of the world wars, which consisted of conflicts between democracies and autocracies or between two autocracies, 11

biases our results against the democratic peace; but it also provides assurance that our results are not determined by these dramatic but atypical events (Farber and Gowa 1997). Our variables and data are very similar to those used in Russett and Oneal (2001), which can be consulted for additional information. The Variables to be Explained: Onset of Militarized Disputes and of Fatal Militarized Disputes The Correlates of War (COW) project has identified militarized interstate disputes, 1816-1992, and assembled information regarding the dispute and the participants (Jones, Bremer, and Singer 1996). Maoz (1999) has noted, however, that states on opposite sides of a multilateral dispute may never have directly threatened, displayed, or used force against one another. For example, Bulgaria and Japan are listed on opposite sides in World War I, but there is no evidence that they were directly engaged in conflict. Consequently, in order to identify those dyads where the states actually confronted one another, we use Maoz s dyadic dispute data. The variable ONSET equals 1 if either state threatened to use force, made a demonstration of its military capabilities, or actually used force against the other; it equals 0 otherwise. We also consider the onset of fatal disputes, conflicts in which at least one member of the armed forces of the parties to the conflict died. Focusing on these particularly violent conflicts serves two purposes. First, it reduces bias in the reporting of less severe military incidents. The use of force at even a low level in Western Europe, e.g., small arms fire across an international border, would not go unreported in the Western media from which the COW data are gleaned; such incidents in Africa are apt often to go unnoticed. Attention to fatal disputes also insures that our analyses are relevant to the violent interstate conflict of greatest concern to political scientists and policy makers alike. Many disputes are limited in severity and pose little real danger to peace. For example, on several occasions, Peru used its navy to seize American fishing boats that entered the territorial waters it claimed. This is coded by the COW project as an actual use of force (four on a 12

5-point scale), though there was little risk of armed conflict between the two countries. Our second dependent variable (FATAL) equals 1 in the first year in which a dyad was involved in a dispute that involved at least one military fatality; it equals zero otherwise. Explanatory Variables: Democracy. We use the Polity III data (Jaggers and Gurr 1995, 1996) to compute a summary measure of the political character of regimes, subtracting from each country s score on the democracy scale its score on the autocracy scale. The result (DEM i ) ranges from -10 for an extreme autocracy to +10 for the most democratic states. Because a dispute can result from the actions of a single state, the likelihood of conflict should be primarily a function of the degree of constraint experienced by the less constrained state in each dyad. We expect, therefore, that the less democratic state (DEM L ) in a dyad determines most strongly the danger of interstate violence: the more democratic this state, the more constrained from engaging in a dispute it will be, and the more peaceful the dyad. Economic Interdependence. For the post-world War II era we use a new data set (Gleditsch 2000). It relies in large part on the same sources that have been used previously: the International Monetary Fund for bilateral trade data and the Penn World Tables for information on nations GDPs, but Gleditsch supplies much data previously unavailable, notably on trade among communist countries. Since trade is expected to influence dyadic relations only if it is economically important, we divide the sum of a country s exports and imports with its partner by its GDP. As with the influence of democratic institutions, we expect the likelihood of a dispute to be primarily a function of the freedom of the less constrained state to use force. This is indicated by the bilateral trade-to- GDP ratio of the state less economically dependent on trade with its dyadic partner (DEPEND L ). For the years before 1950, both bilateral trade data and GDPs are harder to acquire. For 1920-1938 we use the data on bilateral trade in current values and the exchange rates compiled by 13

the League of Nations. Before World War I, annual editions of The Statesman s Yearbook are the closest approximation to an institutional source of trade data. We also collected alternative estimates, compared them to our initial data set, and adjusted it accordingly. Maddison (1995) provides GDP for 56 countries in all regions of the world for 1870-1992. We used these with data on annual energy consumption (Singer and Small 1995) to estimate missing GDP information. 7 Joint IGO memberships. We assess the influence of international organizations on interstate conflicts by counting the number of IGOs in which both states in a dyad share membership as indicated in the Yearbook of International Organizations. This is by no means an ideal measure of the importance and effectiveness of international organizations. It includes organizations that are weak and strong, regional and global, functional and multipurpose. Ideally, the total should be broken down and some organizations given special weight, but this effort is only beginning (Boehmer, Gartzke, and Nordstrom 2000). Consequently, we use the simple count of joint memberships; but to eliminate the strong rising trend in the absolute number of international organizations, we calculated states involvement in IGOs relative to the yearly average for all states. 8 Capability ratio. Realists emphasize the importance of the balance of power in interstate relations. The belief that an equal distribution of power deters conflict has deep historical roots, as does the idea that a preponderance of capabilities, by reducing uncertainty as to which side would win a contest of arms, is more likely to preserve the peace. Recent empirical work suggests, however, that it is preponderance that deters military action (Bremer 1992,1993; Kugler and Lemke, eds. 1996), and that is our hypothesis. Our index of relative power (CAPRATIO) is the natural logarithm of the ratio of the stronger state s military capability index to that of the weaker member. We use the COW project s data (Singer and Small 1995) on population, industry, and military forces to calculate military capabilities. 14

Alliance. Allies are thought to fight each other less than other states because they share common security interests, as well as other political and economic interests. We control for this influence using a variable (ALLIES) that equals 1 if the members of a dyad were linked by a mutual defense treaty, neutrality pact, or entente; it equals 0 otherwise. We updated information in Singer (1995) using Rengger with Campbell (1995). Contiguity and distance. A potential for violence exists when at least one member of a dyad can reach the other with militarily effective force. For most states, that ability derives from geographic proximity. Furthermore, neighbors are likely to have the most reasons to fight over territorial boundaries, natural resources, irredentism, etc. Thus, distance reduces the capability to fight and most of the incentives to do so as well. Because of the importance of this influence, we include two different terms to capture it as fully as possible. DISTANCE is the natural logarithm of the great circle distance in miles between the two states capitals (or major ports for the largest countries); using the logarithm acknowledges a declining marginal effect. We also include NONCONTIG, which equals 1 if two states are not directly or indirectly contiguous (via colonies or other dependencies), and 0 if they share a land border or are separated by less than 150 miles of water. Because of widespread colonial empires for much of the period, these two measures are not highly correlated (r = 0.44). The effect of distance in constraining conflict, however, is less for the great powers: those with the ability to deliver substantial forces or destructive power globally. These major powers have been identified by the COW project based on the consensus of historians. As an additional realist variable we add MINORPWRS, coded 1 if a dyad is composed of minor powers and 0 for those that include at least one great power. 15

Results: Trade Reduces Conflict To clarify the causal relations connecting the Kantian influences to the onset of a militarized interstate dispute, we use distributed-lags analyses of pooled cross-sectional and time series data. The function linking the explanatory factors to the left-hand-side variable is logistic because our measure of interstate conflict is dichotomous. We calculate statistical significances using robust standard errors controlling for clustering by dyads (StataCorp 1999). We begin with our model of fatal interstate disputes: FATAL t = DEM L,t-1 + + DEM L,t-7 + DEPEND L,t-1 + + DEPEND L,t-7 + IGO t-1 + + IGO t-7 (1) + CAPRATIO t-1 + + CAPRATIO t-7 + ALLIES t-1 + ALLIES t-7 + NONCONTIG t-1 + DISTANCE + MINORPWRS t-1 + FATAL t-1 + + FATAL t-7 We account for the onset of a fatal militarized dispute for a pair of states in year t using seven lagged values of each of the main liberal and realist variables. Their influences are estimated while controlling for the history of dyadic disputes over the same period, whether the two states shared a border (either directly or through a dependency), the distance separating them, and whether the dyad included a major power. The last three variables are considered strictly exogenous, so only one value is included. For the other variables, the number of lags to be included was determined by adding terms until additional lags of FATAL were no longer statistically significant. In this way, we seek to insure that we have thoroughly controlled for the influence of past disputes on the current likelihood of conflict. If the other variables still add to the explanation of interstate violence, the causal relation posited by liberal or realist theory is corroborated. The results of estimating equation 1 are reported in Table 1. Instead of giving the coefficients for all the individual terms, we report the sum of the seven coefficients for DEM L, DEPEND L, etc.; the chi 2 statistic for each of these sets of variables; and the probability that the individual coefficients are jointly insignificant. The sum of the coefficients indicates the net effect of a variable if its value remained constant over the seven-year period; the probability associated 16

with the chi 2 statistic is the likelihood that this net effect is zero. The coefficient, standard error, and the probability associated with the Wald test are reported for the strictly exogenous variables. - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - Table 1 about here - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - Column 1 shows the results for the onset of fatal disputes. Notably, the sums of the coefficients of each of the Kantian variables DEM L, DEPEND L, and IGO are negative, showing that higher levels of democracy, interdependence, and involvement in international organizations reduce the likelihood of a dyadic dispute. Indeed, joint memberships in intergovernmental organizations are more closely associated with peaceful outcomes in this distributed-lag analysis than in previous research. Moreover, this greater statistical significance is reflected in a much larger substantive effect, as will be seen. All the variables in the model liberal and realist are statistically significant at the.001 level except for the trade-to-gdp ratio (p <.03) and the indicator of an alliance. Surprisingly, allies are not significantly (p <.59) less likely to fight than non-allies; indeed, the sum of the coefficients is positive. As expected, a history of disputes increases the likelihood of a fatal dispute in the current year, and a preponderance of power, indicated by a large capability ratio, lowers the incidence of conflict. States that do not share a border and states distant from one another have fewer disputes. So too do minor powers. These results are robust with regard to the number of lags included in the analysis. The results in column 2 for the onset of all disputes (not just those with fatalities) are very similar, at least for liberal theory. Six lagged values were sufficient to account for the influence of past disputes on the current likelihood of conflict. The coefficients of most of the theoretical terms are smaller, but all except the capability ratio (p <.04) are significant at the.001 level. The surprising result here is that allied states again have a greater incidence of disputes than do non- 17

allied states, and now this result is very significant statistically (p <.001). A possible explanation is suggested by Siverson and Starr (1991: 93) who, despite regarding alliances as a constraint on the use of force, also note that they create salience and/or the ease of interaction. Evidently, alliances produce not just bonds of security, but grounds for diplomatic disagreement about institutions, decision-making procedures, burden-sharing, strategy, and related matters. Thus they raise the possibility of diplomatic and political disagreement, and even of some militarized disputes. Alliances with a major power especially carry some danger (Oneal and Russett 1997, 1999a). Great powers sometimes are willing to threaten or use force against smaller allies to enforce their spheres of influence. Alliances among minor powers are more consistently associated with peaceful relations. The pacifying effect of being allies also varies through time. It was much stronger during the cold war than in the years before World War II; and the effect was particularly uncertain in the interwar years, 1920-1939 (Russett and Oneal 2001). Bennett and Stam (2000) also report substantial variation in the consequences of an alliance. Allies prove significantly less likely to fight in only two of their twelve tests for non-directed dyads. Ultimately, it is the substantive significance of each influence that matters. If interdependent states, for example, were less likely to fight than others, but the change in the probability of conflict were small, the result would be merely academic. We hope for results that are substantively important (indicated by the magnitude of the regression coefficients) as well as reliable and consistent (shown by the tests of statistical significance) especially if a variable is amenable to manipulation by deliberate national policy. It becomes increasingly important to consider the practical implications of our findings as the size of the sample increases. 9 It is hard to interpret the coefficients of logistic regression analyses because the curve that is fitted is S-shaped rather than linear, but we can make our results more concrete by estimating the effect each theoretical variable has on the likelihood that a militarized dispute will begin. First, we 18

calculated a baseline probability against which to make comparisons. We assumed that the dyad had not had a dispute in the period represented in the lagged terms (seven years for fatal disputes, six years in the analysis of all disputes), and we set all the lags of each of the continuous variables at the same relatively low level, the value taken by a dyad at the tenth percentile among the contiguous pairs of states. We postulated that the members of the dyad shared a border, were not allied, and were not major powers. The distance between their capitals was set at the mean for the contiguous pairs. We estimated the annual probability of the onset of a fatal militarized dispute for this dyad, which serves as a baseline for comparison, using the estimated coefficients in column 1, Table 1. To show the substantive effects of the theoretically interesting variables, we increased each of them, one at a time, to the value taken by a dyad at the ninetieth percentile among the contiguous dyads, or made the states allies. - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - Table 2 about here - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -- As seen in column 1 of Table 2, the baseline probability for the onset of a fatal dispute is.0086. Increasing the lower democracy score reduces this enormously by 86 percent. Raising the bilateral trade-to-gdp ratio, while holding all other variables at their baseline values, lowers the probability of a dispute to.0058, a reduction of 32 percent. An increase in the pair s involvement in IGOs from the tenth to the ninetieth percentile causes the likelihood of conflict to drop by 43 percent. Making the states allied has little effect an increase of 1 percent. Increasing the preponderance of the more powerful state greatly lowers the risk of a militarized dispute, by 71 percent. Yet this can hardly be taken as support for a policy of peace through strength. To go from the tenth to the ninetieth percentile means increasing the superiority of the more powerful state from 1.3:1 to 50.7:1. Such an increase is well beyond the capacity of policy makers even in the long 19

term. This is evident if it is recalled that the capability ratio is calculated using the population and industry of states as well as military measures. Just as the significance levels for the onset of all disputes were not much different from those for all disputes, the changes in probabilities in column 2 are quite similar to those in column 1. The effect of a predominance of power is notably reduced, but still is important. The impacts of democracy and interdependence are also lower but continue to be substantial. The effect of sharing common memberships in international organizations is equal to that of trade. Our distributed-lags analyses capturing the impact of variables over time reveal a stronger effect for IGOs than do previous analyses that simply lag IGOs a year behind disputes. Several authors (Fearon 1994, Smith 1998, Gartzke, Li, and Boehmer 2001) propose that an enhanced ability to signal their intentions accounts for the separate peace among liberal states. Democracies and interdependent states benefit from being able to communicate their preferences by sending costly signals. Transparency, when coupled with support for a show of strength from the domestic opposition, allows these states to persuade adversaries of their resolve and thus to prevail without actually having to fight. Similarly, Boehmer, Gartzke, and Nordstrom (2000) argue that states joined by cohesive and well-institutionalized IGOs can use those organizations to exchange information and communicate credible signals of resolve. In that democracies and interdependent states are even less likely to have fatal disputes than lower-level ones, our empirical results fit such signaling hypotheses to a degree. But since they still are less likely to experience even low-level MIDS with each other than are other states, signaling clearly takes place primarily in political and diplomatic communications without the need even to threaten military force. Our results are, moreover, consistent with other theories of the liberal peace that emphasize the roles played by strong material interests and normative influences in allowing interdependent democracies embedded in a dense network of international organizations to avoid military conflict. 20

Overall, our results provide strong support for the benefits of democracy, interdependence, and international organizations; but again we have only considered their independent effects. Democracies are apt to become interdependent and collaborate in IGOs, and the three influences seem mutually reinforcing (Russett and Oneal 2001, ch. 6). It is appropriate, therefore, to estimate the effect of increasing all three Kantian factors simultaneously. Then, the incidence of fatal disputes falls by 95 percent, from.0086 per annum to.0004. The drop in the probability of the onset of any kind of dispute is also very great a reduction of 79 percent. Additional Analyses of the Dynamics of Interstate Relations We next consider additional analyses to illustrate the dynamic effects of democracy, interdependence, and power. In the results we have reported thus far, we changed all the lagged values of a theoretical variable by the same amount to show its effect on the probability of conflict. We can take further advantage of the information in the time series to evaluate three theories that predict how change through time affects the prospects for peace. We examine Mansfield and Synder s concern about the dangers of democratization, Copeland s argument that expectations about future levels of interdependence affect the risk of conflict, and Organski and Kugler s theory regarding the dangers of a transition in power. Democratization. The dynamic quality of our analysis allows us to reconsider whether democratization increases the risk of conflict, as Mansfield and Snyder (1995, 1996; Snyder 2000) suggest. The turbulent political changes associated with the end of the cold war and the wave of democratization in Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union led to fears of a surge of international conflict fuelled by domestic instability. International relations scholars have long asked whether internal unrest increases the likelihood of external violence, but Mansfield and Snyder offer new reason to consider a diversionary theory of war. Countries in transition from dictatorship to democracy, they suggest, are conflict-prone because nationalism becomes a rallying 21

theme for demagogues seeking political support in an unstable political environment. Xenophobia and jingoism are effective political strategies when the populace is inexperienced in democratic political processes and the responsibilities of citizenship. Dramatic changes in government often do occur at times of social and economic turmoil; and a domestic crisis may encourage a new regime, particularly in a democracy, to pick a quarrel with another state in order to solidify support at home. It is also plausible that democratization would produce instability that tempts neighboring states to attack while the government is weak and not fully in control of the nation. It is not obvious, however, that we should expect new democracies, because they are unstable, to be prone to conflict. The opposite possibility also exists: new democratic governments may be afraid to engage in foreign conflict because they are weak domestically and unsure if they can count on popular support. We can ascertain the effects of democratization on the likelihood of conflict using distributed-lags analyses. The historical dynamics of government, i.e., the character of the less democratic state in each dyad through time, affect the likelihood of a current dispute just as the history of conflict does. The question is: does a recent transition from autocracy to democracy increase the probability of a fatal militarized dispute? To answer this question, we compare three probabilities of the onset of a dispute: for a dyad composed of two democracies throughout the previous seven years, for a dyad that included an autocracy for the entire period, and the average for five dyads that contained an autocracy until this state became democratic in year t-1, t-2, t-3, t-4, or t-5. We use the average of the last five dyads to indicate whether democratization increases the risk of conflict because the lagged measures of democracy are highly correlated. Consequently, the estimated coefficients of the individual terms should not be given too much weight. The probability of a fatal dispute arising in a dyad containing a state that has consistently been autocratic is.0086. It is.0012, or 86 percent less, for a dyad composed of two democracies 22