Governance and Intelligence: Empirical Analysis from African Data

Similar documents
Quality of Institutions : Does Intelligence Matter?

Intelligence and Corruption

CHAPTER 2. Poverty has declined in Africa, but remains high

Food Security and Social Protection in Sub-Saharan Africa: an Evaluation of Cash Transfer Programs

Income Inequality Trends in sub-saharan Africa: Divergence, Determinants, and Consequences

Aid for Trade: Ensuring That the Most Needy Get It

A Foundation for Dialogue on Freedom in Africa

International Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2007, Volume 1, Issue 4,

Impact of Religious Affiliation on Economic Growth in Sub-Saharan Africa. Dean Renner. Professor Douglas Southgate. April 16, 2014

Overview of Human Rights Developments & Challenges

Economic Growth and the Pursuit of Inequality Reduction in Africa

Growth, Inequality, and Poverty in Sub-Saharan Africa: Recent Progress in a Global Context

Daniel Kaufmann

Applied Econometrics and International Development Vol.7-2 (2007)

Appendix Figure 1: Association of Ever- Born Sibship Size with Education by Period of Birth. Bolivia Burkina Faso Burundi Cambodia Cameroon

TABLE OF AFRICAN STATES THAT HAVE SIGNED OR RATIFIED THE ROME STATUTE 1

Economic Growth and the Pursuit of Inequality Reduction in Africa

Rule of Law Africa Integrity Indicators Findings

Statistical Appendix 2 for Chapter 2 of World Happiness Report March 1, 2018

Report of the Credentials Committee

Presentation 1. Overview of labour migration in Africa: Data and emerging trends

In Gabon, overwhelming public distrust of CENAP and election quality forms backdrop for presidential vote dispute

Freedom in Africa Today

APPENDIX FOR: Democracy, Hybrid Regimes, and Infant Mortality: A Cross- National Analysis of Sub-Saharan African Nations

Optimizing Foreign Aid to Developing Countries: A Study of Aid, Economic Freedom, and Growth

Elections and Political Fragility in Africa

Cambridge International Examinations Cambridge International General Certificate of Secondary Education

Slums As Expressions of Social Exclusion: Explaining The Prevalence of Slums in African Countries

IEP Risk and Peace. Institute for Economics and Peace. Steve Killelea, Executive Chairman. Monday, 18th November 2013 EIB, Luxemburg

Intra-Africa Academic Mobility Scheme

The Dynamics of Migration in Sub Saharan Africa: An Empirical Study to Find the Interlinkages of Migration with Remittances and Urbanization.

REPORT ON THE ELECTION OF THE FIFTEEN (15) MEMBERS OF THE PEACE AND SECURITY COUNCIL OF THE AFRICAN UNION

Income and Population Growth

Charting the Future of Africa: Avoiding Policy Syndromes and Improving Governance

On track in 2013 to Reduce Malaria Incidence by >75% by 2015 (vs 2000)

The transition of corruption: From poverty to honesty

ASSOCIATION OF AFRICAN UNIVERSITIES BYELAWS

Youth th and Employment in Africa: The Potential t, he the Problem, the Promise 2

FREEDOM, OPPRESSION AND CORRUPTION IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Generation 2030 AFRICA AUGUST 2014 DIVISION OF DATA, RESEARCH, AND POLICY

Governance of Innovation in the Different Countries of the World

Per Capita Income Guidelines for Operational Purposes

Report on Countries That Are Candidates for Millennium Challenge Account Eligibility in Fiscal

AFRICA LAW TODAY, Volume 4, Issue 4 (2012)

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Harrowing Journeys: Children and youth on the move across the Mediterranean Sea, at risk of trafficking and exploitation

A human rights-consistent approach to multidimensional welfare measurement applied to sub-saharan Africa

ACE GLOBAL A Snapshot

Release Notes. World PPPOI- Consumer Edition. Version 3.2 ( ) Contents:

Release Notes. World Premium Points of Interest-Consumer Edition. Version 3.2 ( ) Contents:

Economic Growth: Lecture 1, Questions and Evidence

HORMONAL CONTRACEPTION AND HIV

CHAPTER 5: POVERTY AND INEQUALITY

Which Countries are Most Likely to Qualify for the MCA? An Update using MCC Data. Steve Radelet 1 Center for Global Development April 22, 2004

A new standard in organizing elections

United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization Executive Board

AFRICAN CIVIL AVIATION COMMISSION 30 th AFCAC PLENARY SESSION (LIVINGSTONE, ZAMBIA, 4 5 DECEMBER 2018)

Chapter 3 Institutions and Economic, Political, and Civil Liberty in Africa

ICAO Regional FAL Seminar Cairo, Egypt February 2014

The World of Government WFP

Comparing the Wealth of Nations. Emily Lin

RECENT TRENDS AND DYNAMICS SHAPING THE FUTURE OF MIDDLE INCOME COUNTRIES IN AFRICA. Jeffrey O Malley Director, Data, Research and Policy UNICEF

AFRICA S YOUTH: JOBS OR MIGRATION?

PUBLIC SERVICE IN AFRICA MO IBRAHIM FOUNDATION

DPI415: COMPARATIVE POLITICS IN GLOBAL PERSPECTIVE. Class 3: Comparative methods: Contrasts between case studies v. large N. approaches.

Proposed Indicative Scale of Contributions for 2016 and 2017

GLOBAL MONITORING REPORT 2015/2016

The Africa Public Sector Human Resource Managers Network (APS-HRMnet): Constitution and Rules

U.S. Food Aid and Civil Conflict

The African strategic environment 2020 Challenges for the SA Army

The Africa Prosperity Report

Africa Center Overview. Impact through Insight

New Strategies and Strengthening Electoral Capacities. Tangier (Morocco), March 2012

An analysis of trends shaping Africa s economic future

Gender Inequality and Growth: The Case of Rich vs. Poor Countries

The effect of foreign aid on corruption: A quantile regression approach

Africa Agriculture Transformation Scorecard: Performance and Lessons for the Southern Africa Development Community-SADCSS

Governance, Fragility, and Security

MAKING MOVEMENT FOR DEVELOPMENT EASIER IN AFRICA - PRESENTING THE REVAMPED AFDB LAISSEZ-PASSER

PUBLIC SERVICE IN AFRICA MO IBRAHIM FOUNDATION

CONSTITUTIVE ACT OF THE AFRICAN UNION

Private Capital Flows, Official Development Assistance, and Remittances to Africa: Who Gets What?

Re: Support for the ICC at African Union (AU) summit on October 11-12

Africa -Opportunities for Entrepreneurship Dr. Jack M. Wilson Distinguished Professor of Higher Education, Emerging Technologies, and Innovation

Maternal healthcare inequalities over time in lower and middle income countries

Endogenous Presidentialism

Inequality of opportunities among children: how much does gender matter?

THEME: FROM NORM SETTING TO IMPLEMENTATION

Macroeconomics+ World+Distribu3on+of+Income+ XAVIER+SALA=I=MARTIN+(2006)+ ECON+321+

The Multidimensional Financial Inclusion MIFI 1

Tuesday, April 16, 2013

Growth and poverty reduction in Africa in the last two decades

A Partial Solution. To the Fundamental Problem of Causal Inference

Bank Guidance. Thresholds for procurement. approaches and methods by country. Bank Access to Information Policy Designation Public

TISAX Activation List

ADDRESSING THE ISSUE OF YOUTH UNEMPLOYMENT: ISSUES AND THE CAUSES. Samuel Freije World Development Report 2013 Team, World Bank

Geoterm and Symbol Definition Sentence. consumption. developed country. developing country. gross domestic product (GDP) per capita

Business environment analysis of Romania

WoFA 2017 begins by defining food assistance and distinguishing it from food aid

It is about Wealth, not (only) Income: What the World Bank says and does not say

Measuring Degree of Globalization of African Countries on Almost Equimarginal Contribution Principle

Transcription:

MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Governance and Intelligence: Empirical Analysis from African Data Oasis Kodila-Tedika University of Kinshasa;, Institute of African Economics 13 May 2012 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/39937/ MPRA Paper No. 39937, posted 8 July 2012 19:22 UTC

Governance and Intelligence: Empirical Analysis from African Data Oasis Kodila-Tedika 1 Firth version Abstract This study aims at testing the relation between intelligence and governance. It is based on African data. This study finds that countries with high-iq populations enjoy good governance. Keys-word : institution, governance, intelligence, Africa JEL Classification: D73, I2 INTRODUCTION In spite of some grey areas (e.g. Méndez and Sepúlveda, 2006; Méon and Weill, 2010; Meisel and Ould Aoudia, 2008; Arndt, 2009), economists now generally admit that institutions or governance matter for the performance of a nation, especially from an economic point of view (e.ge. Acemoglu, Johnson et Robinson, 2005 ; Djankov, Glaeser, La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes et Shleifer, 2003 ; Davis, Owen et Videras, 2009 ; Baland, Moene et Robinson, J., 2010). However this consensus collapses once one tries to include/understand the impulses or the determinants of institutions or gouvernance. Moreover, the ad hoc literature is still in development (e.g. North, 2005; Acemoglu and Robinson, 2005; North, Wallis and Weingast, 2010; Baland, Moene and Robinson, 2010). This article is precisely in line with this research program. It raises the following question: does intelligence explain the level of governance of a State? Let us recall quickly that recently the issue of intelligence started to draw the attention of economists. Work of Jones and Schneider (2006), Weede and Kämpf (2002) and Jones (2011) empirically assign a positive effect of intelligence on growth. Potrafke (2012) thinks of a negative effect of intelligence on corruption. It is also studied within the framework of game theory (Jones, 2008; Jones and Podemska 2010). One realizes quickly that much is left to study. This study contributes its share to the research, by thus marrying the need to include/understand the determinants of governance to the recent research by economists on the effects of intelligence. While thinking of the concern of this article, one would be first tempted to think of a truism. That would be wrong. Intelligence being the very general 1 Department of Economics, University of Kinshasa, Democratic Republic of Congo; Institute of African Economics. E-mail: oasiskodila@yahoo.fr I thank Niklas Potrafke, Isaac Kanyama Kalonda and Emmanuel Martin for helpful suggestions.

mental capacity which implies in particular the ability to reason, to plan, to solve problems, to think abstractedly, to correctly understand complex ideas, to learn quickly and to benefit from one s experiments. (Gottfredson, 1997; Larivée and Gagné, 2006), it is almost natural to deduce that the level of intelligence influences the governance of a nation, but the expected sign is not possible to determine a priori nor is the direction of the effect (direct or indirect). One cannot determine ex ante the effect of intelligence. If intelligence can be useful for the good, it can also be used to circumvent rules or to seek rents, which for example contributes to strengthen atypical or counterproductive regimes. Africa is precisely populated with anecdotes of this kind. Because Africa is a backward continent, it remains a candidate for the Gerschenkron effect (Gerschenkron, 1962): the effect to be able to benefit from the experiments of the others in order to take off (even in terms of governance). Theories of endogenous growth (imitation/transfer of technology or innovation) also agree with this. And here, it is in particular the level of intelligence which is requested. Indeed, if the highest aberrant values in the distribution of intelligence are used advisedly in a society, it is very likely to benefit from a good elite both at the level of State management as in civil society. This can only encourage good governance and make society benefit from the Gerschenkron effect or of the advantages of imitation and innovation predicted in theories of endogenous growth (Aghion and Howitt, 2009), and, in fine, generate a virtuous circle. The reversed effect is also not to be completely excluded. But if the standard deviation of this distribution is close to zero, the effect of intelligence depends then on the absolute level of intelligence. If all the population enjoys higher intelligence, it is likely that political equilibrium will be optimal, with a positive consequence on governance. Under the assumption that the level of intelligence is lower, social equilibrium is very low with, consequently, a probable capture of society by the dominant coalition. The object of this study is, as we underlined it, to study the relation between governance and intelligence on the basis of African data. Interest for Africa is justified initially by the African specificity which has always been. Then and finally, the second reason is due to the originality of data on governance. The rest of the article is organized as follows. The following section is concerned with the presentation of the data and the strategy of econometric estimate. Then we present the results. Lastly, a conclusion is suggested.

DATA AND ESTIMATION STRATEGY From the econometric point of view, we borrow the approach of Potrafke (2012). The equation to be estimated is as follows: With I = 4 N and m representing the various listed African countries.it is about Angola (AGO), Benin (BEN), Botswana (BWA), Burkina Faso (BFA), Burundi (BDI), Cameroon (CMR), Central African Republic (CIF), Chad (TCD), DRC (ZAR), Côte d'ivoire (CIV), Egypt (EGY), Ethiopia (ETH), Ghana (GHA), Guinea-Bissau (GNB), Kenya (KEN), Lesotho (LSO), Madagascar (MDG), Malawi (MWI), Mali (MLI), Mauritania (MRT), Maurice (DRIVEN), Morocco (MAR), Mozambique (MOZ), Namibia (NAM), Niger (NER), Rwanda (RWA), Senegal (SEN), Sierra Leone (SLE), South Africa (ZAF), Togo (TGO), Tunisia (TUN), Uganda (UGA), Tanzania (TZA), Zambia (ZMB) and Zimbabwe (ZWE). Gov is a proxy of Governance. We exploit the data of the Ibrahim Foundation. This indicator compiles 86 indicators gathered in 14 subcategories and four categories (secuirty and rule of law, participation and human right, sustainable economic development and human development) which evaluate the effective service of goods and public services delivered to African citizens. The Ibrahim Index constitutes the most complete collection of quantitative information leading to an annual evaluation of the performance with regard to governance in each African country, only. This index is financed and controlled by a African institution. It is not exploited yet in the empirical literature. In addition, in our estimates, Gov2010 relates to the level of the governance in 2010 and Gov2005 on the level of the governance in 2005. IQ relates to the mean intelligence quotient of the general population. Gouillon (2002) affirms that IQ is the tool more used in psychometry. It allows in form simple to quantify a great number of cognitive capacities of the subject and her general intelligence (the factor G). Psychologists regularly resort to it (Neisser, 1998; Larivée and Gagné, 2006). We make use of it to approximate intelligence. In the estimates, QI2006 relates to the level of intelligence in 2006 and QI2002 on the level of the intelligence in 2002. The data on IQ come from Lynn et al. (2002, 2006 and 2010). In Table 1, i.e. basic estimates, we employ the data of Lynn and Vanhanen (2006), which was also used by Jones and Schneider (2010), Potrafke (2012). The data of Lynn and Vanhanen (2002) are employed in the section of tests of robustness. Let us specify here that the concern first was to also use the data of Lynn and Meisenberg (2010). However, this data base does not cover enough countries of

our sample. Moreover, this way of testing the robustness of results is used in particular by Potrafke (2012). Reg is a regional dummy variable. It takes the value 1 if the country belongs to the area, and 0 if not. We distinguish five sub-regions : Central Africa, East Africa, West Africa, Southern Africa and North Africa. This variable makes it possible to control the variation of governance from a sub-region to another. X is a vector of control variables, including the log of GDP per capita (Penn World Tables 6.3), a dummy of the democracy-dictatorship of Cheibub et al. (2010) (Demo). We also control economic globalization by the KOF index used by Dreher (2006) and Dreher et al. (2008), expressed by GEKOF in the econometric results. Lastly, OrigDroit variable is taken in La Porta et al. (1999). We distinguish two for Africa from them from our sample: the English origin of law (OrigDroitAng) on the one hand and the French origin of law (OrigDroitFr) on the other. DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS Before moving to estimates, let us seize initially the statistical characteristics of our variables. Table 1 following takes care some. Table 1. Descriptive statistics Variables Obs. Mean Std-dev. Min Max Central Africa 35 0,085 0,284 0 1 Southern Africa 35 0,343 0,482 0 1 East Africa 35 0,171 0,382 0 1 North Africa 35 0,114 0,323 0 1 West Africa 35 0,286 0,458 0 1 Log GDP per capita 35 7,560 0,883 5,903 9,817 Demo 35 0,343 0,483 0 1 GEKOF 35 48,490 10,599 30,384 67,185 QI2006 35 70,719 6,219 64 89 QI2002 35 71,286 5,644 63 85 Gov2010 35 52,244 12,649 30,561 82,465 Gov2005 35 50,905 13,100 28,120 77,933 OrigDroitAng 35 0,343 0,486 0 1 OrigDroitFr 35 0,657 0,486 0 1 By considering only the variable to be estimated and the variable of interest (intelligence), Mauritius appears as the African country which is distinguished very positively in terms from governance and of intelligence. And one notes a

30 40 50 60 70 80 positive change from 77 to 82 out of 100, between 2005 and 2010. However, the last rank changes in time. In 2005, DRC occupies the last rank with a note of 28 out of 100. But in 2010, this position is occupied by Chad. Guinea-Bissau and Ethiopia have the weakest IQ in 2002, but in 2006 the place of the last is shared by four States: Cameroon, RCA, Mozambique and Sierra-Leone. Graph 1 presents the correlation between the variable of interest (IQ) and the level of governance in Africa. Whatever the variable considered, one notes the existence of clubs of convergence. Graph 1.IQ and gouvernance MUS BWA NAM ZAF MOZ GHA LSO BEN SEN TZA MWI ZMB BFA UGA MLI RWA KEN EGY TUN MAR SLE CMR ETH BDITGO NER AGO MRT MDG GNB CIV CAF ZAR ZWE TCD 65 70 75 80 85 90 iq06_1 gov2010 Fitted values Basic results RESULTS Table 2 hereafter shows the first five basic estimates. Except for (1), in the other columns, the absence of estimated coefficients of certain variables is due to the multicolinearity which these variables cause in the estimates. The majority of variables of control are not statistically significant. The increase in income tends to make level of governance increase, given the high significativity and the importance of its coefficient. According to (5), on average, countries of West and East Africa have a level of governance higher than countries of central Africa, whereas the performances of countries of North and Southern Africa do not differ much. Curiously, legal origin does not seem to have significant effect from the statistical point of view. In an undifferentiated way, this conclusion applies to OrigDroitFr and OrigDroitAng.

The level of intelligence statistically influences governance. In columns (1) and (3), the degree of confidence is 99%; it drops however to 95% in the other columns. This result is considerable insofar as an increase in one percentage point in the degree of confidence, compared to its standard deviation, directly involves an increase of 4,35 points in the level of governance. The fundamental question for which it is necessary to find an answer is: can one affirm that this conclusion is robust? Table 2. Results of the estimates QI2006 1,02*** Gov2010 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (0,29) 1,02** (0,45) Central Africa -9,07 (7,61) East Africa 5,53 (5,52) 1,35*** (0,40) North Africa -10,45 Southern Africa 11,13 (6,82) West Africa 6,43 (6,94) (5,59) 0,62** (0,30) -6,35 (7,51) 9,35 (6,62) 5,88 (4,15) 9,08 (4,14) Log GDP per capita 8,00*** (2,25) Demo 2,12 (4,96) GEKOF -0,00 (0,30) OrigDroitFr -6,49 Constant -20,03 (20,41) -25,64 (36,54) -41,96 (27,64) (4,64) -54,51 (26,00) 0,70** (0,28) 15,78** (6,09) 5,94 (7,44) 12,94 (6,98) 16,83*** (6,15) 8,01*** (2,22) 0,06 (0,24) -6,86 (4,41) -63,64*** Obs. 35 35 35 34 34 (22,57) Adj. R² 0,25 0,37 0,25 0,50 0,52 Notes: Absolute value of t statistics in brackets; * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% Robustness checks Given the limited options to validate these results in terms of robustness, we resort to the same exercise of robustness used by Potrafke (2012). It is a question of changing the years for the variable of control as well as for the variable to be

estimated. To have the same result suggests that this one remains insensitive with change in specification or variation of time. The results of this gymnastics are included in table 2. But beyond this way of testing robustness of results, we tried to introduce other variables of control: means of instruction age, opening of Penn World Tables 6.3 in place of GEKOF. We also used the corrected IQ of Potrafke to take into account criticisms of Wicherts et al. (2010). In spite of this change 2, the conclusion remains the same: intelligence statistically affects governance, in a positive way. Table 2. Search for robustness QI2002 1,18*** Gov2005 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (0,29) 1,37*** (0,48) Central Africa -9,66 (6,67) East Africa 8,70 (5,92) 1,59*** (0,39) North Africa -11,25 Southern Africa 11,75 (5,19) West Africa 10,22 (8,21) (5,50) 1,06* (0,53) -17,44** (4,95) 2,17 (7,45) -9,92 (10,16) -2,18 (6,72) Log GDP per capita 6,54** (2,87) Demo 4,90 (4,85) GEKOF 0,03 (0,38) OrigDroitAng 4,44 Constant -33,17 (21,12) -53,46 (39,03) -61,40 (27,11) (5,37) -74,56 (32,98) 1,13** (0,47) -19,12** (7,55) -1,42 (5,39) -14,16 (8,73) -4,03 (5,55) 6,15) 6,95 (3,01) -0,08 (0,22) 5,22 (3,99) -74,60** Obs. 35 35 35 34 34 (33,07) Adj. R² 0,25 0,37 0,25 0,45 0,45 Notes: Absolute value of t statistics in brackets; * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% 2 Let us specify that we do not include in table 2, the results of all these changes, the interested reader can ask to the author his results.

CONCLUSION We argue in this article that the level of intelligence of a population is likely to affect the governance of government in which this population lives. Indeed, because to be intelligent implies "the ability to reason, to solve problems, to understand complex ideas well, to learn quickly and to benefit from one s experiments", one can insinuate a nonreversible influence of this one on the governance. Our econometric analysis made it possible to establish, while controlling for the impact of the average income and other traditional variables, a direct relation between intelligence and governance: to have a high level of intelligence guarantees a remarkable governance in our sample guarantees. This effect proved to be of an non negligible extent, since while increasing by one point compared to its standard deviation, intelligence is likely to directly involve an increase of 4,35 points of the level of the governance. Moreover, this relation seems robust. These results, in conformity with our assumptions, must however be regarded as exploratory. The analysis appears to us to have to be prolonged in several directions, in particular the following ones. How does intelligence interact with other variables potentially likely to affect governance? Can one affirm with robustness the indirect effect of intelligence on governance? Does the level of intelligence of the leaders have a direct incidence on governance? Does intelligence boost the civil society and its capacity of empowerment? The econometric model could be specified so as to test the threshold effects and other nonlinearities: there a minimum level of intelligence from which the effects have an importance on governance? Remainder, how does this relation behave if the sample is widened, by breaking up governance into several dimensions? REFERENCES Acemoglu, D. et Robinson, J., 2005, Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy, Cambridge (Mass.), Cambridge University Press. Acemoglu, D.; Johnson, S. and Robinson, J. A., 2005, Institutions as the Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth, In P. Aghion et S. Durlauf (eds.) Handbook of Economic Growth. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Aghion, P. et Howitt, P. 2009, Economie de la croissance, Paris, Economica. Arndt, C. 2009, Governance Indicators, doctoral dissertation, Maastricht University School of Governance, Maastricht, Juin. Baland, J.-M., Moene, K.-O. and Robinson, J., 2010, Governance and development, In Dani Rodrik and Mark Rosenzweig, (ed.), Handbook of Development Economics, Vol. 5, The Netherlands: North-Holland: 4039-4214.

Cheibub, J., Gandhi, J. and Vreeland, J.R., 2010. Democracy and dictatorship revisited, Public Choice 143: 67-101. Davis, L., Owen, A. and Videras, J. 2009. Do All Countries Follow the Same Growth Process? Journal of Economics Growth, 14(4) : 265-286. Djankov, S., Glaeser, G., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F. and Shleifer, A., 2003. The New Comparative Economics. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4): 595 619. Dreher, A., 2006. Does globalization affect growth? Evidence from a new index of globalization. Applied Economics 38: 1091-1110. Dreher, A., Gaston, N. and Martens, P., 2008. Measuring globalization Gauging its consequences. Springer, Berlin. Gerschenkron, A. 1962, Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective : A Book of Essay, Cambridge, MA : Belknap Press of Havard University Press. Gottfredson, L.S. 1997, Foreword for intelligence and social policy, Intelligence, 24(1): 1-7. Gouillou, P. 2002, Le QI, Revue ANAE, 67:83-90. Jones, G. and Podemska, M., 2010. IQ in the utility function: cognitive skills, time preference and cross-country differences in savings rates. Working Paper, GMU, Virginia. Jones, G. and Schneider, W.J., 2006. Intelligence, human capital and economic growth: A Bayesian averaging of classical estimates (BACE) approach, Journal of Economic Growth 11: 71-93. Jones, G. and Schneider, W.J., 2010. IQ in the production function: evidence from immigrant earnings. Economic Inquiry 48: 743-755. Jones, G., 2008. Are smarter groups more cooperative? Evidence from Prisoner s Dilemma experiments, 1959-2003. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 68: 489-497. Jones, G., 2011. National IQ and national productivity: The hive mind across Asia. Asian Development Review 28: 58-71. La Porta, R., Lopez-di-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R., 1999. The quality of government. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 15: 222-279. Larivée, S. et Gagne, F. 2006, Intelligence 101 ou l ABC du QI, Revue de Psychoéducation, 35(1) :1-9. Lynn, R. and Meisenberg, G., 2010. National IQs calculated and validated for 108 nations. Intelligence 38, 353-360. Lynn, R. and Vanhanen, T. 2002. IQ and the wealth of nations. Westport, CT: Praeger Publishers.

Lynn, R. and Vanhanen, T. 2006. IQ and global inequality. Augusta, GA: Washington Summit Publishers. Meisel, N. et Ould Aoudia, J. 2008. L insaisissable relation «bonne gouvernance» et développement?. Revue économique 59(6). Méndez, F. and Sepúlveda, F. 2006, Corruption, Growth and Political Regimes: Crosscountry evidence, European Journal of Political Economy, 22(1): 82-98. Méon, P.-G. and Weill, L. 2010, Is Corruption an Efficient Grease?, World Development 38(3) : 244-259. Neisser, U. 1998, Sommes-nous plus intelligent que nos grands grands-parents, Recherche, 309 :46-52. North, D. (2005), Le processus du développement économique, Paris, Ed. Organisation. North, D., Wallis, J. et Weingast, B., 2010, Violence et ordres sociaux, Paris, Ed. Gallimard. Potrafke, N. 2012, Intelligence and Corruption, Economics Letters, 114(1): 109-112. Weede, E. and Kämpf, S. 2002. The impact of intelligence and institutional improvements on economic growth. Kyklos 55: 361-380. Wicherts, M., Dolan, V., Carlson, S. and van der Maas, L.J., 2010a. Another failure to replicate Lynn s estimate of the average IQ of sub-saharan Africans. Learning and Individual Differences 20 : 155-157. Wicherts, M., Dolan, V., Carlson, S. and van der Maas, L.J., 2010b. Raven s test performance of sub-saharan Africans: Average performance, psychometric properties, and the Flynn effect. Learning and Individual Differences 20: 135-151.