Simplifying the Choice of Forum: A Reply

Similar documents
Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

Book Review: Civil Justice, Privatization, and Democracy by Trevor C. W. Farrow

Standards for the New Millennium Meeting Public Expectations

The Presumption of Innocence and Bail

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

General Discussion: Cross-Border Macroeconomic Implications of Demographic Change

Patent Venue Wars: Episode 5 5th Circ.

Borders, Citizenship and Immigration Act 2009 the new provisions for naturalisation

HARVARD JOHN M. OLIN CENTER FOR LAW, ECONOMICS, AND BUSINESS

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One

Arbitration Law in Eastern Europe. Elizabeth Shackelford* Although arbitration in some form has had a long history in Eastern Europe, 1

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF TEXAS TYLER DIVISION ORDER

POLITICAL AUTHORITY AND PERFECTIONISM: A RESPONSE TO QUONG

Civil Justice Improvements (CJI) Committee. Update #2

James M. Buchanan The Limits of Market Efficiency

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

The Provision of Public Goods, and the Matter of the Revelation of True Preferences: Two Views

April 30, Dear Acting Under Secretary Rea:

Safety and Justice Challenge: Interim performance measurement report

THE SUPREME COURT OF NEW HAMPSHIRE. APPEAL OF ANNELIE MULLEN (New Hampshire Department of Employment Security)

CHAPTER 1 PROLOGUE: VALUES AND PERSPECTIVES

Journals in the Discipline: A Report on a New Survey of American Political Scientists

HARVARD NEGATIVE-EXPECTED-VALUE SUITS. Lucian A. Bebchuk and Alon Klement. Discussion Paper No /2009. Harvard Law School Cambridge, MA 02138

Teaching Constitutional Law: Homage to Clio

FEDERAL COURTS COMMITTEE OF THE NEW YORK COUNTY LAWYERS ASSOCIATION COMMENTS ON PROPOSED AMENDMENTS TO THE FEDERAL RULES OF APPELLATE PROCEDURE

FAIR REPUTATIONS: A GAME-THEORETIC MECHANISM FOR E-COMMERCE DISPUTES*

EFFICIENCY OF COMPARATIVE NEGLIGENCE : A GAME THEORETIC ANALYSIS

The Language of Law and More Probable Than Not : Some Brief Thoughts

Joint NGO Response to the Draft Copenhagen Declaration

BUSINESS TORTS / COMMERCIAL LITIGATION: EFFECTIVE TRIAL TECHNIQUES

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT CENTRAL DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) JURISDICTION

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF DELA WARE ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) MEMORANDUM

J L S BOOK REVIEWS JOURNAL OF LIBERTARIAN STUDIES VOLUME 21, NO. 2 (SUMMER 2007):

CHAPTER 1 PROLOGUE: VALUES AND PERSPECTIVES

The Effects of the Right to Silence on the Innocent s Decision to Remain Silent

DISPUTE RESOLUTION PROVISIONS OF THE CANADA-UNITED STATES FREE TRADE AGREEMENT

April 30, The Sections of Antitrust Law and International Law (the Sections ) of the American

Litigating Bad Faith: Why Winning the Battle May Not Win the Protest

Fee Awards and Optimal Deterrence

11.002/17.30 Making Public Policy 11/09/14. Comparing the Strategic Efforts of Gay Marriage and Immigration Reform Advocates

Natural Resources Journal

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC LAW: THE POLITICAL THEATRE DIMENSION

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAWYERS ASSOCIATION

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES. Working Paper No. i63. NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge MA

Permanent Editorial Board for the Uniform Commercial Code PEB COMMENTARY NO. 18. July 2014

UNDERCOVER POLICING INQUIRY

Although the Judiciary Act of 1789 (ch. 20, 35, 1 Stat. 73, 92 93) created

Case 1:16-cv ESH Document 75 Filed 12/05/17 Page 1 of 11 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA

What is the Jurisdictional Significance of Extraterritoriality? - Three Irreconcilable Federal Court Decisions

More Justice for Less Money

Research Note: Toward an Integrated Model of Concept Formation

NO. COA NORTH CAROLINA COURT OF APPEALS. Filed: 21 August Appeal by Defendant and cross-appeal by Plaintiff from

Possible voting reforms in the United States

The author of this article has worked as a European Patent Attorney both in private practice and in industry, and as an economics consultant.

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting

Review of Federal Trial Handbook, By Robert S. Hunter

A Solution to the Problem of Nuisance Suits: The Option to Have the Court Bar Settlement. David Rosenberg and Steven Shavell *

BEFORE THE APPEALS COUNCIL OF THE NEW ZEALAND INSTITUTE OF CHARTERED ACCOUNTANTS

IS STARE DECISIS A CONSTRAINT OR A CLOAK?

Monthly Census Bureau data show that the number of less-educated young Hispanic immigrants in the

Democracy, and the Evolution of International. to Eyal Benvenisti and George Downs. Tom Ginsburg* ... National Courts, Domestic

Getting ready for Ontario s new Construction Act. Understanding the key changes and how to prepare for them. Howard Krupat

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Case 2:10-cv HGD Document 31 Filed 06/27/11 Page 1 of 10 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT NORTHERN DISTRICT OF ALABAMA SOUTHERN DIVISION

Employment Special Interest Group

DIRECT PURCHASERS STANDING TO SUE FOR WALKER PROCESS FRAUD IN RE: DDAVP DIRECT PURCHASER ANTITRUST LITIGATION

REVIEW. Statutory Interpretation in Australia

Immigration and Conflict in Democracies

RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT WESTERN DISTRICT OF ARKANSAS FAYETTEVILLE DIVISION CASE NO. 12-CV-5162 ORDER

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group

Strengthening aspects of the presumption of innocence and the right to be present at trial in criminal proceedings

Restraining and replacing the party system

DEPARTMENT OF HOMELAND SECURITY. U.S. Customs and Border Protection. 8 CFR Parts 103 and 235. Docket No. USCBP CBP Decision No.

Comparison of the Psychometric Properties of Several Computer-Based Test Designs for. Credentialing Exams

PIPER AIRCRAFT COMPANY v. REYNO Supreme Court of the United States, U.S. 235, 102 S.Ct. 252, 70 L.Ed.2d 419.

VIRGINIA SELF-REPRESENTED LITIGANT STUDY:

Case 1:16-cv ER Document 18 Filed 04/19/16 Page 1 of 59

Legal Change: Integrating Selective Litigation, Judicial Preferences, and Precedent

Case 2:17-cv JRG Document 234 Filed 07/19/18 Page 1 of 9 PageID #: 18232

THE SUPREME COURT'S DECISION IN

The Fairness of Sanctions: Some Implications for Optimal Enforcement Policy

U.S. Foreign Policy: The Puzzle of War

Chapter 2: Core Values and Support for Anti-Terrorism Measures.

Standing in the Judge s Shoes: Exploring Techniques to Help Legal Writers More Fully Address the Needs of Their Audience

This appeal challenges the trial court s determination that the Department of

PART 1 INTRODUCTION SCOPE OF THIS REPORT

NON-PRECEDENTIAL DECISION - SEE SUPERIOR COURT I.O.P

May 21, By Marcia E. Asquith Office of the Corporate Secretary FINRA 1735 K Street, NW Washington, DC

RESPONSE TO AN UNWARRANTED ACCUSATION

Promoting Work in Public Housing

COURT OF CHANCERY OF THE STATE OF DELAWARE. June 3, 2010

Response to the Evaluation Panel s Critique of Poverty Mapping

SOUTHERN GLAZER S WINE AND SPIRITS, LLC. EMPLOYMENT ARBITRATION POLICY

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 6: An Examination of Iowa Absentee Voting Since 2000

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF HAWAII ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) I. INTRODUCTION

Research Note: U.S. Senate Elections and Newspaper Competition

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

Regulatory Coordinating Committee

Ethical and Practical Guidance to Avoiding Pitfalls When Drafting Arbitration Clauses. October 11, 2016

Transcription:

Washington University Law Review Volume 75 Issue 4 January 1997 Simplifying the Choice of Forum: A Reply Theodore Eisenberg Kevin M. Clermont Follow this and additional works at: http://openscholarship.wustl.edu/law_lawreview Part of the Jurisdiction Commons Recommended Citation Theodore Eisenberg and Kevin M. Clermont, Simplifying the Choice of Forum: A Reply, 75 Wash. U. L. Q. 1551 (1997). Available at: http://openscholarship.wustl.edu/law_lawreview/vol75/iss4/7 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law School at Washington University Open Scholarship. It has been accepted for inclusion in Washington University Law Review by an authorized administrator of Washington University Open Scholarship. For more information, please contact digital@wumail.wustl.edu.

SIMPLITYING THE CHOICE OF FORUM: A REPLY KEVIN M. CLERMONT* THEODORE EISENBERG" INTRODUCTION We have three things to think about here, as the real estate agents say- "location, location, location." Accordingly, the two of us have engaged for several years in empirical studies aimed at gauging the effect of forum on case outcome. The results to date strongly suggest that forum really matters. An early piece of the puzzle fell into place in our study on transfer of venue. 1 In that article, we examined the benefits and costs of the federal courts' scheme of transfer of civil venue "in the interest of justice." 2 Ours was a pretty straightforward and simple cost-benefit analysis, but we supported it with some fairly elaborate data. For example, to expose the benefits, we demonstrated a dramatic drop in plaintiffs' rate of winning after transfer of venue, 3 and we argued that on average the altered outcomes reflect the more just transferee forums' more accurate outcomes. 4 Thus, the benefit side of the analysis included this substantial reduction in error costs, along with direct costs' net diminution from litigating in a more convenient forum. As to the cost side of the analysis, our empirical work indicated considerable total expense of handling transfer motions, but also a tendency among commentators to overestimate that expense. 5 Our bottom line, admittedly not definitive, was, "[g]ood policy calls, at the least, for preserving the transfer mechanism." 6 Now Professor David Steinberg, after some kind introductory words, responds, "I disagree with almost all of their conclusions. ' 7 He specifies: First, by including cases where courts have entered default judgments, * Flanagan Professor of Law, Cornell University. ** Henry Allen Mark Professor of Law, Cornell University. 1. See Kevin M. Clermont & Theodore Eisenberg, Exorcising the Evil offorum-shopping, 80 CORNELL L. REv. 1507 (1995). 2. 28 U.S.C. 1404(a) (1994). 3. See Clermont & Eisenberg, supra note 1, at 1511-25. 4. Seeid at 1515-16. 5. See id at 1525-30. 6. Id at 1530. 7. David E. Steinberg, Simplifidng the Choice of Forum: A Response to Professor Clermont and Professor Eisenberg, 75 WASH. U. L.Q. 1479, 1480 (1997). 1551 Washington University Open Scholarship

1552 WASHINGTON UNIVERSITY LAW QUARTERLY [VOL. 75:1551 Professor Clermont and Professor Eisenberg exaggerate the effect, if any, that the choice of forum has on the outcome of a case. Second, Professor Clermont and Professor Eisenberg do not demonstrate that transfers lead to more accurate outcomes. Instead, their data only supports the conclusion that a defendant's chance of winning a case improves if the defendant has selected the forum through a transfer motion. Third, Professor Clermont and Professor Eisenberg understate the costs and appropriateness of transfer under the open-ended standard currently employed in section 1404(a) litigation. Fourth, if Professor Clermont and Professor Eisenberg are correct that forum shopping is both pervasive and effects outcomes, Congress or the courts should address this problem directly by limiting the geographic choices available to a plaintiff bringing a federal court suit Such an approach would address any inequities resulting from forum shopping far more universally and efficiently than the case-by-case transfers currently employed under section 1404(a). 8 Professor Steinberg's first two arguments attack our benefit analysis, as he contends that we failed to show any real drop in plaintiffs' win rate upon transfer and that, even if we did succeed, we have no reason to suspect that the change is in the direction of accuracy. His third argument goes to our cost analysis, as he contends that the expense of handling transfer motions is exorbitant. Professor Steinberg's fourth argument addresses our conclusion, as he says that if against all odds we were right, then we should be championing the more radical reform of narrowing the plaintiffs' initial choice of forum. We believe that our article met Professor Steinberg's first three arguments. As to his fourth point, however, we are in agreement. Our point had indeed been to open the door to that more radical reform, but we gently pushed it open because we were early in the process of gathering empirical support. Since writing that article, we have extended our focus beyond transfer. We have shown that forum affects outcome in other contexts. Therefore, we are now prepared to argue ever more explicitly that the initial choice of forum is currently a little too wide to be just. At any rate, we shall reply to Professor Steinberg's four arguments in order. 8. Id at 1481-82. http://openscholarship.wustl.edu/law_lawreview/vol75/iss4/7

1997] SIMPLIFYING THE CHOICE OF FORUM: A REPLY 1553 A. Transfer Effect: Descriptive I. BENEFITS OF TRANSFER The striking finding that triggered our research was that in three million recent federal civil cases, the plaintiffs won 58% of the non-transferred cases that went to judgment but only 29% of such transferred cases. 9 One cannot look just at output, however, because the set of non-transferred cases is very different from the set of transferred cases. For example, we noted prominently that about 32% of non-transfer judgments are by default, contrasted to about 4% of transfer judgments.' 0 In other words, "easy plaintiff victories often, but not always, occur quickly, without transfer, so that transferred cases are tougher to win."" Accordingly, we warned right at the outset that "the overall drop from 58% to 29% gives an exaggerated sense of the magnitude of the transfer effect."', 2 The exaggeration was not a wild one, however. Just as we noted several sources of exaggeration, we noted several sources of understatement. Most notably, we were looking only at judgments. Yet 53% of non-transfer case terminations are by non-judgment dismissal (primarily voluntary dismissals and dismissals for lack of prosecution), while 64% of transfer terminations are by non-judgment dismissal. This contrast shows that plaintiffs tend to abandon their cases after transfer. Therefore, confining our study to judgments ignored this abandonment and thus understated the actual transfer effect. 13 Nevertheless, to remain as objective as possible, we did restrict our focus to judgments for the plaintiff or the defendant We then employed the mathematical technique of regression to control for the differences between the non-transfer and transfer judgment sets, including the difference in default rate. In other words, we separated out the effects of the differences between cases from the effect of transfer by itself. We found that "transfer continues to have a substantial negative effect on win rate," so much that transfer reduces a 50% chance of the plaintiff's winning a judgment to 9. See Clermont & Eisenberg, supra note 1, at 1511-12. 10. See id. at 1521-22 (explaining that the 32% and 4% rates are based on a subset ofjudgments, so that the actual figures are 29% and 4%). 11. d at 1517. 12. Id. at 1513. 13. See id. at 1522-23. Because the number of terminations exceeds the number of judgments, the effect of this difference in non-judgment dismissals is considerably bigger than the opposite effect of that difference in default judgments. Washington University Open Scholarship

1554 WASHINGTON UNIVERSITY LAW QUARTERLY [VOL. 75:1551 40%.14 Interestingly, we have since expanded our footnoted comparison of transfer and removal 15 into an article on the "removal effect."' 16 There, looking at judgments for the plaintiff or the defendant again, we conclude that removal by itself reduces a 50% chance of plaintiff's winning to 39%.17 This comparison suggests a consistent "forum effect" that reflects the plaintiffs loss of forum advantage.1 8 Very often empirical results are counterintuitive. Most readers are consequently loath to accept them. Yet here our work substantiated common knowledge. As most practitioners already knew, forum-shopping is the name of the game.1 9 Nonetheless, Professor Steinberg remains unconvinced that forum in fact affects outcome. Professor Steinberg dismisses our fifteen pages of data analysis simply because the "28% difference in default judgment rates is almost identical to the overall 29% difference in plaintiff win rates for non-transferred as opposed to transferred cases. ' 20 Because empirical investigation and interpretation are so difficult, those who dislike the results will not find it this easy to dismiss or explain away those results. First, according to the data presented in our article, the plaintiffs' win rates in non-transferred and transferred cases, excluding default judgments, are 41% and 27% respectively. Our discussion of methods of case disposition, for example, noted for judgments by pretrial motion a non-transfer win rate of 26% and a transfer win rate of 13%.2 1 Second, Professor Steinberg's observation indicates a lack of understanding of regression analysis. Quite simply, we took the different default rates into account, at some length in fact. The regressions proved the persistence of the transfer effect. Third, even at a lower level of mathematics, Professor 14. See id at 1524 & n.39. We found for diversity cases a drop upon transfer from 50% to 38%. Kevin M. Clermont & Theodore Eisenberg, Do Case Outcomes Really Reveal Anything About the Legal System? Win Rates and Removal Jurisdiction, 83 CORNELLL. REV. 581,603 n.67 (1998). 15. See Clermont & Eisenberg, supra note 1, at 1514 n.18. 16. See Clermont & Eisenberg, supra note 14. 17. See id. at 604 n.71 (diversity cases only). 18. The shift in inconvenience upon removal is probably less than upon transfer, thus implying a relatively smaller removal effect. However, the defendant unilaterally triggers removal, while the defendant must get the judge to approve transfer, this increased opportunity for forum-shopping by the removing defendant would relatively augment the removal effect. The overall result is that the transfer and removal effects for diversity cases are about equal. 19. See, e.g., Kimberly Jade Norwood, Shopping for a Venue: The Need for More Limits on Choice, 50 U. MIAMI L. REV. 267, 310 (1996) (urging, as an ideal, tighter venue laws); Brannon J. Buck, Commentary, Forum Shopping and Venue Transfers in Alabama, 48 ALA. L. REv. 671 (1997) (urging greater use of transfer in the state-court system to curtail the growing problem of forumshopping). 20. Steinberg, supra note 7, at 1484. 21. See Clermont & Eisenberg, supra note 1, at 1522. http://openscholarship.wustl.edu/law_lawreview/vol75/iss4/7

19971 SIMPLIFYING THE CHOICE OF FORUM: A REPLY 1555 Steinberg's observation ignores the rules of ratios, and the changing denominator. If one excludes default judgments at the rates of 32% and 4% and assumes they were all plaintiff victories, the 58% non-transfer and 29% transfer win rates do not fall to equality as Professor Steinberg implies, but after a simple calculation stand at 38% for non-transferred cases and 26% for transferred cases. In summary, the plunge in default rate after transfer by no means fully accounts for the observed transfer effect The effect of transfer in reducing the plaintiffs' win rate is real. Unsurprisingly, the plaintiffs have an advantage in the forum chosen by the plaintiffs. Indeed, instead of detracting from our position, the plunging default rate after transfer may support it. The high default rate in the plaintiffs' initially chosen forum may in part reflect their real forum advantage, as some defendants just elect not to litigate there. 2 Perhaps we need to make a more general point, one that goes beyond defaults and mathematics. Why is it that Professor Steinberg and others persist in thinking that forum has a negligible effect in comparison to the merits, while our research seems to prove that forum can have a serious effect on outcome? A clue lies in one of Professor Steinberg's early footnotes: Professor Clermont and Professor Eisenberg do not discuss the radical implications of their suggestion that transfers lead to more accurate outcomes... But if the 29% plaintiff win rate in transferred cases is accurate or just, then presumably the 58% win rate in cases that courts do not transfer is inaccurate or unjust. Following this reasoning, courts should consider transferring every case. 2 3 Although otherwise faulty, Professor Steinberg's point shows that he is thinking of all cases, while we are observing the transfer effect only in the small subset of transferred cases. As we wrote: One would not expect the forum to have a mammoth effect independent of the merits. However, transferred cases do tend to comprise those cases where the substantive effect of forum is greatest After all, the plaintiff tried to forum-shop, the defendant chose to fight back, and the court decided that the forum truly mattered. Thus, it is reasonable to conclude that redressing plaintiffs' forum-shopping 22. See Steinberg, supra note 7, at 1484-85, 1491, 1496. 23. Id. at 1481 n.6. Washington University Open Scholarship

1556 WASHINGTON UNIVERSITY LAW QUARTERLY [VOL. 75:1551 advantage by transfer should decrease the win rate to some extent. 24 In other words, we are not saying that forum-shopping always has a major impact In most cases the plaintiff has chosen a basically fair forum. We are simply saying that in the relatively few cases that the courts transfer, the transfer procedure has offset a serious forum effect. B. Transfer Effect: Normative Thus forum, and hence transfer, affects outcome. But in what way? On this we argued that: as transfer works to neutralize any lopsided cost advantage, and thereby to equalize the effectiveness of the two sides' litigation expenditures, the outcome should be more accurate in the transferee court... Transfer removes the plaintiff's forum advantage when the interest of justice so counsels, and therefore removes the plaintiff's opportunity to gain an unjust victory in litigation or to achieve an unjust settlement 25 Professor Steinberg attacks here too, again with a single line of argument: because transfer shifts the case to a forum chosen by the defendant, and forum-shopping by the defendant is no more conducive to accurate outcomes than forum-shopping by the plaintiff, we cannot draw any normative inference from changed outcomes. 26 This common view misses how transfer of venue works. The plaintiff initially chooses the most favorable forum by filing suit in that one court off the list of proper venues. If the choice is too favorable to tolerate, the defendant moves to transfer to another court off that same list. The judge, typically more neutral and objective than the parties, orders transfer only if it is in the interest of justice. The key difference between the transferor court and the transferee court is that the plaintiff unilaterally chose the former, while the defendant must get the judge to agree that the latter is not only a better forum but a much better forum. 27 Because the transfer process is far from unrestrained forum-shopping by the defendant, Professor Steinberg's argument falls apart. We accordingly summarized that: 24. Clermont & Eisenberg, supra note 1, at 1515. 25. Ma2 26. See Steinberg, supra note 7, at 1486-92, 1496-98. 27. See 15 CHARLES ALAN WRIGHT ET AL., FEDERAL PRACTICE AND PROCEDURE 3847-3854 (2d ed. 1986). http://openscholarship.wustl.edu/law_lawreview/vol75/iss4/7

1997] SIMPLIFYING THE CHOICE OF FORUM: A REPLY 1557 transfer does not shift the choice of forum from plaintiff to defendant, but instead from plaintiff to judge. Moreover, the judge decides to transfer only in rather extreme cases of forum-shopping, normally deferring to the presumption in favor of the selected forum. In short, the transferee forum should generally be a better forum affording a better outcome. 28 II. COSTS OF TRANSFER Critics of transfer without any data tend to assume very high costs of operating the transfer system, and therefore we set out to provide some numbers. We concluded that transfer motions occur in less than 5% of cases, 29 and that most of these motions experience inexpensive handling in the district court and no appeal. 30 Some of the motions have a clear result, reducing the effort that goes into them. 31 Even on most of the closer ones, despite the importance of forum to the parties, the court and the litigants cannot sink grand amounts of resources into the venue fight because of the inherent simplicity of the issues. 32 Professor Steinberg responds only that all this expense still sounds like a lot to him. 33 Well, it sounds fairly considerable to us too, but not in comparison to the benefits of the transfer system. Professor Steinberg continues, however, by taking this opportunity to resurrect his proposal to change the standard under the federal transfer statute, a position to which he committed himself in an earlier article. 34 Professor Steinberg argues that to reduce costs, courts should decide transfer motions usually by considering only the location of the preponderance of relevant witnesses and documents. 35 We certainly would not resist any sound attempt to reduce transfer's costs. However, Professor Steinberg's proposed narrowing of judicial focus to one factor does not seem remotely to capture the appropriate standard of"in the interest of justice." 36 Moreover, Professor Steinberg's cramped focus will not always produce easy questions for 28. Clermont & Eisenberg, supra note 1, at 1516. 29. See id. at 1529. 30. See id. at 1529-30. 31. See id. at 1530. 32. See id. at 1525-30. 33. See Steinberg, supra note 7, at 1492-96. 34. See David E. Steinberg, The Motion to Transfer and the Interest of Justice, 66 NoTRE DAME L. REV. 443 (1990). 35. See Steinberg, supra note 7, at 1499-505. 36. 28 U.S.C. 1404(a) (1994). Washington University Open Scholarship

1558 WASHINGTON UNIVERSITY LAW QUARTERLY [VOL. 75:1551 judicial decision. It could even induce more motions to transfer because defendants could often make a plausible argument for transfer based only on a preponderance of relevant witnesses and documents. It indeed cannot, and does not, completely close the door to the litigants' arguing or the courts' considering other factors, such as the personal circumstances of the parties. Finally, Professor Steinberg's proposal would have profound but unforeseen effects, especially upon plaintiffs, as it is almost equivalent to amending the venue statute to require plaintiffs to bring every suit in the one court with the preponderance of relevant witnesses and documents. In sum, the matter of which forum will be better in producing the better outcome turns on many factors, and any standard that arbitrarily restricts the courts' focus to one factor is ill advised. CONCLUSION Having established that the various benefits of transfer outweigh the costs of administering transfer, we concluded that the legal system, "at the least," should preserve the transfer mechanism. 3 7 Here Professor Steinberg, for the sake of argument, switches sides to accuse us of timidity. 8 However, we expressly observed that there was nothing wrong with a proposal to tighten the plaintiffs' initial choice of forum. 39 One of us, moreover, had already written in favor of "a progressively more restrictive approach on both federal and state levels" to this question of territorial authority to adjudicate 4 and, more to the point and on the basis of our transfer article, subsequently made the following proposal: So plaintiffs today are frequently forum-shopping their way to unjust victories. A role therefore remains for due process-as a robust test of multifactored reasonableness, not a narrow test limited to extreme inconvenience or bias effectively denying a day in court or limited to a few factors such as unfair choice of law [as some have suggested]. We must rely on due process to ensure that the plaintiff is choosing from a limited list of basically fair forums, while also relying on venue provisions to narrow further the choice within a workable system and relying on transfer mechanisms to handle the special cases. 37. See Clermont & Eisenberg, supra note 1, at 1530. 38. See Steinberg, supra note 7, at 1505-12. 39. See Clermont & Eisenberg, supra note 1, at 1510 n.10. 40. See Kevin M. Clermont, Restating Territorial Jurisdiction and Venue for State and Federal Courts, 66 CORNELLL. REV. 411,451 (1981). 41. Kevin M. Clermont, Whither Due Process? Here To Stay, in ASSOCIATION OF AM. LAW http://openscholarship.wustl.edu/law_lawreview/vol75/iss4/7

1997] SIMPLIFYING THE CHOICE OF FORUM: A REPLY 1559 At the time of our transfer article, we were not far enough along in our empirical research to do more than suggest such radical reform. Now that we have studied the forum effect in settings other than transfer of venue, we are ready to argue that the plaintiffs' initial choice of forum is currently a little too wide. Because states have incentives to extend their territorial reach, the most plausible method for restricting them is federal judicial control, which would entail a somewhat greater role for due process. On the federal level, we can hope and argue for a tighter venue statute from Congress. Thus, one could aspire to the situation that Professor Steinberg professedly prefers: "Parties should win or lose cases based on the merits of their substantive claims, and not as a result of procedural maneuvering." 42 Yet Professor Steinberg seems all too content to preserve the current system, where the outcome sometimes turns on the plaintiff's choice of forum. Professor Steinberg also contends that the Court's and Congress's spotty performances to date in the jurisdiction and venue realm somehow establish that current regulation of the plaintiffs' initial choice of forum is optimal. 43 With the new information provided by our empirical research, we are tiying to change that current law and current thinking. Professor Steinberg's reaction indicates that ours will be an uphill battle. SCHOOLS, AALS CONFERENCE ON CIVIL PROCEDURE 37,41 (1995). 42. Steinberg, supra note 7, at 1512. 43. See Steinberg, supra note 7, at 1496-98, 1509-11. But ef Michael E. Solimine, The Quiet Revolution in Personal Jurisdiction 2-4, 42-46 (1998) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the Washington University Law Quarterly) (showing that recent trends in the law of territorial authority to adjudicate are much more ambiguous than Professor Steinberg's representation). Washington University Open Scholarship

http://openscholarship.wustl.edu/law_lawreview/vol75/iss4/7