Abstract. The customary Anglo-Saxon approach to public finance treats the state as

Similar documents
The origins of public finance, as a field of study though most certainly not

1. Political economy and public finance: a brief introduction

The Continental Tradition in the Theory of Public Finance: An Exercise in Mapping and Recovery. Jürgen G. Backhaus

JUSTIFICATION OF THE COMPOUND REPUBLIC: James M. Buchanan

Society, State, and Public Finance: Setting the Analytical Stage Jürgen G. Backhaus and Richard E. Wagner

Constitutional Political Economy 1

From Continental Public Finance to Public Choice: Mapping Continuity. Jürgen G. Backhaus

James M. Buchanan was one of the premiere political economists of the

An Austrian Perspective on Public Choice

KEITH DOUGHERTY. Office Department of Political Science updated 1/1/17 University of Georgia (706)

SYSTEMS ANALYSIS AND MODELING OF INTEGRATED WORLD SYSTEMS - Vol. I - Systems Analysis of Economic Policy - M.G. Zavelsky

Market Failure: Compared to What?

Public Choice. Peter T. Calcagno. College of Charleston. Rhonda Free, ed. (Sage Publishers, 2010) Revised Draft 7/7/2009.

Meddlesome preferences and rent extraction: the tobacco shakedown. Tobacco has become an arena of civil warfare throughout the Western

Pareto Optimality and the Rule of Law

Experimental economics and public choice

Do Voters Have a Duty to Promote the Common Good? A Comment on Brennan s The Ethics of Voting

Meeting Plato s challenge?

James M. Buchanan The Limits of Market Efficiency

WHY DOES GOVERNMENT GROW? THE SOURCES OF GOVERNMENT GROWTH FROM PUBLIC CHOICE PERSPECTIVE

The Contractarian Constitutional Political Economy of James Buchanan. Roger D. Congleton West Virginia University Morgantown WV. September 23, 2013

JOSEPH ALOIS SCHUMPETER

Setting User Charges for Public Services: Policies and Practice at the Asian Development Bank

Lecture Outline: Chapter 2

Overview of the Austrian School theories of capital and business cycles and implications for agent-based modeling

Keynes as an Interpreter of Classical Economics

"Efficient and Durable Decision Rules with Incomplete Information", by Bengt Holmström and Roger B. Myerson

Book review for Review of Austrian Economics, by Daniel B. Klein, George Mason

P1: aaa SJNW N stylea.cls (2005/11/30 v1.0 LaTeX Springer document class) January 2, :37

VII. Sections and Conferences

Robbins as Innovator: the Contribution of An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science

SCIENCE AND SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY THE BUREAUCRATIC WARS FROM PUBLIC CHOICE THEORY

Political Science 200A Week 8. Social Dilemmas

1. At the completion of this course, students are expected to: 2. Define and explain the doctrine of Physiocracy and Mercantilism

RATIONAL CHOICE AND CULTURE

Postscript: Subjective Utilitarianism

Natural Law and Spontaneous Order in the Work of Gary Chartier

Ideology COLIN J. BECK

Prof. Dr. Bernhard Neumärker Summer Term 2016 Albert-Ludwigs-Universität Freiburg. Constitutional Economics. Exam. July 28, 2016

POLITICAL MEANINGS OF PUBLIC DEBT

Curriculum Vita Tony Caporale. January 2013

POLI 111: INTRODUCTION TO THE STUDY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE

Dr. CHEN Chien-Hsun List of Publications: Articles in Refereed Journals:

Topic Page: Hayek, Friedrich A. von (Friedrich August),

Catholic-inspired NGOs FORUM Forum des ONG d inspiration catholique

8. The Need for Wellbeing Measurement in Context

Rousseau s general will, civil rights, and property

Welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft

THE PEOPLE OF THE STATE OF MICHIGAN ENACT:

Imprimis. The national speech digest of Hillsdale College OVER 1,100,000 READERS MONTHLY. Nobel Laureate in Economic Science George Mason University

Social Capital and Social Movements

Department for Economic and Social Affairs (UNDESA) Division for Social Policy and Development

History Major. The History Discipline. Why Study History at Montreat College? After Graduation. Requirements of a Major in History

Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory

International Law s Relative Authority

Notes toward a Theory of Customary International Law The Challenge of Non-State Actors: Standards and Norms in International Law

Chapter 1: Theoretical Approaches to Global Politics

Lived Poverty in Africa: Desperation, Hope and Patience

POLI 359 Public Policy Making

Thomas Oatley. (919) (Work) University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill. (202) (Home) Chapel Hill, NC

CURRICULUM VITAE. Jerry M. Evensky. ADDRESS: Office:

Call for Papers. Special Issue of the Journal of Business Ethics. The Ethics of the Commons. Submission Deadline: 15 December 2018

An American Professor Speaks Out On Poverty Alleviation in China

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

VOTING RULES AND REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF THE RECENT ECONOMIC CRISIS

The Economic Effects of Judicial Selection Dr. John A. Dove Faulkner Lecture Outline

RIGHTS 8. FISCAL POLICY AND PROPERTY

History & Society: The Work of Michael Mann

South East European University Tetovo, Republic of Macedonia 2 ND CYCLE PROGRAM IN PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION. Master studies - Academic Diplomacy

Review of Social Economy. The Uncertain Foundations of Post Keynesian Economics: Essays in Exploration. By Stephen P. Dunn.

Unit Three: Thinking Liberally - Diversity and Hegemony in IPE. Dr. Russell Williams

The Conflict between Notions of Fairness and the Pareto Principle

CAPACITY-BUILDING FOR ACHIEVING THE MIGRATION-RELATED TARGETS

The European Heritage in Economics and the Social Sciences

Complexity, Governance, and Constitutional Craftsmanship. Richard E. Wagner

Grounding Transnational American Studies in European and American Contexts

College of Arts and Sciences. Political Science

The Justification of Justice as Fairness: A Two Stage Process

Faculty of Political Science Thammasat University

HANDBOOK ON COHESION POLICY IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

Political Science. Political Science-1. Faculty: Ball, Chair; Fair, Koch, Lowi, Potter, Sullivan

Classical Political Economy. Week 2 University i of Wollongong

FRED S. MCCHESNEY, Northwestern University, Chicago, IL 60611, U.S.A.

Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress

Rethinking Migration Decision Making in Contemporary Migration Theories

SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE!

Classical Political Economy. Part III. D. Ricardo

W. J. Ethier January The Literature

Civic Participation and Government Spending

Notes on Charles Lindblom s The Market System

APPLICATION FORM FOR PROSPECTIVE WORKSHOP DIRECTORS

Cambridge University Press The Cambridge Rawls Lexicon Edited by Jon Mandle and David A. Reidy Excerpt More information

4. Philip Cortney, The Economic Munich: The I.T.O. Charter, Inflation or Liberty, the 1929 Lesson (New York: Philosophical Library, 1949).

POLITICAL SCIENCE (POLI)

Public Economics [Module code ]

III. PUBLIC CHOICE AND GOVERNMENT AS A SOLUTION

School of Public Policy INTRODUCTION CORE INFORMATION PROGRAMME SPECIFICATIONS. MPhil (18 years of formal education)

3. Public Choice in a Direct Democracy

1 Introduction. Cambridge University Press International Institutions and National Policies Xinyuan Dai Excerpt More information

Fluctuating Transnationalism

Transcription:

James M. Buchanan b. 1919 Abstract The customary Anglo-Saxon approach to public finance treats the state as exogenous to the economic process, which restricts public finance to the study of market-based reactions to exogenous fiscal impositions. In contrast, Buchanan has cultivated an approach to public finance that incorporates the state into the economic process. The domain of fiscal analysis is thus expanded in two directions. One direction, public choice, involves the study of the effect of political institutions on collective choices. The other direction, constitutional political economy, involves the emergence of and changes in political institutions. James M. Buchanan was awarded the 1986 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Science for his seminal role in developing the contractual and constitutional bases for the theory of economic and political decision-making. Buchanan spent his boyhood in rural Tennessee near Murfreesboro. After receiving Batchelor s and Master s degrees from Middle Tennessee State College and the University of Tennessee respectively, he entered the U. S. Navy in 1941. After completing his naval service in the Pacific, Buchanan enrolled at the University of Chicago in 1946, receiving his Ph. D. in 1948. He has spent the preponderance of his academic career at three Virginia universities: the University of Virginia (1956-68), Virginia Polytechnic Institute (1969-83), and

George Mason University (since 1983). Buchanan has been a truly prolific scholar throughout this period, as shown by the 20 volumes it took for Liberty Fund to publish his collected works; moreover, he has continued his scholarly work at full speed since the completion of that collection in 2001. The Nobel citation quoted above identifies two predominant strains within Buchanan s scholarly oeuvre. One of these is the theory of public choice, which entails the application of economic theorizing to politics. The other is constitutional political economy, which explores the relationship between constitutional rules and political outcomes. While Buchanan s body of work also contains numerous contributions to economic theory and methodology, and which by themselves would have constituted a significant scholarly career, this short essay will focus exclusively on Buchanan s approach to public choice and constitutional political economy. Precursory Influences While Buchanan has been creative as well as prolific, he has nonetheless been inspired by and has built upon the contributions of others. Buchanan has acknowledged these precursory influences numerous times, particularly in his autobiographical Better than Plowing where he identifies three sources of primary influence on his work. The primary precursors to Buchanan s public choice theorizing were a set of Italian scholars, among who were Antonio De Viti De Marco, Maffeo Pantaleoni, and Luigi Einaudi, who developed a unique orientation toward public 2

finance between the 1880s and the 1930s. Where Anglo-Saxon scholars treated the state as outside the economy, the Italians sought to incorporate political outcomes into the economic process. For instance, much Anglo-Saxon fiscal scholarship sought to develop norms regarding the desirable degree of tax progressivity, as illustrated by various sacrifice theories of taxation. By contrast, the Italians sought to explain the actual structure of taxation independently of normative concern, and to do so with reference to the same categories of utility and cost as they invoked to explain market outcomes. This Italian orientation of sober realism toward political processes was central to the later development of public choice theorizing. For instance, in his Forward to the German translation of Amilcare Puviani s 1903 treatise on fiscal illusion, Teoria della illusione finanziaria, Gunter Schmölders observed that over the last century Italian public finance has had an essentially political science character.... This work [Puviani] is a typical product of Italian public finance.... Above all, it is the science of public finance combined with fiscal politics, in many places giving a good fit with reality. The Italians were thoroughgoing realists and not romantic idealists, and it was a short distance from their initial formulations to what subsequently became known as public choice. The sober realism of the Italians implied, in keeping with the general equilibrium theorizing of the time, that actual fiscal outcomes were to be explained as equilibrium outcomes. If so, it might seem as though fiscal theorizing offered no coherent vantage point from which to pursue any program of fiscal reform. Yet Buchanan has always sought to use fiscal knowledge as an 3

instrument of fiscal reform. It was Knut Wicksell who provided Buchanan the vehicle for combining his sober realism with his interest in reform. Buchanan s constitutional emphasis can be traced to the second of Wicksell s three essays in Finanztheoretische Untersuchungen, which Buchanan translated as A New Theory of Just Taxation, in Classics in the Theory of Public Finance, edited by Richard Musgrave and Alan Peacock. From Wicksell, Buchanan derived two themes that informed his work thereafter. One theme was the treatment of unanimous consent and not majority approval as the normative benchmark for appraising political outcomes. The other theme was a distinction between constitutional politics, where institutional rules are selected, and postconstitutional politics, where particular outcomes emerge. Wicksell s treatment of two distinct levels of political activity led to Buchanan s articulation of a constitutional political economy, wherein political reform was a matter of changing the rules that govern the game, as distinct from changing the strategies of play within a game. While Wicksell and the Italians cover the two themes mentioned in Buchanan s Nobel citation, any mention of precursory influences would be remiss without including Frank Knight, whom Buchanan initially encountered during his student days at the University of Chicago. Knight s influence on Buchanan is not so much one of particular ideas as of general attitude and orientation toward a scholar s life and work. From Knight, Buchanan carried forward the belief that no doctrine or authority should be treated as sacrosanct and above challenge. Everyone else may say that something is true, but this doesn t mean they are 4

right; there may be many pretentious emperors walking around naked. Buchanan s work has also demonstrated the same multi-disciplinary character that was prominent in Knight s work. For Buchanan, as for Knight, economic theorizing was not self-contained, but had points of contact throughout the humane studies, which led to a style of theorizing wherein Buchanan, as Knight, continually makes contact with such related fields of inquiry as law, ethics, history, philosophy, and politics. From Italian Public Finance to Public Choice The Italianate approach to public finance treated the state as an entity whose actions conformed to the same principles of marginal utility as the actions of other economic participants. The Italians did not seek to advance statements concerning how large the state should be in order to promote some vision of social welfare. They sought instead to offer coherent explanations about the actual size of the state. At the level of formal analysis, this meant that the state would expand until the marginal utility from state-provided services equaled the marginal utility from market-supplied services. To be sure, the Italians recognized the numerous problems of aggregation that were involved in making such statements. In response, they developed a variety of models regarding just whose utility was driving the equilibrium. Where some models treated the state as a cooperative enterprise that worked to the benefit of all, others treated the state as an entity that promoted the advantage of ruling classes. In any case, it 5

was a small step from the Italian fiscal theorizing to the public choice theorizing that began to take shape in the 1960s, as elaborated in Richard Wagner (2003). Perhaps the best place to see the Italianate influence on public choice is Buchanan s 1967 treatise Public Finance in Democratic Process, which was written at a time when public choice was not yet a term of scholarly identification. Buchanan starts that book by noting the narrow and limited scope of Anglo- Saxon approaches to public finance, wherein public finance is concerned only with explaining market-based reactions to exogenously imposed taxes and expenditures. On the tax side of the budget, for instance, a progressive income tax with several brackets of rising marginal rates might be replaced by a degressive tax where a single marginal rate is imposed above some initial exemption. The task of the fiscal scholar would be to explain the impact of such an exogenous tax shift on such things as the amount of labor people supply, the amount of underground economic activity they undertake, and the amount of taxable income they earn. Alternatively, on the expenditure side of the budget, an appropriation might be made to finance a highway. The task of fiscal analysis would be to analyze the market-based reactions to the highway. For instance, land rents near highway exits might rise, due to the reduction in travel time that resulted. Whatever the particular topic examined, the analytical task of Anglo- Saxon public finance has everything to do with explaining market-based reactions to exogenously imposed fiscal measures and has nothing to do with explaining state budgets and fiscal institutions. 6

In treating state budgets as exogenous to fiscal inquiry, the Anglo-Saxon orientation toward public finance ignored two large areas of possible inquiry, both of which Buchanan explores in Public Finance in Democratic Process. One ignored area is the ability of fiscal institutions to influence budgetary outcomes and not just market outcomes. This topic occupies the first part of Public Finance in Democratic Process, and the analyses presented there were early illustrations of public choice theorizing. The second ignored area is the choice or emergence of fiscal institutions. This topic occupies the second part of Public Finance in Democratic Process, and the analyses presented there were harbingers to subsequent work in constitutional political economy. Buchanan gives several illustrations in Public Finance in Democratic Process of how fiscal institutions and arrangements might influence fiscal outcomes, of which I shall mention three. First, Buchanan examines the possible budgetary consequences of a choice between general-fund financing and tax earmarking. Under the former practice, tax revenues accrue to a general fund from which various appropriations are made; under the latter practice, specific taxes are earmarked to finance particular services. Buchanan suggests that general-fund financing is a form of tie-in sale that might bring about a budgetary shift in favor of services in relatively elastic demand. Second, Buchanan examines the possible budgetary consequences of the withholding of income taxes. His analysis in this case is related to claims about fiscal illusion or perception. Buchanan argues that individual perceptions about the costliness of public output depend on the manner in which tax extractions are 7

made. Perhaps the most open and direct manner of paying for public output would be for people to write monthly checks to government, just as they pay their utility bills. Buchanan explores the possibility that withholding may create some tendency for individuals to perceive the costliness of government to be less than it would otherwise be, which should in turn lead to some increase in the size of government. Third, Buchanan examines the effect of public debt on budgetary outcomes, a topic that he initially explored in Public Principles of Public Debt and to which he returned in Democracy in Deficit (co-authored with Richard Wagner). The principle of Ricardian equivalence holds that tax finance and debt finance are identical. In the aggregate, this is true as a simple matter of double-entry accounting. If $1 million of tax revenue is replaced by public borrowing, the present value of the future payments necessary to service the debt will equal the tax reduction. However, the collectivity does not act as a unit, so a statement about aggregate equivalence is irrelevant for any effort to explain fiscal conduct. What matters for collective action is the direction of individual desires as these are mediated through political and fiscal institutions. For instance, people in higher age ranges will find debt to be less costly than taxation, increasingly so with age. Compare a tax of $1,000 now with a perpetual debt that entails payments of $100 when the appropriate discount rate is ten percent. In terms of perpetuity, the debt and the tax are equivalent. For a younger person who might look forward to 50 taxpaying years, the present value of the debt is $991. For an 8

older person who might have but ten years of tax paying life expectancy left, the present value of the debt is but $614. To be sure, it could be claimed that the older person has some bequest motivation toward heirs. If so, that older person would treat the debt obligation as continuing beyond his life. But not all older people have heirs. And of those that do, not all of them seem to have the types of bequest motives that generate Ricardian equivalence. This point gets to another significant feature of Buchanan s thought: his unwillingness to make statements based on aggregates without exploring the underlying structural patterns to which those aggregates pertain. After all, aggregates are not entities that act, and in Buchanan s approach collective action must be generated out of choices by discernable, acting individuals, as these choices are mediated through institutional frameworks for making collective choices. The literature on public choice has, of course, exploded since 1967, with entrées to this literature provided by such compendia as Mueller (1997), Rowley and Schneider (2004), and Shughart and Razzolini (2001). A good deal of that literature has carried forward the effort of Buchanan and his Italian forebears to articulate the impact of political institutions on collective outcomes. From Wicksell to Constitutional Political Economy Where public choice examines the impact of political and fiscal institutions on collective outcomes, constitutional political economy examines the impact of constitutional rules on post-constitutional outcomes. The seminal statement of 9

constitutional political economy is the Calculus of Consent (co-authored with Gordon Tullock), which the authors described as simply an elaboration with economic logic of the American constitutional framework of 1789. According to that framework, government is established by the consent of the governed, which provides unanimity as the conceptual starting point, just as it did for Wicksell (Wagner (1988) explores the relationship between Wicksell and the Calculus of Consent). While unanimity is the conceptual starting point, any effort actually to implement unanimity will confront free riders and strategic holdouts. If everyone s consent is required to undertake collective action, some people will be tempted to withhold their consent, not because they object to the action but because they are acting strategically to shift the fiscal terms of the action in their favor. Such strategic efforts at securing distributional gain can sabotage projects that are genuinely beneficial to all. Consequently, people may reasonably agree to be bound by something less than unanimous consent. Buchanan and Tullock conceptualized a trade-off between decision costs and external costs, as these are viewed from the perspective of participants in collective choice. Decision costs are the costs people bear in trying to reach a collective decision. The greater the degree of consent required, the higher will be those costs due to such things as free riding and strategic bargaining. External costs are the costs that individuals bear when collective choices run contrary to their desires. These costs will fall with increases in the degree of consent required to take to collective action, and will vanish when unanimity is required. An optimal voting rule, formally speaking, will result when the sum of 10

those costs is minimized. With this analytical construction, Buchanan and Tullock provided a rationalization for Knut Wicksell s support for some supermajority rule within a parliamentary assembly, as illustrated by references to three-quarters and four-fifths consent. A voting rule is a simple scalar. Actual constitutional frameworks for collective choice contain a vector of characteristics, and to some extent those other characteristics can substitute for greater inclusivity in the degree of consent required. For instance, a representative assembly that is bicameral can achieve a greater degree of consensus with a less inclusive voting rule than would be possible within a unicameral assembly. Legislative action, moreover, can be filtered in various fashions through different parliamentary rules. There are many margins along which political and fiscal institutions can be modified, and with post-constitutional politics adapting to whatever constitutional framework is in place. There are two levels of analysis in Buchanan s analytical schema: constitutional and post-constitutional. Post-constitutional politics, public choice, represents the working out of interactions among political participants within the context of some particular institutional arrangement. Constitutional politics concerns the selection among possible institutional arrangements. Buchanan s distinction between constitutional and post-constitutional politics calls forth the distinction between choosing the rules of a game and choosing strategies by which to play a game. For Buchanan, reform is a constitutional and not a postconstitutional matter. 11

Consider, for instance, his approach to progressive income taxation. Where the Anglo-Saxon sacrifice theorists sought to specify the degree of progressivity that some exogenous authority should impose on a society, Buchanan sought to probe the circumstances under which people might choose to employ progressivity in taxing themselves. In several places, he explores the conditions under which people might support progressive income taxation as a form of income insurance. Progressive taxation allows people to achieve some smoothing of consumption in the presence of fluctuating income, as compared with proportional taxation. The purchase of insurance, after all, is a constitutional and not a post-constitutional activity: people purchase insurance before they have had accidents and not after. To the extent such formulations have merit, what appears to be redistribution when seen from an ex post perspective might represent mutual gains from trade when viewed from an ex ante, constitutional perspective. Alternatively, consider the treatment of broad-based taxation in Buchanan and Congleton (1998). Without a constitutional requirement of uniformity in taxation, post-constitutional politics will generate increasingly complex revenue systems as tax favors are granted or removed within the political marketplace. While the resulting narrowing of the tax base imposes excess burdens on market participants, it also warps processes of collective choice. For instance, those who are favored by the resulting fiscal discrimination will support more collective activity than they would otherwise support. With the continual churning of the tax 12

code that results, however, most participants may end up worse off than they would have been under a simple system of tax uniformity. Buchanan s Legacy Until the late-1930s there was a flourishing continental orientation toward public finance that stood in contrast to the Anglo-Saxon orientation, and pretty much along the lines articulated by Buchanan in Public Finance in Democratic Process (this thesis is elaborated in Backhaus and Wagner (forthcoming)). Within this orientation, public finance was a multidisciplinary field of study, with a home in economics but with tentacles that reach out into such fields as politics, law, and public administration. Buchanan has carried forward the continental approach to public finance, and has given it new life through his many creative works. 13

Selected Works Buchanan, J. M. 1999-2002. The Collected Works of James M. Buchanan. 20 vols. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund. [This collection contains the preponderance of his academic work through the late 1990s, both books and papers.] Buchanan, J. M. 1958. Public Principles of Public Debt. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin. Buchanan, J. M. 1967. Public Finance in Democratic Process. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press. Buchanan, J. M. 1992. Better than Plowing. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Buchanan, J. M. and Tullock, G. 1962. The Calculus of Consent. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Buchanan, J. M. and Wagner, R. E. 1977. Democracy in Deficit. New York: Academic Press. Buchanan, J. M. and Congleton, R. D. 1998. Politics by Principle, Not Interest. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Bibliography Backhaus, J. G. and Wagner, R. E. Forthcoming. From Continental Public Finance to Public Choice: Mapping Continuity. History of Political Economy. Mueller, D. C., ed. 1997. Perspectives on Public Choice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 14

Musgrave, R. A. and Peacock, A. T., eds. 1958. Classics in the Theory of Public Finance. London: Macmillan. Puviani, A. 1960. Die Illusionen in der öffentlichen Finanzwirtschaft. Berlin: Dunker & Humblot, 1960. [This is a German translation of Puviani s 1903 Teoria della illusione finanziaria.] Rowley, C. K, and Schneider, F. 2004. The Encyclopedia of Public Choice. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Shughart, W. F. II and Razzolini, L., eds. 2001. The Elgar Companion to Public Choice. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. Wagner, R. E. 2003. Public Choice and the Diffusion of Classic Italian Public Finance. Il pensiero economico 11: 271-82. Wagner, R. E. 1988. "The Calculus of Consent: A Wicksellian Retrospective." Public Choice 56: 153-66. Richard E. Wagner George Mason University 15