CPI Antitrust Chronicle February 2012 (1)

Similar documents
Comments on DG Competition s Guidance on procedures of the Hearing Officers in proceedings relating to Articles 101 and 102 TFEU *

Roundtable on challenges and co-ordination of leniency programmes - Note by the United States

Enforcement Response Guidelines

Global Forum on Competition

WAIKATO REGIONAL COUNCIL ENFORCEMENT POLICY TE KAUPAPA HERE ŪRUHITANGA A TE KAUNIHERA Ā-ROHE O WAIKATO

MEMORANDUM. Criminal Procedure and Remedies Issues Recommended for Commission Study

Summary of Discussion Points. Presented by the Business and Industry Advisory Committee (BIAC) to the OECD Competition Committee Working Party No.

FCA Consultation on Concurrent Competition Powers. Response of Norton Rose Fulbright LLP

Draft Recommendation CM/Rec (2018) XX of the Committee of Ministers to member States concerning restorative justice in criminal matters

Global Forum on Competition

2. Compliance A state in which all Metro Vancouver bylaw and relevant provincial legal requirements are met.

TD/RBP/CONF.7/L.10. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. Model Law on Competition (2010) Chapter X. United Nations GE.

UNDERSTANDING AND DEALING WITH LUAs, DORs AND ADVERSE EXAMINATION FINDINGS

ORGANIZATIONAL SENTENCING GUIDELINES THE HONORABLE RUBEN J. CASTILLO VICE-CHAIR, U.S. SENTENCING COMMISSION

FCA Mission: Our Approach to Enforcement. March 2018

How ACPERA Has Affected Criminal Cartel Enforcement

FOOD LAW ENFORCEMENT POLICY

Private sector-led challenges to anti-competitive behaviour. Growth and fairness: private sector-led challenges to anti-competitive behaviour

CHAPTER EIGHT - SENTENCING OF ORGANIZATIONS

ARGUMENTS FOR PROSECUTORS OF ENVIRONMENTAL

The Proposed Damages Directive: The Real Lessons from the United States

January 25, 2012 INTRODUCTION & EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

On the Alleged Disproportionate Sentencing of Cartel Managers

RADTECH INTERNATIONAL NORTH AMERICA (RadTech) ANTITRUST COMPLIANCE MANUAL

Ethical issues in enforcement Krista Weymouth Senior Associate. 24 February 2015

Due Diligence: The Sentencing Guidelines and the Lawyer s Role in Corporate Compliance and Ethics Programs. by Steven Carr

January 19, Executive Summary. the two-stage interim grant of immunity process,

BEST PRACTICES IN REGULATION OF LOBBYING ACTIVITIES

F4 & F5 Offender Placement

INTEL AND THE DEATH OF U.S. ANTITRUST LAW

Guidance on consumer enforcement CAP 1018

Global Forum on Competition

Guidance on the use of enforcement action June 2016

Private Actions for Infringement of Competition Laws in the EU: An Ongoing Project

COMPETITION AND ANTITRUST LAW

Will the Third Time Be the Charm? Antitrust Whistleblower Protections May Need Further Incentives to Pass the House

Independent review of the Financial Reporting Council s enforcement procedures sanctions

President's introduction

European Commission staff working document - public consultation: Towards a coherent European Approach to Collective Redress

Quantifying Harm for Breaches of Antitrust Rules A European Union Perspective

(Translation) Announcement. NFS Asset Management Company Limited. PorBorSor. NFS 002/2017. Subject: Anti-Corruption Policy

CPI Antitrust Chronicle July 2012 (1)

TAUC The Association of Union Contractors ANTITRUST COMPLIANCE PROGRAM

(1) the nature and circumstances of the offense and the history and characteristics of the defendant;

Notice of 16 May 2011 on the Method Relating to the Setting of Financial Penalties

CHAPTER 14 PUNISHMENT AND SENTENCING CHAPTER OUTLINE. I. Introduction. II. Sentencing Rationales. A. Retribution. B. Deterrence. C.

Should Cartel Laws Be Criminalised?

PROCEDURE OF SETTING FINES IMPOSED PURSUANT TO THE ACT ON THE PROTECTION OF COMPETITION

June 3, Introduction

INTERIM GUIDANCE FOR INVESTIGATING TITLE VI ADMINISTRATIVE COMPLAINTS CHALLENGING PERMITS

Responding to Government Investigations

A Guide to the UK s Bribery Act 2010 Martin Polaine. London Centre of International Law Practice. Anti-corruption Forum, 007/ /02/2015

TRUST IN JUSTICE ESS. Professor Mike Hough Birkbeck College

Tackling Exploitation in the Labour Market Response to the Department of Business Innovation & Skills and Home Office consultation December 2015

PART H - SPECIFIC OFFENDER CHARACTERISTICS. Introductory Commentary

Fraud, bribery and money laundering: corporate offenders Definitive Guideline DEFINITIVE GUIDELINE

COMMERCE COMMISSION NEW ZEALAND

FAIRNESS VERSUS WELFARE. Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell. Thesis: Policy Analysis Should Be Based Exclusively on Welfare Economics

(2012), available at

Ways in which the System of Sanctions in EU Competition Enforcement can be changed

Civil Liability Bill

Q1) Do you agree or disagree with the Council s approach to the distinction between a principle and a purpose of sentencing?

1. offering, promising or giving a bribe (in the UK or overseas); 2. requesting, agreeing to receive or accepting a bribe (in the UK or overseas);

CPI Antitrust Journal November 2010 (1)

New guidelines for sentencing of Health & Safety offences and Corporate Manslaughter

2015 GUIDELINES MANUAL

Strategic Considerations for Business Lawyers: Resolving Disputes through ADR or Litigation

Penalties for Anti-Competitive Conduct: Sharpening the sting of South Africa s competition authorities

CARTEL OFFENCE: THE UK EXPERIENCE Philipp Girardet, SJ Berwin. 44 th FIW Symposium, 11 March v1

Shalala v. Illinois Council on Long Term Care, Inc.

Litigation PROPOSED AMENDMENTS TO FEDERAL SENTENCING GUIDELINES POTENTIALLY IMPACT ORGANIZATIONAL COMPLIANCE PROGRAMS

Society for Ecological Corporate Sponsorship Ethics & Decision-Making Framework June 2016

21. Creating criminal offences

HORIZONTAL MARKET POWER: THE EVOLVING LAW AND ECONOMICS OF MERGERS AND CARTELS

An Introduction to Stakeholder Dialogue

ANTITRUST COMPLIANCE GUIDE FOR THE MANAGED FUNDS ASSOCIATION

BID RIGGING CARTELS IN PUBLIC PROCUREMENT

London Criminal Courts Solicitors Association. Response to the Sentencing Advisory Panel Consultation Paper on Bail Act Offences

Anti-Bribery Policy. Policies, Guidance & Procedures. The Collett School, St Luke s School Forest House Education Centre

CPI Antitrust Chronicle December 2013 (1)

CPI Antitrust Chronicle February 2013 (1)

October Guideline to Disciplinary Committee for Determining Disciplinary Orders

THE OECD COMPETITION LAW AND POLICY INDICATORS QUESTIONNAIRE

Anthony Norton Norton's Inc. Criminalisation of cartel behaviour: Implications for corporates in South Africa

PARLIAMENTARY RESEARCH BRANCH DIRECTION DE LA RECHERCHE PARLEMENTAIRE

Criminal Liability of Companies Survey. U.S.A. - California Morrison & Foerster LLP

EC consultation Collective Redress

ARBITRATION AND COMPETITION LAW NEW PROSPECTS OF RECOVERY FOR VICTIMS OF ANTITRUST INFRINGEMENTS

Frequently Asked Questions: Sentencing Guidelines (6 th Edition & 6 th Edition, Revised) and General Sentencing Issues

New Zealand Institute of Surveyors. Policy Statement

UNITED STATES ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY WASHINGTON, D.C January 12, 1994

Referring to Article 110 of the Constitution of the Republic of Kosovo and the Law on Kosovo Prosecutorial Council (Nr.03/L-244)

Working Party No. 3 on Co-operation and Enforcement

COMMENTS OF THE ABA SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW ON THE PROPOSED AMENDMENTS TO THE ANTITRUST RECOMMENDATIONS OF THE UNITED STATES SENTENCING GUIDELINES

NORTHERN IRELAND SOCIAL CARE COUNCIL

Issues Paper Concerning Unregulated Legal Service Providers

Responding to Government Investigations: What to do when the Government Knocks. Gabriel Colwell Partner Squire Patton Boggs (US) LLP

Attorney/Client Privilege Waiver Requests: Charging Corporations Under The McNulty Memorandum KIRSTEN V. MAYER

Information Notice. Information Notice. Reference: ComReg 17/49

Enforcement Proceedings Framework for Enforcement Sanctions and Costs

Transcription:

CPI Antitrust Chronicle February 2012 (1) Normative Compliance The Endgame Caron Beaton-Wells University of Melbourne www.competitionpolicyinternational.com Competition Policy International, Inc. 2012 Copying, reprinting, or distributing this article is forbidden by anyone other than the publisher or author.

Normative Compliance: The Endgame Caron Beaton-Wells 1 Global anti-cartel enforcement has developed over the last decade into a formidable enterprise. Competition authorities have considerable powers and resources and are networked with each other in a way that gives them unprecedented access to expertise and information. Most authorities marshal immunity and leniency policies tools for detecting and prosecuting illegal activity in a way that would be the envy of law enforcers in any other field. In the United States and European Union, as well as in an increasing number of other jurisdictions, when offenders are detected they are subject to debilitating corporate fines and, if not fined themselves, individuals may be banned from management or, in some places, jailed. The process of investigation and enforcement is extremely costly and time consuming. The reputational damage to the corporations and often the individuals involved is inestimable. This enforcement industry 2 is justified by reference to the economic harm associated with anticompetitive conduct, and cartels in particular. The overriding goal is said to be deterrence specific and general. Deterrence is narrowly characterized for this purpose as the rational calculative response by potential offenders to the prospect of formal legal consequences for breaching the law. The degree of deterrence is seen to be conditioned primarily, if not exclusively, by the potential offender s fear of, or at least desire to avoid, such consequences. One consequence of the overriding focus on deterrence is that it may detract from a focus on compliance. Compliance may be seen as a secondary, or at least a separate concern, of enforcement authorities. Moreover, the relationship between deterrence-oriented enforcement action and compliance, particularly normative compliance, appears rarely to be considered at least by enforcers. However, there is substantial research to support the view that motivations and behavior in relation to legal compliance are far more complex than this emphasis on deterrence allows for. 3 This research supports the adoption of a broader approach that encompasses a range of strategies, formal and informal, that are employed in contextually sensitive ways. Based on the well-known theory of responsive regulation, 4 such an approach emphasizes compliance as the ultimate goal and deterrence as one of various strategies that may be invoked to motivate or, if necessary, secure compliance. Depicted as a pyramid, the responsive regulation model identifies 1 Associate Professor, University of Melbourne. 2 See, further, Christopher Harding, The Anti-Cartel Enforcement Industry: Criminological Perspectives on Cartel Criminalisation, CRIMINALISING CARTELS: CRITICAL STUDIES OF AN INTERNATIONAL REGULATORY MOVEMENT, Ch. 16 (C. Beaton-Wells & A. Ezrachi eds., 2011). 3 See, specifically in this context, Christine Parker & Vibeke Lehmann Nielsen, Deterrence and the impact of calculative thinking on business compliance with competition and consumer regulation, (56)2 ANTITRUST BULL., 377 (2001). There is considerable research bearing on this from a wide range of fields, including psychology, organizational theory, business strategy, and behavioral economics. 4 The seminal exposition of which remains IAN AYRES & JOHN BRAITHWAITE, RESPONSIVE REGULATION: TRANSCENDING THE DEREGULATION DEBATE (1992). 2

the capacity to persuade businesses to voluntarily comply in a social interaction as the baseline for enforcement strategies that are then escalated to deterrence and punishment where necessary. Deterrence and punishment are considered most effective when held in reserve, threatening in the background but never in the foreground, 5 and only used in the most serious cases at the tip of the pyramid. The responsive regulation approach has been extended by a further body of research that explores the motivations for compliance. According to this research, compliance should be understood as influenced by a constellation of plural motivations economic, social, and normative. 6 Economic motivation to comply is clearly based on the commitment by a firm or individual to maximize economic utility and hence is most directly influenced by the deterrenceoriented strategy of increasing the costs of non-compliance through the threat of formal legal sanctions. However, informal economic sanctions, such as the damage to brand value and reputation through adverse publicity should also be counted as material to economic motivation. Additionally, the economic costs and gains associated with compliance (as distinct from noncompliance) are relevant. Economic motivation is not only influenced by the costs and gains associated with the activity that may ultimately be found to be in breach of the law (i.e., with non-compliance). Firms also weigh the costs of investing in compliance programs and training, for example, against the benefits of improving customer and employee retention and satisfaction through a demonstrated commitment to compliance. 7 Social motivation captures the extent to which firms or individuals are influenced in their decisions to comply, or not comply, with the law by the value they attach to the approval or respect of significant others. Social motivation may be linked to economic motivation in the sense that social disapproval might lead to economic losses. However, the independent distinctive motivation to be well regarded, including to the extent of acting against one s economic selfinterest, and even if not normatively committed to compliance, should not be discounted. Consistent with this, there is empirical evidence to support the proposition that businesses are concerned to preserve the respect and esteem of third parties including customers, shareholders, employees, and business partners and that, in respect of some of these stakeholders (customers and employees especially), such concerns have a positive impact on compliance behavior. 8 It should be expected that family and friends also exert a powerful social influence. Ultimately the most effective, efficient, and sustainable form of compliance is compliance that is normatively motivated; that is, compliance based on a voluntary normative commitment to adhere to the law. This is the scenario in which compliance is internalized by a sense of duty and does not require activation by some external force or pressure. Normative motivation to 5 JOHN BRAITHWAITE, RESTORATIVE JUSTICE AND RESPONSIVE REGULATION, 35 (2002). 6 See Vibeke Nielsen & Christine Parker, Mixed Motives: Economic, Social and Normative Motivations in Business Compliance (forthcoming), drawing in turn on Soren Winter & Peter May, Motivation for compliance with environmental regulations, 20 J. POL Y ANALYSIS & MGMT. 675 (2001). More generally, see the various contributions in EXPLAINING COMPLIANCE (Christine Parker & Vibeke Nielsen eds., 2011). 7 See Christine Parker & Vibeke Nielsen, How Much Does it Hurt? How Australian Businesses Think About the Costs and Gains of Compliance and Non-Compliance with the Trade Practices Act, 32 MELB. U. L. REV. 554 (2008). 8 See Vibeke Nielsen & Christine Parker, To What Extent do Third Parties Influence Business Compliance? 35(3) J. LAW & SOCIETY 309 (2008). There is potential also for the enforcement agency itself to exercise social relational influence. 3

comply can be based on a belief that a law is just or right in the sense that obeying the law leads to an outcome that fits with moral or ideological values the regulated business complies with rules because its managers and employees see those rules as substantively just or right. They agree with the ethos of competition and agree there should be a law to protect it. Further, an impressive body of empirical research has established that people are also likely to obey a law where they see that law, and its enforcement, as legitimate, and that they judge legitimacy by whether the relevant legal authorities are procedurally just or fair. People comply because they recognize the legitimate authority of the law and of the regulatory agencies that administer and enforce the law, rather than, or in addition to, evaluating the substance of the law. 9 Businesses are influenced by all three types of motivation. And there are likely to be some contexts in which different types of motivation support each other and other contexts in which they may chafe against or conflict with each other. Enforcement agencies should be concerned to activate every possible motivation for compliance, but should also be sensitive to potential conflicts between strategies that are directed at different types of motivation in particular, strategies that may have a bearing on both economic (deterrence-related) and normative motivations. There are several aspects of the current deterrence-oriented approach to the public enforcement of competition laws that could be seen as damaging to normative compliance, either because they may be seen as antithetical to the substantive rationale for competition law or because they may be viewed as procedurally unjust or unfair. Three such aspects are highlighted below. First, immunity policies are justified entirely by the need to detect and deter conduct that is said otherwise to be largely undetectable and hence undeterrable. However, the impact of such policies on normative compliance appears rarely, if ever, to be considered by public enforcers and other immunity advocates. These policies reduce law enforcement to a game 10 the company that is first to the confessional wins, and winner takes all. The outcome is determined by timing only, and sometimes as a matter of days or hours. Neither the circumstances in which the immunity beneficiary came to be first, nor the compliance commitment of the beneficiary relative to other parties to the offending conduct, are relevant. 11 Moreover, in most jurisdictions, the immunity prize does not include any requirement to implement, improve, or update a compliance program. Nor does it generally require the beneficiary to take reasonable steps to make restitution to the victims of the cartel. It is difficult to imagine how this scenario promotes respect for the law or its administration. The challenges of cartel detection are not to be discounted. However, as with any 9 See TOM R. TYLER, WHY PEOPLE OBEY THE LAW (2006); Tom R. Tyler & John Darley, Building a Law-Abiding Society: Taking Public Views About Morality and the Legitimacy of Legal Authorities into Account when Formulating Substantive Law, 28 HOFSTRA L. REV. 707 (2000). 10 See Joe Murphy, Compliance Policy at the Antitrust Division, BLOOMBERG LAW REPORTS (November 8, 2011). 11 See the examples in Joe Murphy, Promoting Compliance with Competition Law: Do Compliance and Ethics Programs Have a Role to Play?, Paper for Roundtable on Promoting Compliance with Competition Law, OECD DAF/COMP(2011), October 7, 2011, [30]-[37] (Paper circulated for Competition Committee meeting on June 29-30, 2011). 4

enforcement tool, good public policy demands that both the benefits and costs of its use be counted. Second, as discussed elsewhere in this Chronicle, there are jurisdictions (the United States and European Union particularly) in which prosecutorial and penalty decisions are made without regard to the efforts made by the company to ensure compliance. In the United States, the Department of Justice Antitrust Division ( DOJ ) has a special carve-out for antitrust cases from the compliance program provisions of the U.S. Attorney s Manual and there is a similar carveout from the U.S. Sentencing Guidelines which would otherwise allow a company to rely on its compliance program and record by way of mitigation. The DOJ is unusual among U.S. enforcement agencies in this regard. Similarly the European Commission has recently published compliance guidance urging companies to take compliance seriously but, at the same time, rejecting the relevance of compliance programs in calculating penalties. The contradiction in these positions by the U.S. and E.U. authorities is not hard to miss. The legitimacy of an authority advocating compliance on the one hand while choosing to ignore it for certain purposes on the other is highly questionable as a matter of public policy, not to mention practical effectiveness in achieving compliance the ultimate objective. Third, while there is growing support for private actions for damages in respect of anticompetitive conduct around the world, public enforcement agencies by and large remain adamant that private claimants should receive minimal assistance from agencies by way of access to information on their files. The rationale for this stance relates primarily to protection of the efficacy of immunity policies. At its essence, the argument made in support of such protection prioritizes deterrence (through the heightened prospects of detection with an immunity policy) over the facilitation of compensation for victims of cartel conduct. The argument may not be problematic where other measures are taken to facilitate compensation, including requiring immunity beneficiaries to take reasonable steps to compensate victims or otherwise incentivizing cooperation with private claimants. 12 However, it conceivably threatens normative compliance where competition authorities pursue an enforcement agenda that makes no provision or does not reasonably provide in some way for compensation. At this point it is possible only to theorize about the impact of current public enforcement policies on normative compliance among the business community. Empirical research on such matters would assist competition authorities in an ongoing effort to develop and customize strategies aimed at maximizing compliance with competition laws. And that ultimately should be the endgame. 12 As for example, under the Antitrust Criminal Penalty Enhancement and Reform Act (2004) 15 USC 1. 5