COVER SHEET. EU institutional reform: Evidence on globalization and international cooperation. Phone: ; Secretary

Similar documents
Lecture # 3 Economics of European Integration

The Root of the Matter: Voting in the EU Council. Wojciech Słomczyński Institute of Mathematics, Jagiellonian University, Kraków, Poland

Turkey: Economic Reform and Accession to the European Union

The Impact of Turkey s Membership on EU Voting. Richard Baldwin and Mika Widgrén. Abstract

In this lecture, we will explore weighted voting systems further. Examples of shortcuts to determining winning coalitions and critical players.

What is The European Union?

THE DRAFT CONSTITUTIONAL TREATY S VOTING REFORM DILEMMA

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

The European Union in a Global Context

Asylum Seekers in Europe May 2018

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005

The Financial Crises of the 21st Century

Jagiellonian Compromise

Lectures on European Integration History. G. Di Bartolomeo

POLICYBRIEF EUROPEAN. Searching for EMU reform consensus INTRODUCTION

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

A HISTORY of INTEGRATION in EUROPE

Regional Economic Integration : the European Union Process.

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different?

History Over the past decades, US relations have been mostly positive either with the EU and its predecessors or the individual countries of western E

Transitional Measures concerning the Schengen acquis for the states of the last accession: the cases of Bulgaria and Romania.

On the Weights of Nations: Assigning Voting Weights in a Heterogeneous Union Salvador Barberà and Matthew O. Jackson

OLLI 2012 Europe s Destiny Session II Integration and Recovery Transformative innovation or Power Play with a little help from our friends?

The impact of international patent systems: Evidence from accession to the European Patent Convention

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018

V. Decision-making in Brussels The negotiation and decision phase: ordinary legislative procedure, Council Working Groups etc.

Extended Findings. Finland. ecfr.eu/eucoalitionexplorer. Question 1: Most Contacted

POLITICS OF MIGRATION LECTURE II. Assit.Prof.Dr. Ayselin YILDIZ Yasar University (Izmir/Turkey) UNESCO Chair on International Migration

Brexit. Alan V. Deardorff University of Michigan. For presentation at Adult Learning Institute April 11,

Regional inequality and the impact of EU integration processes. Martin Heidenreich

Statewatch Analysis. EU Lisbon Treaty Analysis no. 4: British and Irish opt-outs from EU Justice and Home Affairs (JHA) law

Statewatch Analysis. EU Reform Treaty Analysis no. 4: British and Irish opt-outs from EU Justice and Home Affairs (JHA) law

From a continent of war to one of and prosperity

From Europe to the Euro. Delegation of the European Union to the United States

LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES

Report: The Impact of EU Membership on UK Molecular bioscience research

Letter prices in Europe. Up-to-date international letter price survey. March th edition

The Components of Wage Inequality and the Role of Labour Market Flexibility

Outside and inside at the same time? Lessons from Norway for Brexit. Karen Helene Ulltveit-moe

A timeline of the EU. Material(s): Timeline of the EU Worksheet. Source-

Fertility rate and employment rate: how do they interact to each other?

Decision Making in Europe: Were Spain and Poland Right to Stop the Constitution in December 2003? 1

Mark Scheme (Results) Summer GCE Government & Politics EU Political Issues 6GP04 4A

III Decision-making in the ESS - the decision-making phase

From Europe to the Euro

Brexit essentials: Alternatives to EU membership

Standard Note: SN/SG/6077 Last updated: 25 April 2014 Author: Oliver Hawkins Section Social and General Statistics

Intellectual Property Rights Intensive Industries and Economic Performance in the European Union

ISSUE BRIEF: U.S. Immigration Priorities in a Global Context

The Changing Relationship between Fertility and Economic Development: Evidence from 256 Sub-National European Regions Between 1996 to 2010

FACULTY OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION. Master Thesis,,THE EUROPEAN UNION S ENLARGEMENT POLICY SINCE ITS CREATION CHAELLENGES AND ACHIEVEMENTS

Migration and the European Job Market Rapporto Europa 2016

Bachelorproject 2 The Complexity of Compliance: Why do member states fail to comply with EU directives?

Civil and Political Rights

TESTOF KNOWLEDGE ACQUIRED

Economics Level 2 Unit Plan Version: 26 June 2009

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Christian KEUSCHNIGG. Europe after Brexit

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Labour mobility within the EU - The impact of enlargement and the functioning. of the transitional arrangements

Flash Eurobarometer 430. Summary. European Union Citizenship

From Europe to the Euro Student Orientations 2014 Euro Challenge

Flash Eurobarometer 431. Report. Electoral Rights

Shake Hands or Shake Apart? Pre-war Global Trade and Currency. Blocs: the Role of the Japanese Empire

Electoral rights of EU citizens

The Transmission of Economic Status and Inequality: U.S. Mexico in Comparative Perspective

International Summer Program

5-Year Evaluation of the Korea-EU FTA Implementation

Where are the Middle Class in OECD Countries? Nathaniel Johnson (CUNY and LIS) David Johnson (University of Michigan)

Evolution of the European Union, the euro and the Eurozone Sovereign Debt Crisis

Economics of European Integration Lecture # 10 Monetary Integration II

THE TREATY ESTABLISHING A CONSTITUTION FOR EUROPE: IMPLICATIONS FOR ASYLUM AND IMMIGRATION IN THE UK

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications

Statewatch briefing on the European Evidence Warrant to the European Parliament

European Union Passport

IMPLICATIONS OF WAGE BARGAINING SYSTEMS ON REGIONAL DIFFERENTIATION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION LUMINITA VOCHITA, GEORGE CIOBANU, ANDREEA CIOBANU

REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY

Through the Financial Crisis

Inequality and Anti-globalization Backlash by Political Parties

European Parliament Elections: Turnout trends,

HIGHLIGHTS. There is a clear trend in the OECD area towards. which is reflected in the economic and innovative performance of certain OECD countries.

Regional and Sectoral Economic Studies

The United Kingdom in the European context top-line reflections from the European Social Survey

Convergence across EU Members and the Consequences for the Czech Republic

Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries

Commission on Growth and Development Cognitive Skills and Economic Development

From Europe to the Euro Student Orientations 2013 Euro Challenge

Mark Scheme (Results) January GCE Government & Politics 6GP04 4A EU POLITICAL ISSUES

Migration Policy and Welfare State in Europe

REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY

EUROPEAN UNION CURRENCY/MONEY

Economic Voting Theory. Lidia Núñez CEVIPOL_Université Libre de Bruxelles

New Approaches to Measuring the Impacts of STI Policy

The European Union Economy, Brexit and the Resurgence of Economic Nationalism

How does education affect the economy?

The evolution of turnout in European elections from 1979 to 2009

The EU on the move: A Japanese view

Mika Widgrén The Impact of Council's Internal Decision-Making Rules on the Future EU. Aboa Centre for Economics

Transcription:

COVER SHEET EU institutional reform: Evidence on globalization and international cooperation Richard Baldwin (corresponding author) The Graduate Institute Cigale 2 1010 Lausanne Phone: 011 41 79 287 6708; Secretary 011 41 22 908 5959 Email: rbaldwin@cepr.org Session: Reform of Economic Institutions of the European Union, Jan. 5, 10:15 am Presiding: TIMOTHY BESLEY, London School of Economics Discussant: MARTIN FELDSTEIN, Harvard University 1

EU institutional reform: Evidence on globalization and international cooperation 9 January 2008. By Richard Baldwin * According to received wisdom, globalization fosters cooperation on economic governance at the international level since it hinders governments ability to govern unilaterally. This hypothesis is difficult to test. Most economic integration is slow and clear examples of international cooperation are rare. The EU, by contrast, has seen rapid and well defined economic integration since the mid-1980s accompanied by equally rapid and well defined reform of its economic institutions. If the received wisdom is right, the EU s rapid economic integration should have been associated with a transfer of economic policy sovereignty to the supranational level. This paper marshals several strands of evidence in support the received wisdom, although the relationship in the EU is clearly two-way. Economic integration makes governments more interested in international cooperation, but the institutional reforms that facilitate such cooperation also facilitate deeper economic integration. I. EU ECONOMIC INSTITUTIONS Much of the policy that governs economic activity in EU economies is made by supranational (SN) decision procedures. Just as U.S. States are bound by Acts of Congress that their Congressmen oppose, EU nations must implement EU legislation even if they oppose it. Not all policy areas are subject to SN procedures. In sensitive areas (e.g. taxation and international * GIG, 11a Ave de la Paix, 1202 Geneva Switzerland (email: rbaldwin@cepr.org). Thanks to Marty Feldstein s for comments that helped me clarify many issues, Thomas Koenig for advice and data, Mika Widgren for power calculations, and Dany Jaimovich for research assistance. 1

migration) members have a veto, so nations are only bound to what they agree. Such intergovernmental (IG) decision making is the standard form of international cooperation (e.g. the Kyoto Protocol). Discussion of how EU decision making has evolved requires some institutional background (see Richard Baldwin and Charles Wyplosz 2005 for details). Roughly speaking the lawmaking procedure follows the classic bicameral setup with the European Commission as the agendasetting executive, the Council of Ministers as the upper house and the European Parliament as the lower house. However, the Commission and Council are unelected. Commissioners are appointed by members, and each member sends a minister to represent its interests in the Council. The European Parliament (EP) is directly elected. Most EU lawmaking entails weighted voting called Qualified Majority Voting (QMV). Each Minister in the Council has a certain number of votes; populous nations have more votes, but much less than population proportionality would suggest. The Council s threshold for passage is about 70% of the votes. Member of European Parliament (MEP) have one vote each; populous nations have more MEPs but again fewer than strict proportionality would suggest. The EP s usual threshold is 50 percent. Since the Council s majority threshold is tighter, the EP s vote has little impact on national power. If MEPs voted on national lines, they would have little influence. Anything that attracted more than 70 percent of votes in the Council would easily pass the EP s threshold, so it is common to focus solely on the Council when it comes to national influence. All this concerns secondary law. Primary EU law is embodied in the Treaties, starting with the Treaty of Rome (ToR). Collectively, these act like a constitution, establishing institutions, decision-making procedures, and allocating power between the EU and its members. Primary law can only be changed by the adoption of a new Treaty, which requires unanimous approval of 2

all members and a majority vote by the EP. Four Treaties have been implemented over the past 25 years: the Single European Act (SEA), and the Maastricht, Amsterdam and Nice Treaties. The final key player is the EU Court. The Court s rulings are the supreme authority in the EU on areas in which the Court has jurisdiction (most SN economic policy issues). Court rulings can overturn any national law or national court ruling and they have the force of law in all member nations. They cannot be appealed. While logically necessary given the supranationality, such supremacy is certainly the most unusual aspect of EU economic governance. II. QUALITATIVE EVIDENCE No type of EU lawmaking is easy but unanimous decisions are especially difficult. For example, massive cross-border VAT fraud (acknowledged and studied for more than a decade) costs members billions every year, but since decisions must be unanimous, the Council has for years failed to agree technical remedies (e.g. centralizing information or obliging cooperation among national VAT authorities). Until 1987, most EU economic policy was made on an IG basis (unanimity in the Council). Little got done beyond maintenance of the customs union and the Common Agriculture Policy (CAP). One of the clearest signs of increased cooperation is found in the shifting of many policy areas from the IG basis (unanimity) to the SN basis (QMV). The biggest change came with the 1987 SEA. QMV became the decision rule for most issues pertaining to the Single Market (free movement of goods, services, workers and capital), thus switching an enormous swath of policy decisions form IG to SN. This shift is best thought of as an exogenous big-push initiative something like the EU s equivalent of the Thatcher-Reagan pro-market reforms of the 1980s. With the SEA in place, the integration-minded Commission (led by Jacques Delors) rapidly expanded the range of areas covered by SN procedures using its agenda-setting power and the 3

ToR s broad goals. Members reigned in this tendency by establishing three categories, or pillars, of policy in the 1992 Maastricht Treaty and explicitly limiting SN to first-pillar matters (basically the Single Market). In matters of defense and foreign policy (second pillar), and home and justice affairs (third pillar) decision making is IG. Members are reluctant to expand QMV to new areas but the rising importance of immigration, and transnational crime and terrorism has led to the switching to QMV in several areas previously considered matters of purely national concern. I take this as qualitative evidence that EU members have reacted to globalization by embracing deeper international cooperation. Specifically, the Treaties in 1997 and 2000 moved a number of areas to QMV. Additional qualitative evidence can be found in the EP s growing power. Initially, it had a merely consultative role with no power to block or amend. It has gained power in each of the last four EU Treaties and will gain even more if the Reform Treaty is ratified. While the justification was that this lessens the democratic deficit, it also reduces members ability to set economic policy unilaterally. Since each nation could have vetoed this, they all must have approved of this restriction on their national sovereignty in economic policy. The final bit of evidence is found in EU enlargement. Given the EU s economic size, nations on its fringes are unable to control economic policy unilaterally. Their own industries demand that national policies mimic EU laws to avoid the cost of two sets of rules. Nations such as Switzerland and Norway resisted joining but have instead signed agreements that oblige them to implement most EU laws in exchange for equal access to the EU market. They have, however, no formal input into the lawmaking process. Most nations in Europe looked at this regulation without representation and decided that they would have more control inside the EU despite 4

QMV. Enlargement, can thus be thought of as an indication that nations faced with deeply integrated markets feel they gain control from pooling their sovereignty on economic policy. III. A MODEL OF THE FLOW OF EU LEGISLATION The EU passes hundreds of legislative acts annually. This flow has gradually fallen over the past two decades and this might be taken as evidence against the received wisdom. This conclusion, however, overlooks the fact that the flow of laws is governed by the balance of decision-making costs and benefits. Since the received wisdom concerns only the benefits, I posit and estimate a model that distinguishes changes in decision-making costs and benefits. Decision-making costs in the sense of James M. Buchanan and Gordon Tullock (1962) vary enormously over different policies. Some laws are passed in a single day; others take years. Roughly speaking, policies that entail international redistribution are more contentious and thus have higher decision-making costs. What determines which laws are proposed and passed? I suggest that laws are passed up to the point where the marginal decision-making cost just equals the marginal benefit. The neoclassical supply and demand curves are the marginal cost and marginal benefit curve, respectively, so I think of this as a supply and demand model of EU lawmaking. The payoff to this insight is that the decision-making cost is also an indication of its marginal benefit just as the price in a competitive market is equal to both the marginal production cost and marginal benefit to consumers. While decision-making costs are impossible to measure directly, political scientists Thomas Koenig, Brooke Luetgert, and Tanja Dannwolf (2006) have gathered a rich dataset that includes the number of days between each law s formal proposal and its adoption. I take this as a proxy for the average decision-making cost. 5

Figure 1 shows the available data (1985 to 2002 aggregated annually) on the number of laws and the mean delay. The data shows a clear drop in the number of laws passed. Is the reduced flow due to an inward shift of demand (marginal benefit), or an inward shift of supply (marginal cost)? To answer this, I estimate a supply and demand model. Delay (days) 350 '01 '99 300 '98 '02 '97 250 '96 200 '00 '94 '91 '92 '89 150 '95 '93 '87 '90 100 '86 '85 '87 50 200 300 400 500 600 Number of laws FIGURE 1 SUPPLY AND DEMAND FOR EU LAWS The demand equation involves the delay (price) and demand-shifters. The received wisdom suggests that economic integration should shift out the demand for EU laws. My proxies for economic integration are dummy variables for the major pro-market Treaties (the SEA and the Maastricht Treaty). The supply curve is assumed to shift in response to the difficulty of decision making. Since laws tend to get more difficult to negotiate as the cumulative level of integration rises, I take a time trend as a simple proxy and use this as the supply-shifter in the first instance. The three-stage least squares estimation results are displayed in Table 1. The first two columns show the estimated demand and supply curves. As expected, the demand slope is negative and the supply slope is positive (although not statistically different from flat). The variables of interest the proxies for deeper integration turn out positive but 6

only the SEA is statistically significant. The supply shifter, as expected, is negative and significant indicating that the supply curve is gradually shifting to the northwest. TABLE 1 THREE STAGE LEAST SQUARE ESTIMATES OF THE SUPPLY AND DEMAND FOR EU LAWS Demand Supply Demand Supply Delay -1.05 0.13-0.32 0.48 (0.19)** (0.32) (0.14)** (0.33) SEA 85.1 40.7 (25.1)** (16.6)* Maastricht 34.0 (25.4) Trend -18.0-22.7 (3.7)** (4.1)** Overall Openness -9.4 (1.5)** R2 0.73 0.56 0.93 0.85 Notes: Standard errors in brackets. * and ** indicate significance at 5 and 1 percent. SEA is 1 from 1987 to 1992 and Maastricht is 1 from 1994 to 1999, otherwise 0. One standard measure of economic integration is overall trade openness as defined by the sum of imports and exports over GDP. When this is included as another demand shifter its influence 7

is estimated as negative. This suggests the intriguing possibility that overall openness dampens the demand for EU cooperation while EU specific measures, like SEA, increase the demand. Although these results require further exploration and an expansion of the data sample, they are broadly supportive of the idea that the equilibrium flow of EU laws balances the marginal benefit (demand) and marginal cost (supply) for laws with the delay acting as a proxy for the price. Assuming the Commission proposes laws up to the point where the marginal cost equals the marginal benefit, the delay is a proxy for the decision-making marginal benefit as well as the marginal decision-making cost. As such, the rising delay is consistent with the hypothesis that globalization has increased the value of cooperation. IV. SHIFTING POWER AND THE NATURE OF EU COOPERATION In the words of its founding Treaty, the EU is both a union of states and a union of peoples. This principle shows up in the allocation of votes in the Council. A pure union of states would allocate equal voting power per nation (as in the UN General Assembly). A pure union of citizens would allocate power among nations so as to yield equal voting power per person (as in a proportional-representation democracy). The actual EU power distribution is a blend. If the received-wisdom hypothesis is correct, globalization should have driven the EU toward the union of citizens pole as nations become less able to govern unilaterally. As Annick Laruelle and Mika Widgren (1998) show, game theory allows a formal analysis of the blend between the union of states versus citizens. Here the analysis is extended to consider the most recent institutional changes the Nice Treaty voting reforms, the subsequent enlargement to 25 then 27 members, and the proposed voting changes in the Reform Treaty. The pure equipotent-states power-distribution is obvious; each member should have the same power. The pure equipotent-citizens distribution is more complex but well understood among 8

voting theorist since Lionel Penrose (1946) first proved it; each nation should have a number of votes that is proportional to the square-root of its population (see Richard Baldwin, Erik Berglof, Francesco Giavazzi, and Widgren 2001 for the logic of this so-called Penrose rule). 16% 14% 12% 10% 8% Union of Citizens Actual Power distribution (1999) Union of States 6% 4% 2% 0% Germany UK France Italy Spain Netherlands Greece Belgium Portugal Sweden Austria Denmark Finland Ireland Luxembourg FIGURE 2: THE 2-UNION VIEW OF EU POWER DISTRIBUTION But how does one measure the actual power distribution? Cooperative game theory provides a measure called the normalized Banzhaf index (NBI) of power. Roughly, the NBI indicates how likely a nation is to find itself in a position to break a winning coalition on a randomly selected issue, assuming that nations yes-no positions are independently and identically distributed. Each member s NBI is calculated by working out all possible yes-no coalitions and using the QMV rules to identify the winning coalitions. Each winning coalition is then examined and the likelihood of each nation breaking a winning coalition is calculated and normalized so the NBIs add to unity. Deriving the NBI is calculation-intensive (there more than 1.3 million coalitions in the EU27) but straightforward. Note that Heikki Kauppi and Widgren 2004 demonstrate the 9

relevance of such power indices by showing that they are excellent predictors of one of the most easily measured outcomes of power, namely members shares of the EU budget. Figure 2 shows how the actual power distribution can be thought of as a weighted average of the two extremes, with least squares identifying the weighting. The actual and equipotent-citizen power distribution changed with each of the six enlargements. Table 2 shows the estimated weight on the union-of-citizens distribution for each configuration. The weight was near 80 percent for most of the EU s history, but moved sharply up with the 2004 enlargement. The driving force behind this change was the Nice Treaty voting reforms (first applied to the EU25), which shifted much power to large members. The justification for this reform was that decision making with so many small members would be unmanageable under the old rules which gave small and tiny members power shares far in excess of their population shares. The proposed Reform Treaty rules will shift even more power to big members, especially Germany. TABLE 2 EU POWER DISTRIBUTION AND UNION OF CITIZENS WEIGHTS Reform Treaty EU27 EU25 EU15 EU12 EU10 EU9 Weight on Union-of-Citizens 1.06 0.92 1.08 0.78 0.79 0.84 0.82 s.e. 0.05 0.04 0.05 0.04 0.04 0.05 0.04 R-square 0.94 0.96 0.95 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.98 Notes: Ordinary least square regression of square-root population shares on NBIs. The statistical results together with the qualitative discussion motivating the Nice and Reform Treaty voting reforms presents support for the notion that EU members have agreed to changes in their economic policy making institutions in order to maintain their ability to make SN 10

decisions. This of course does not directly confirm the received wisdom. No causality can be ascribed to the correlation between the shift toward the union-of-citizens power distribution and progressive integration, but the correlation is consistent with predictions of the received wisdom. V. CONCLUDING REMARKS This short paper argues that deep economic integration in Europe reduced the effectiveness of unilateral economic policy making and members reacted by embracing deeper international cooperation. The process, however, was two-way deeper lawmaking cooperation facilitated deeper economic integration and vice versa. The state of globalization in most parts of the world is decades behind the degree of economic integration among EU nations, but the negotiating agenda of global and non-european regional trade agreements are expanding and now go far beyond border measures such as tariffs and quotas. If this trend continues, nations are likely to find it increasing difficult to manage their economic policies in isolation. The attraction of international cooperation on issues such as product standards, investment rights, intellectual property rights, financial markets etc. will grow. While the EU is unique in many aspects, the institutional and political reaction of EU nations to economic integration provides lessons for the rest of the world. As global integration deepens, nations are likely to find their interests are best served by deepening international cooperation on economic policies. 11

References Baldwin, Richard, and Charles Wyplosz. 2005. The Economics of European Economic Integration. London: McGraw Hill. Baldwin, Richard, Erik Berglof, Francesco Giavazzi and Mika Widgren (2001). Nice Try Should the Treaty Be Ratified? London: CEPR. Buchanan, James M., and Gordon Tullock. 1962. The Calculus of Consent. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Kauppi, Heikki, and Mika Widgren. 2004. "What determines EU decision making? Needs, power or both?" Economic Policy, 19(39): 221-266. Koenig, Thomas, Brooke Luetgert, and Tanja Dannwolf. 2006. "Quantifying European Legislative Research: Using CELEX and PRELEX in EU Legislative Studies." European Union Politics, 7(4): 553-574. Laruelle, Annick, and Mika Widgren. 1998. Is the allocation of power among EU states fair? Public Choice, 94(3/4): 317-339. Penrose, Lionel. 1946. The Elementary Statistics of Majority Voting. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 109: 53-57. 12