The Root of the Matter: Voting in the EU Council. Wojciech Słomczyński Institute of Mathematics, Jagiellonian University, Kraków, Poland

Similar documents
Jagiellonian Compromise

PENROSE VOTING SYSTEM AND OPTIMAL QUOTA

In this lecture, we will explore weighted voting systems further. Examples of shortcuts to determining winning coalitions and critical players.

About the conference

Square root voting system, optimal treshold and π

Kybernetika. František Turnovec Fair majorities in proportional voting. Terms of use: Persistent URL:

State Population Square root Weight

The Impact of Turkey s Membership on EU Voting. Richard Baldwin and Mika Widgrén. Abstract

A Mathematical View on Voting and Power

Two-Tier Voting: Solving the Inverse Power Problem and Measuring Inequality

COVER SHEET. EU institutional reform: Evidence on globalization and international cooperation. Phone: ; Secretary

The composition of the European Parliament in 2019

Baseline study on EU New Member States Level of Integration and Engagement in EU Decision- Making

Invariably Suboptimal An attempt to improve the voting rules of Treaties of Nice and Lisbon

Lecture # 3 Economics of European Integration

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION

Turkey: Economic Reform and Accession to the European Union

Voting Power Implications of a Unified European Representation at the IMF

Fertility rate and employment rate: how do they interact to each other?

Degressive proportionality in the European Union

Size and Development of the Shadow Economy of 31 European and 5 other OECD Countries from 2003 to 2013: A Further Decline

For the Encyclopedia of Power, ed. by Keith Dowding (SAGE Publications) Nicholas R. Miller 3/28/07. Voting Power in the U.S.

IMMIGRATION, ASYLUM AND NATIONALITY ACT 2006 INFORMATION FOR CANDIDATES

On Bounds for Allocation of Seats in the European Parliament

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Proposal for a new repartition key

SECOND TIER CITY REGIONS IN EUROPE: WHAT POLICY MESSAGES FROM & FOR EUROPE?

COMMISSION IMPLEMENTING DECISION. of

On the Weights of Nations: Assigning Voting Weights in a Heterogeneous Union Salvador Barberà and Matthew O. Jackson

Annick Laruelle and Federico Valenciano: Voting and collective decision-making

Evolution of the European Union, the euro and the Eurozone Sovereign Debt Crisis

National Human Rights Institutions in the EU Member States Strengthening the fundamental rights architecture in the EU I

PARTIE III RAPPORTS NATIONAUX. établie par le Professeur Nigel Lowe, Faculté de droit de l Université de Cardiff * * *

Proposal for a COUNCIL DECISION

EUROPEAN COUNCIL Brussels, 18 June 2013 (OR. en)

IMMIGRATION, ASYLUM AND NATIONALITY ACT 2006 INFORMATION FOR CANDIDATES

Context Indicator 17: Population density

Limited THE EUROPEAN UNION, hereinafter referred to as the "Union" THE KINGDOM OF BELGIUM, THE REPUBLIC OF BULGARIA, THE CZECH REPUBLIC,

Who benefits from the US withdrawal of the Kyoto protocol?

Brexit. Alan V. Deardorff University of Michigan. For presentation at Adult Learning Institute April 11,

Thema Working Paper n Université de Cergy Pontoise, France

The distribution of power in the Council of the European Union

Letter prices in Europe. Up-to-date international letter price survey. March th edition

Explanatory Report to the European Convention on the Exercise of Children's Rights *

Ad-Hoc Query on the age limit for capacity to perform legal acts for the purpose of administrative expulsion and detention

FACULTY OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION. Master Thesis,,THE EUROPEAN UNION S ENLARGEMENT POLICY SINCE ITS CREATION CHAELLENGES AND ACHIEVEMENTS

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

IMF Governance and the Political Economy of a Consolidated European Seat

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

COMMISSION IMPLEMENTING DECISION. of

Improving the accuracy of outbound tourism statistics with mobile positioning data

COMMISSION IMPLEMENTING DECISION. of

All Party Parliamentary Group Art, Craft & Design Education

COMMISSION IMPLEMENTING DECISION. of establishing the list of supporting documents to be presented by visa applicants in Ireland

Welfarism and the assessment of social decision rules

EU Decision-making and the Allocation of Responsibility

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT, THE COUNCIL AND THE EUROPEAN ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL COMMITTEE

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT, THE EUROPEAN COUNCIL AND THE COUNCIL. Thirteenth report on relocation and resettlement

CO3.6: Percentage of immigrant children and their educational outcomes

This refers to the discretionary clause where a Member State decides to examine an application even if such examination is not its responsibility.

Civil and Political Rights

The United Kingdom in the European context top-line reflections from the European Social Survey

Special Eurobarometer 470. Summary. Corruption

Extended Findings. Finland. ecfr.eu/eucoalitionexplorer. Question 1: Most Contacted

WORLDWIDE DISTRIBUTION OF PRIVATE FINANCIAL ASSETS

The High Cost of Low Educational Performance. Eric A. Hanushek Ludger Woessmann

Taiwan s Development Strategy for the Next Phase. Dr. San, Gee Vice Chairman Taiwan External Trade Development Council Taiwan

UNDER EMBARGO UNTIL 9 APRIL 2018, 15:00 HOURS PARIS TIME

Income inequality and voter turnout

GDP per capita in purchasing power standards

Of the 73 MEPs elected on 22 May in Great Britain and Northern Ireland 30 (41 percent) are women.

International migration data as input for population projections

THE EUROPEAN UNIFIED PATENT SYSTEM:

Which electoral procedures seem appropriate for a multi-level polity?

Second Tier Cities in Age of Austerity: Why Invest Beyond the Capitals?

Index for the comparison of the efficiency of 42 European judicial systems, with data taken from the World Bank and Cepej reports.

Annexations and alliances : when are blocs advantageous a priori? Dan S. Felsenthal and Moshé Machover

8193/11 GL/mkl 1 DG C I

THE DRAFT CONSTITUTIONAL TREATY S VOTING REFORM DILEMMA

NOTE from : Governing Board of the European Police College Article 36 Committee/COREPER/Council Subject : CEPOL annual work programme for 2002

Gender pay gap in public services: an initial report

EUROPEAN UNION CURRENCY/MONEY

A New Method of the Single Transferable Vote and its Axiomatic Justification

Electoral rights of EU citizens

Reference Title Dates Organiser(s) 00/2007 Train the Trainers Learning Seminar Step February 2007 Portugal 01/2007 Crime, Police and Justice in

EU Settlement Scheme Briefing information. Autumn 2018

The Mathematics of Apportionment

2. The table in the Annex outlines the declarations received by the General Secretariat of the Council and their status to date.

Factual summary Online public consultation on "Modernising and Simplifying the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP)"

ASSOCIATION OF EUROPEAN JOURNALISTS (AEJ)

Economics Level 2 Unit Plan Version: 26 June 2009

Institutions of the European Union and the ECHR - An Overview -

EUROPEAN UNION CITIZENSHIP

Decision Making in Europe: Were Spain and Poland Right to Stop the Constitution in December 2003? 1

COMMISSION IMPLEMENTING DECISION. of

The evolution of turnout in European elections from 1979 to 2009

Transcription:

The Root of the Matter: Voting in the EU Council by Wojciech Słomczyński Institute of Mathematics, Jagiellonian University, Kraków, Poland Tomasz Zastawniak Department of Mathematics, University of York, UK Karol Życzkowski Institute of Physics, Jagiellonian University, Kraków, Poland Centre for Theoretical Physics, Polish Academy of Sciences, Warsaw, Poland The distribution of votes in the Council of Ministers of the European Union was a major obstacle during the negotiations of the Treaty Establishing the Constitution for Europe, and remains one of the factors hindering the current process of ratification of the Constitution. In 1952 the British psychiatrist and mathematician Lionel Sharples Penrose (father of the eminent British scientists: mathematician Sir Roger, and physicist Oliver) made a prophetic statement predicting the flaws that are now inherent in the EU Constitution: [ ] if two votings were required for every decision, one on a per capita basis and the other upon the basis of a single vote for each country, the system would be inaccurate in that it would tend to favour large countries [ ] The mathematical theory of voting put forward by Lionel Penrose in the mid 1940 s, combined with proposals arising from research carried out by the authors at the Jagiellonian University in Kraków in 2004, bring about an unexpectedly simple and effective solution to the problem of voting in the EU Council. The enlargement of the EU to 25 (and in the not too distant future 27) countries makes it necessary to adopt new voting rules in the Council of Ministers. The provisions differ considerably between the Treaty of Nice, currently in force, and the Treaty Establishing a Constitution for Europe, signed in Rome in October 2004, pending ratification. Pursuant to the Treaty of Nice, the voting weights of individual member states in the Council of Ministers reflect to a certain degree the population of each state. The Council adopts a piece of legislation if: the sum of the weights of the member states voting in favour exceeds 232 (approximately 72% of the total weight of all 25 member states); the member states constituting a qualified majority represent at least 62% of the total population of the Union; a majority of member states (at least 13 out of 25) vote in favour of the motion. According to the Treaty Establishing a Constitution for Europe, a resolution would be adopted by the Council of Ministers subject the following criteria: at least 55% of member states, comprising at least 15 of them, vote in favour; the member states voting in favour comprise at least 65% of the total population of the Union;

additionally, a blocking minority must include at least four Council members, failing which a qualified majority shall be deemed attained. The main deficiency of the Nice system is that it proves extremely difficult to form a winning coalition and to pass any new legislation efficiently. The Nice system is complicated by the fact that three diverse criteria need to be applied simultaneously in the calculation of qualified majority. In addition, as we shall see, it assigns too much power to certain countries, while others obtain less power than appropriate. Meanwhile, the European Constitution assigns too much power to the largest and the smallest states, while middle-sized countries do not receive their due share of influence. Is it possible to construct a two-tier voting system free of these deficiencies, in which each citizen of each member state would have the same voting power? Can it be done in a way that is transparent, easy to implement, efficient to use, and will readily accommodate any future extensions of the Union? A partial answer to this question can be found in Penrose s work, who deliberated in 1946 on the principles of an ideal representative voting system (in the context of a hypothetical distribution of votes in the UN General Assembly). First consider direct elections of the Government of a member state with population size N. The average citizen of a large member state, such as Germany, has less influence on the election of the Government of his or her country than, for example, a citizen of the much smaller Luxembourg. Penrose established that in such elections the voting power of a single citizen is proportional to 1 / N, given that votes are uncorrelated. The elected Government then nominates the Minister to vote on behalf of the country in the European Council. It follows that the system of indirect voting applied to the European Council would be representative, giving each citizen of each EU state the same influence on the decisions of the Council, if the voting power of each country were proportional to N, cancelling out the factor 1 / N. This principle of distribution of voting power in a wider context of a two-tier voting system is known as the square root law of Penrose. There exists a close analogy in physics: the mean square distance travelled by a diffusing particle is proportional to the square root of time. From the mathematical viewpoint the square root laws concerned with voting power and diffusion follow very similar reasoning. Note that Penrose s law can, if desired, be stated without explicit reference to the square root. It is sufficient to stipulate that the voting weight of each member state should be equal to the side of a square with area equal to its population. A voting system in the EU Council of Ministers that obeys Penrose s square root law was first proposed in 1998 by Annick Laruelle from the Université Catholique de Louvain, Belgium and Mika Widgrén from the Turku School of Economics and Business Administration, Finland. Since then such voting systems have been endorsed by scientists from the Czech Republic, France, Germany, Israel, Norway, Poland, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom. The Penrose law provides a theoretical solution to the question of how to allocate voting power to member states. However, until recently it had remained unclear in general how to attribute voting weights and how to define qualified majority decision rules in order to obtain the desired distribution of voting power.

In this connection, it is important to make a clear distinction between the voting weight of a given member state and their voting power. The two quantities do not have to be proportional. In a hypothetical Union of two states, with voting weights 51% and 49% operating under a simple majority decision rule, the country with the higher voting weight would be able win every vote, taking 100% of the voting power. Between 1958 and 1973, despite a relatively high voting weight assigned to Luxemburg as compared to its population, it was in fact impossible for this country exercise any a priori voting power in the European Economic Community Council. The configuration of the voting weights of the remaining member states was such that Luxemburg was unable to influence the outcome of any ballot, irrespective of the vote cast by their representative. A country can only exercise power whenever their vote cast in a ballot proves decisive: should this country decide to change its vote, the winning coalition would fail to satisfy the qualified majority condition. Voting power can be understood as the ratio of the number of coalitions in which the vote of a given country is decisive to the number of all possible coalitions in which it takes part. This is known as the Banzhaf index, after John F. Banzhaf III, the well-known American lawyer and practitioner of public interest law, who introduced this ratio as a measure of voting power independently of Penrose in 1965. In the EU consisting of 25 states there are more than 33.5 million of possible coalitions. When two more states join the Union in the near future, this number will increase to over 134 million. Given the voting weight of each state and the qualified majority rules, it is then possible to compute the number of coalitions in which the vote of a given state proves decisive, and to work out the voting power of that state as measured by the Banzhaf index. In early 2004 two of the current authors proposed a voting system based on the following criterion: the voting weight of each member state should be allocated proportionally to the square root of its population, with decisions passed by the Council if the sum of weights exceeds a certain quota, namely 62% for the EU of 25 countries and 61.4% for 27 countries. This particular choice of the quota would ensure that the voting power of each country is practically equal to the voting weight and, as a result, proportional to the square root of the population. The Penrose law would then be fulfilled almost exactly, and the potential influence of every citizen of each member state on the decisions taken by the Council would be very nearly the same, irrespective of the size of the state. Such a voting system would not only be representative, but also transparent: the voting powers of member states would become proportional to the voting weights, and only a single criterion would be needed for the calculation of qualified majority. Moreover, any further enlargement of the Union would involve a one-off recalculation of a single quantity, the quota used in the qualified majority rule. This proposed voting system stimulated considerable interest among experts in voting theory. It has since been christened by the media as the Jagiellonian Compromise, with overtones referring to the Jagiellonian University in Kraków, where the research was carried out, and to the Jagiellonian dynasty, who reigned over vast parts of Central Europe during the Renaissance period. Prior to the June 2004 EU Summit in Brussels, an open letter in support of square root voting weights in the EU Council endorsed by eminent European scientists,

predominantly mathematicians and physicists, was sent to the Governments of EU member countries and EU institutions. Figure 1 illustrates the effects of the provisions of the European Constitution, the Jagiellonian Compromise and the Treaty of Nice on the voting power of individual citizens of six representative EU member states with widely differing population sizes: Germany (82.5 million citizens), the United Kingdom (59.3 million), Poland (38.2 million), the Netherlands (16.2 million), the Czech Republic (10.2 million) and Lithuania (3.5 million). It shows that voting power is very unequally distributed among the citizens of different countries under the Treaty of Nice as well as under the European Constitution. As predicted by Penrose, the citizens of Germany, with its large population, would gain considerable additional voting power if the Constitution were to be adopted. What is the reaction by politicians? The Jagiellonian Compromise has been endorsed by number of leading politicians in Poland as part of their agenda. The former Irish Prime Minister John Burton has made numerous positive references to the voting system based on the square root law. A recent article by David Reid in Physics World referring to the Jagiellonian Compromise was quoted and the voting system scrutinised in the House of Commons Library Research Paper No 04/75. When a similar system was put forward by Swedish diplomacy in 2000, the Swedish Prime Minister Göran Persson commented: Our formula has the advantage of being easy to understand by public opinion and practical to use in an enlarged Europe it is transparent, logical and loyal. Maybe that is why it does not please everybody. If, as is now increasingly likely, the Constitution for Europe will fail to come into force, the question of the voting system in the EU Council of Ministers will need to be revisited. If a solution is sought based on rational principles to ensure equal distribution of voting power among all citizens of European Union countries, then the principles underlying Penrose s square root law and the Jagiellonian Compromise may be able to inform future discussions and negotiations. relative voting power of a citizen 1.60 1.40 1.20 1.00 0.80 0.60 0.40 0.20 0.00 Germany United Kingdom Poland Netherlands Czech Rep. Lithuania member states European Constitution Jagiellonian Compromise Treaty of Nice Fig. 1. Voting power of a citizen of the United Kingdom, Poland, the Netherlands, the Czech Republic and Lithuania under the European Constitution, the Jagiellonian Compromise and the Treaty of Nice relative to the voting power of a citizen of Germany.

Further reading J F Banzhaf 1965 Weighted voting does not work: A mathematical analysis Rutgers Law Rev. 19 317-343 D S Felsenthal and M Machover 1998 Measurement of Voting Power: Theory and Practice, Problems and Paradoxes (Cheltenham, Edward Elgar) D S Felsenthal and M Machover 2004 A priori voting power: What is it all about? Polit. Stud. Rev. 2 1-23 A Laruelle and M Widgrén 1998 Is the allocation of power among EU states fair? Public Choice 94 317-339 L S Penrose 1946 The elementary statistics of majority voting J. Roy. Stat. Soc. 109 53-57 L S Penrose 1952 On the Objective Study of Crowd Behaviour (London, H. K. Lewis & Co) K Życzkowski and W Słomczyński 2004 Voting in the European Union: The Square Root System of Penrose and the Critical Point. arxiv.org e-print archive cond-mat.0405396. http://xxx.lanl.gov/ftp/cond-mat/papers/0405/0405396.pdf