and Ferrie maintain in this sprightly institutionalist history, was the prerequisite for the rise of

Similar documents
The Effects on U.S. Farm Workers of an Agricultural Guest Worker Program

Reconstruction

SAC: Was the New Deal Effective?

Reconstruction Change in the South: Chapter 14, Section 4

Chapter 18 Reconstruction pg Rebuilding the Union pg One American s Story

Chapter 16 - Reconstruction

Panel 1, Migration of the Negro Casein Tempera On Hardboard 18 x 12

Chapter 17 - Reconstruction

Chapter Section 25 Section 1. Chapter 21 Section 2. Americans Face Hard Times

Creating America (Survey)

bk12c - The Reconstruction Era ( )

SS8H8 Georgia Between the Wars

The Economic and Political Effects of Black Outmigration from the US South. October, 2017

Reconstruction ( )

Essential Question: What were the various plans to bring Southern states back into the Union and to protect newly-emancipated slaves?

THE RECONSTRUCTION ERA

The Politics of Reconstruction

The Era of Reconstruction

Social Studies Content Expectations

Mexican Migrant Workers in the 20th Century By Jessica McBirney 2016

Policymaking Process: A Primary Source Case Study

The Roaring 20s in the United States & South Carolina & 8-6.3

Chapter Section 25 Section 1. Terms and People

Georgia: After WWI and the Great Depression

Reconstruction of The South, Part 2

Chapter 12: Reconstruction ( )

Unit 8 Review Standard Indicators Which amendments did SC refuse to ratify? 2. What did these two amendments guarantee?

SLIDE 1 Chapter 13: Reconstruction of Georgia and the South

CHAPTER 15 - RECONSTRUCTION. APUSH Mr. Muller

Government agency to help former slaves and poor whites. Many former northern abolitionists risked their lives to help southern freedmen.

The War s Aftermath. Chapter 12, Section 1

Goal 1. Analyze the political, economic, and social impact of Reconstruction on the nation and identify the reasons why Reconstruction came to an end.

Structured Academic Controversy: FDR s New Deal

SS8H SS8E1

SSUSH17 The student will analyze the causes and consequences of the Great Depression.

Chapter 12. Reconstruction

Reconstruction Practice Test

Chapter 7 5/7/09. Problem 7. Social Inequality. The Cultural Construction of Social Hierarchy

History 1301 U.S. to Reconstruction

Key Questions. 2. How do we rebuild the South economically after its destruction during the war?

SOCIAL STUDIES GRADE 10 AMERICAN HISTORY. I Can Checklist Office of Teaching and Learning Curriculum Division

Related Thematic Learning Objectives. Concept Outline

Georgia Studies. Unit 6: Early 20 th Century Georgia. Lesson 1: The Great Depression. Study Presentation

Period 1: Period 2:

APUSH RECONSTRUCTION REVIEWED!

NEW DEAL APUSH GREAT DEPRESSION &

Reconstruction and Its Effects

The New Deal. President Franklin Delano Roosevelt sitting in the Oval Office.

Imperialism by the US

LABOUR BROKERAGE ON FRUIT FARMS THE PORTFOLIO COMMITTEE ON LABOUR TUESDAY 18 TH AUGUST 2009

Chapter 17 Reconstruction and the New South ( ) Section 2 Radicals in Control

Topics / The Great Migration, / Great Migration / Great Migration (Overview)

The Americans (Reconstruction to the 21st Century)

Risk Management Strategies Concerning Seasonal Farmworkers 1

1. An intense devotion/loyalty to one s own ethnic group. 2. Alliance made up of Germany, Austria-Hungary, and the Empire

4. Which of the following was NOT a. B. The protection of the civil rights of. C. The imposition of military rule upon the

AP U.S. History Essay Questions, 1994-present. Document-Based Questions

COMPREHENSION AND CRITICAL THINKING

PART IV RED SCARE POLITICS IN GEORGIA

Causes of the Great Depression

TEKS 8C: Calculate percent composition and empirical and molecular formulas. Causes of the Great Depression

Uzbek Cotton Chronicle, Issue 1 December, 2010.

Dublin City Schools Social Studies Graded Course of Study American History

Transcript for The Great Black Migration and Competition in Northern Labor Markets

Period 4 Content Outline,

Document A: Fireside Chat (Modified)

SSUSH21A, B & C Domestic Policies of Truman and Eisenhower

POLI 12D: International Relations Sections 1, 6

Name Date The period after the Civil War was called Reconstruction. It changes our government and the Constitution. Three

Networks and Mobility

The End of the War, Outcomes, and Reconstruction

INDUSTRY AND MIGRATION/THE NORTH AND THE SOUTH. pp

Prentice Hall US History: Reconstruction to the Present 2010 Correlated to: Minnesota Academic Standards in History and Social Studies, (Grades 9-12)

9 US History Student Name: Unit 3: Reconstruction. Unit Questions. (Prepare to answer these questions for unit exam) Thought Jots

HOOVER RESPONDS TO THE DEPRESSION. Chapter 11 Section 3

Do Migrant Remittances Lead to Inequality? 1

Chapter 1: Objectives

Understanding institutions

Reconstruction. How can Northern resources help the South? In what ways can the South rebuild its economy?

Immigration & Farm Labor 2017

PERIOD 6: This era corresponds to information in Unit 10 ( ) and Unit 11 ( )

Chapter Introduction. Section 1: Causes of the Depression Section 2: Americans Face Hard Times Section 3: Hoover s Response Fails

Name: Unit 7 Interactive Vocab: The Great Depression, FDR, and the New Deal

I. The Agricultural Revolution

Middle Level Grades 7 & 8 Sample Informative Stimulus-Based Prompt

Sherman s March. Feel the hard hand of war Burned houses, farms, pillaged food and resources Attacked hostile civilians as well.

Roosevelt's New Deal. Mr. Venezia. Roosevelt's New Deal 1

Reconstruction Chapter 4. Results of Civil War (1865) Questions still unanswered (Left up to victorious North)

History 1301 U.S. to 1877

Farm Worker Organizing Collection, No online items

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY

Vote Buying and Clientelism

RESEARCH REPORT ON MIGRANT WORKERS IN HIGH-RISK INDUSTRY

Chapter 15 Vocab. The New Deal

A) Following the Civil War, government subsidies for transportation and communication systems helped open new markets in North America.

Reconstruction: The 2 nd Civil War

The Politics of Reconstruction

S apt ect er ion 25 1 Section 1 Terms and People Reconstruction Radical Republican Wade-Davis Bill Riv l for Reconstruction

Unit 9 Industrial Revolution

Key Concept 6.2: Examples: Examples:

Transcription:

Southern Paternalism and the American Welfare State: Economics, Politics, and Institutions in the South, 1865-1965. By Lee J. Alston and Joseph P. Ferrie. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999. Pp. xii, 170. $? The decline of a private system of social welfare on southern cotton plantations, Alston and Ferrie maintain in this sprightly institutionalist history, was the prerequisite for the rise of the national welfare state in the United States. Three conditions, they argue, supported southern paternalism. First, white and especially black tenant farmers and sharecroppers needed wellconnected patrons to protect them from antipathetic laws and adverse economic and social norms -- laws and norms fostered and enforced by the privileged class from which patrons could be drawn. Second, plantation owners had an incentive to provide their workers with protection and to facilitate loans to them in order to reduce labor turnover and the monitoring costs of a decentralized production process. Paternalism bought loyalty and hard work. Third, owners opposed any extension of national welfare benefits to southern farm workers because such laws might interfere with patron-client relationships or even substitute a governmental for a private patron. Fortunately for them, the South s one-party politics and the House and Senate norms designating the most senior members as powerful committee chairmen gave white southerners effective veto power over national social welfare legislation. The combination of these three factors allowed the paternalistic equilibrium to be maintained for a century after the Civil War. Only when an exogenous technological change, the perfection of the cotton picking machine, disrupted the equilibrium in the 1960s could the American welfare state mature. Plantations no longer needed workers with farm-specific skills, and they required far fewer total workers. With nothing to gain from paternalism any more, planters could transfer the costs 1

to the public. The plantation elite and its political minions in Congress therefore finally allowed comprehensive welfare bills to pass. Offering a tidy explanation for puzzling and significant regional and national trends, integrating politics knowledgeably and seamlessly into an essentially economic analysis, interpreting paternalism as an economically rational bargain, rather than a misty ideologicalcultural construct, and avoiding mathematicized theory and statistical estimations, this short, provocative book should fit well into courses in economic history and American political development, and it deserves the attention of non-academic readers interested in American history. But its omissions make its arguments less than wholly persuasive. Slavery was the prototype of a dependency relationship. Reconstruction was the most violent period of southern history between 1865 and the present. Labor arrangements were more in flux and more new areas were settled in the South in the 1860s, 70s, and 80s than at any time thereafter. The social habits of hierarchical relationships ought to have been most familiar during these decades, and if Alston and Ferrie s model is correct, both workers demands for paternalism and owners desires to supply it ought to have peaked then. One would therefore expect the focus of a book about post-emancipation paternalism to be on this period. Yet Alston and Ferrie barely discuss it. Instead, more than three-quarters of the book is devoted to the years between 1933 and 1965. Although they never spell out their rationale, they apparently believe that because systematic direct evidence about southern paternalism is so difficult to obtain, the best way to illuminate the nature of paternalism is to look at events that can be interpreted as opposition to attempts to replace it. Thus, their three central chapters concern southern congressional opposition to covering 2

farm workers under the Social Security Act in the 1930s and to the increasingly radical Farm Security Administration in the 1930s and early 40s, and southern delegations support for the bracero program to bring in largely Mexican farm workers on a temporary and highly regulated basis from 1942 through 1964. In each case, they draw almost entirely on secondary sources, rather than gathering and analyzing original data themselves, and the chief alternative hypotheses that they confront are the contentions that southern legislative behavior was the product of a conservative mentality or pure racism, or that it was aimed merely at keeping southern farm workers wages low, rather than representing a desire to preserve private paternalism unfettered. They are surely correct in rejecting the idea that the South was consistently devoted to principles of conservatism or laissez faire. Federal farm loans, demonstration projects, crop price supports, acreage restrictions, flood control, electric power, and a host of other programs, including almost all of those of the early New Deal, received enthusiastic support from nearly all southern whites. (The opinions of the largely disfranchised southern blacks didn t count before the 1940s and are therefore difficult to gauge.) And because excluding agricultural workers from unemployment, old age, and mothers pensions affected more white than black workers, pure racism seems inadequate as an explanation. But when Alston and Ferrie (p. 59) partially reject the low wages argument on the grounds that owners were already providing old age and unemployment benefits, the difficulty with their general indirect strategy becomes clear: They do not know indeed, probably no one knows how general, comprehensive, and generous paternalism was. If the benefits were offered by only a small proportion of farmers or by all farmers to only a small proportion of workers, or if whoever they were offered by or to, they 3

were miserly, then the low wages argument is not so weak after all, and perhaps we do not need the complications of side benefits. It also seems unsatisfying that the authors mention but never analyze the congressional actions of 1950, 1954, and 1956 that brought farm workers under Social Security, all of which took place before the widespread adoption of the cotton picking machine. Why did these facets of paternalism cease to be worth protecting just then, if that was what the members of Congress were doing? The Farm Security Administration, which succeeded the early New Deal Resettlement Administration in 1937, fits Alston and Ferrie s case better. Besides helping small farm owners, the RA and the FSA provided loans to distressed tenants, set up cooperatives, and often sought better, more standard terms in tenant contracts. Such programs did not directly increase wages, but they did threaten the traditional landlord-tenant and merchant-tenant relationships. As the FSA expanded the original RA programs, southern planters and their congressional representatives increasingly protested, until in 1943, they managed to slash the most threatening programs dramatically. Alston and Ferrie point out a strange fact about the bracero program -- that support for it was higher from southern members of Congress than from those of any other region, despite the fact that only two southern states, Arkansas and Texas, received any appreciable number of bracero workers and offer their paternalism thesis to account for the anomaly. Wartime restrictions on the geographic mobility of agricultural workers and local boards ability to defer farm workers from the military draft as essential for the economy helped keep southern farm labor in surplus and wages low. The bracero program, which continued long after World War II and the Korean War, had the same effect because it expanded the national supply of agricultural 4

labor. There are two difficulties with the paternalism solution to the anomalous pattern of southern support for the bracero program: First, braceros were essentially employed in the Southwest, Michigan, and California to pick crops. Would tenants and sharecroppers in great numbers have joined the migrant stream if the formal bracero program had not existed, but if some portion of the demand for pickers had been satisfied by undocumented immigrant workers? It is not clear that the human capital built up during relatively sedentary tenantry would have transferred well to picking fruits and vegetables, or that trading a sharecropper s shack for a migrant labor camp was a good bargain. Second, even assuming that they would have become migrants or that southern farm proprietors would have feared that they would, a desire on the part of those proprietors to keep workers wages low is just as satisfactory an explanation as the more complicated paternalism thesis. Perhaps the boldest claim in this book is that it was a shift in the attitudes and behavior of the plantation elite, not the reenfranchisement of southern blacks or the increasing political potency of northern black and white liberals, that led to the full-blown national welfare state, which Alston and Ferrie associate with Lyndon Johnson s Great Society programs (120). While it is true, as they emphasize, that southerners did retain considerable power in congressional committees through the end of the sixties, their constituencies were changing and becoming more complicated, and they were by no means as responsive to cotton plantation owners as they had been earlier. The combination of the boll weevil, the agricultural depression of the 20s and 30s, and New Deal agricultural programs diversified the region s agriculture. Even before the passage of the Voting Rights Act in 1965, nearly 40 percent of African- 5

American adults were registered to vote in the South. Urbanization, suburbanization, cracks in one-party control, and anticipations of political upheaval to come also helped to change politicians strategies. Mechanization was important, and Alston and Ferrie s discussion of it is nuanced and provocative. But even assuming that the pre-1960 expansion of the welfare state can be largely ignored, it will take more evidence, including direct evidence from the mouths or papers of members of Congress, to establish mechanization as the sole or chief cause of southern political change that allowed the expansion of governmentally-provided welfare. Alston and Ferrie s explicit development of an economic model of paternalism suggests questions that more casual discussions do not raise. How would one test the degree to which paternalism was an economic, rather than a cultural or social phenomenon? How did it vary from place to place and time to time, and were those variations the product, as their model implies, of differences in the levels of prosperity, violence, public service provision, and bias in private institutions, such as those that granted credit? How did southern states differ in the importance of paternalism in their social and economic structures, and how did its importance change? How mobile was southern agricultural labor, and how did that mobility shift from area to area and change over time? Would many tenants stay on one plantation long enough to take advantage of old age and medical care benefits, and could owners expect them to? Was there any connection between plantation paternalism and the welfare capitalism of early 20 th century textile mills and other enterprises faced with high quit rates? Since other agricultural proprietors, such as California corporations that employed largely migrant labor under decidedly non-paternalistic conditions, also virulently opposed governmental interference in agricultural labor relations, except to regularize their exploitation of workers, was paternalism necessary to 6

explain southern opposition to analogous state measures? Alston and Ferrie s stimulating book deserves study and questioning. J. Morgan Kousser California Institute of Technology. 7