Majority cycles in national elections

Similar documents
VISA POLICY OF THE REPUBLIC OF KAZAKHSTAN

PISA 2015 in Hong Kong Result Release Figures and Appendices Accompanying Press Release

Equity and Excellence in Education from International Perspectives

SKILLS, MOBILITY, AND GROWTH

PISA 2009 in Hong Kong Result Release Figures and tables accompanying press release article

Rankings: Universities vs. National Higher Education Systems. Benoit Millot

Migration and Integration

GLOBAL RISKS OF CONCERN TO BUSINESS WEF EXECUTIVE OPINION SURVEY RESULTS SEPTEMBER 2017

Electoral Engineering & Turnout

WORLDWIDE DISTRIBUTION OF PRIVATE FINANCIAL ASSETS

Contributions to UNHCR For Budget Year 2014 As at 31 December 2014

OECD Strategic Education Governance A perspective for Scotland. Claire Shewbridge 25 October 2017 Edinburgh

QGIS.org - Donations and Sponsorship Analysis 2016

Children, Adolescents, Youth and Migration: Access to Education and the Challenge of Social Cohesion

APPENDIX 1: MEASURES OF CAPITALISM AND POLITICAL FREEDOM

Individualized education in Finland

Translation from Norwegian

A GAtewAy to A Bet ter Life Education aspirations around the World September 2013

BRAND. Cross-national evidence on the relationship between education and attitudes towards immigrants: Past initiatives and.

The evolution of turnout in European elections from 1979 to 2009

Trump, Condorcet and Borda: Voting paradoxes in the 2016 Republican presidential primaries

Employment in the tourism industries from the perspective of the ILO. Valeria Nesterenko, International Labour Organisation

2016 Europe Travel Trends Report

HUMAN RESOURCES IN R&D

The Future of Central Bank Cooperation

Management Systems: Paulo Sampaio - University of Minho. Pedro Saraiva - University of Coimbra PORTUGAL

Global Consumer Confidence

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

The global and regional policy context: Implications for Cyprus

Human Resources in R&D

Cambridge International Examinations Cambridge International Advanced Subsidiary and Advanced Level

Education Quality and Economic Development

Dashboard. Jun 1, May 30, 2011 Comparing to: Site. 79,209 Visits % Bounce Rate. 231,275 Pageviews. 00:03:20 Avg.

Annex 1. Technical notes for the demographic and epidemiological profile

Round 1. This House would ban the use of zero-hour contracts. Proposition v. Opposition

The Multidimensional Financial Inclusion MIFI 1

CO3.6: Percentage of immigrant children and their educational outcomes

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 412 persons in December 2017, and 166 of these were convicted offenders.

List of countries whose citizens are exempted from the visa requirement

Student Background and Low Performance

PISA 2006 PERFORMANCE OF ESTONIA. Introduction. Imbi Henno, Maie Kitsing

How do the performance and well-being of students with an immigrant background compare across countries? PISA in Focus #82

Overview of JODI Gas Milestones and Beta Test Launch

ISSUE BRIEF: U.S. Immigration Priorities in a Global Context

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads

On aid orphans and darlings (Aid Effectiveness in aid allocation by respective donor type)

The political economy of electricity market liberalization: a cross-country approach

The Extraordinary Extent of Cultural Consumption in Iceland

THE VENICE COMMISSION OF THE COUNCIL OF EUROPE

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

2010/SOM1/EC/WKSP/004 Session 1. Starting a Business. Submitted by: World Bank

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Emerging Asian economies lead Global Pay Gap rankings

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 429 persons in January 2018, and 137 of these were convicted offenders.

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) returned 444 persons in August 2018, and 154 of these were convicted offenders.

South Africa - A publisher s perspective. STM/PASA conference 11 June, 2012, Cape Town Mayur Amin, SVP Research & Academic Relations

A Partial Solution. To the Fundamental Problem of Causal Inference

9 th International Workshop Budapest

Countries for which a visa is required to enter Colombia

New York County Lawyers Association Continuing Legal Education Institute 14 Vesey Street, New York, N.Y (212)

BULGARIAN TRADE WITH EU IN JANUARY 2017 (PRELIMINARY DATA)

WSDC 2010: THE DRAW ROUND ZERO. PROPOSITION versus OPPOSITION NIGERIA CYPRUS CROATIA BULGARIA LEBANON PALESTINE BOSNIA AND HERZEGOVINA RUSSIA

UNIDEM CAMPUS FOR THE SOUTHERN MEDITERRANEAN COUNTRIES

BULGARIAN TRADE WITH EU IN THE PERIOD JANUARY - MARCH 2016 (PRELIMINARY DATA)

Stimulating Investment in the Western Balkans. Ellen Goldstein World Bank Country Director for Southeast Europe

VOICE OF THE PEOPLE GOVERNMENT INDEX*

VOICE AND DATA INTERNATIONAL

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 375 persons in March 2018, and 136 of these were convicted offenders.

The High Cost of Low Educational Performance. Eric A. Hanushek Ludger Woessmann

EuCham Charts. October Youth unemployment rates in Europe. Rank Country Unemployment rate (%)

Consumer Barometer Study 2017

Improving the accuracy of outbound tourism statistics with mobile positioning data

Copyright Act - Subsidiary Legislation CHAPTER 311 COPYRIGHT ACT. SUBSIDIARY LEGlSLA non. List o/subsidiary Legislation

On the Future of Criminal Offender DNA Databases

Global Access Numbers. Global Access Numbers

Analyzing the Location of the Romanian Foreign Ministry in the Social Network of Foreign Ministries

Trafficking in Persons

Italy Luxembourg Morocco Netherlands Norway Poland Portugal Romania

Doing Business in East Asia and the Pacific

The Future of ER as an Academic Field

Asia Pacific (19) EMEA (89) Americas (31) Nov

1. Why do third-country audit entities have to register with authorities in Member States?

BIPM Perspectives. Dr Martin Milton. 13 th 14 th October BIPM Director

NATIONAL INTEGRITY SYSTEM ASSESSMENT ROMANIA. Atlantic Ocean. North Sea. Mediterranean Sea. Baltic Sea.

The Conference Board Total Economy Database Summary Tables November 2016

Data on gender pay gap by education level collected by UNECE

Polimetrics. Mass & Expert Surveys

Global Trends in Location Selection Final results for 2005

Delays in the registration process may mean that the real figure is higher.

PISA DATA ON STUDENTS WITH AN IMMIGRANT BACKGROUND. Mario Piacentini

Q233 Grace Period for Patents

The Madrid System. Overview and Trends. Mexico March 23-24, David Muls Senior Director Madrid Registry

Country pairings for the second cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

International Egg Market Annual Review

KINGDOM OF CAMBODIA NATION RELIGION KING 3 TOURISM STATISTICS REPORT. September 2010

TRIPS OF BULGARIAN RESIDENTS ABROAD AND ARRIVALS OF VISITORS FROM ABROAD TO BULGARIA IN AUGUST 2015

PC-related conditions and mechanisms for care coordination in Europe

TRIPS OF BULGARIAN RESIDENTS ABROAD AND ARRIVALS OF VISITORS FROM ABROAD TO BULGARIA IN AUGUST 2016

Transcription:

Majority cycles in national elections Bodo Knoll, Joan Serra 1 University of Bochum Abstract This paper provides information on cycle probabilities for 147 national elections and tests if a high level of political information reduces the empirical probability of Condorcet cycles. We construct preference ratings for parties and party leaders from the Comparative Study of Electoral Systems survey database, and we identify three cyclical group preferences for parties and three cyclical preferences for party leaders in 147 elections studied. Only one of these cycles affects the winner and, therefore, no best alternative exists. A bootstrapping exercise shows that the probability of a majority cycle in none of these six cases exceeds 40%. Our results suggest, therefore, that Condorcet cycles in national elections are rare. We compare subsamples of well and less informed citizens to test if the absence of cycles is caused by a similar assessment of parties and leaders of large groups of politically informed voters. We find some evidence for this hypothesis as cycles are more likely in the sample of less sophisticated voters. Keywords: Majority cycle, Condorcet Paradox, Comparative Study of Electoral Systems 1. Introduction Majority cycles, also known as Condorcet cycles or the voting paradox, have attracted a large amount of interest in the public choice literature. Theoretical papers have focused on analyzing which characteristics of preference profiles 1 Bodo Knoll, Joan Serra, University of Bochum, Department of Economics, Chair of Public Finance and Economic Policy, Universitätsstr. 150, 44801 Bochum Preprint submitted to 24th World Congress of Political Science July 23-28, 2016, Pozna, PolandJuly 1, 2016

5 10 15 20 25 30 make majority cycles more likely. Single-peaked preferences over onedimensional alternatives (e.g. ranked on a left-right scale) exclude majority cycles (Black, 1958). With equiprobable preference profiles, the likelihood of cycles rises with the number of alternatives and the number of voters (see e.g. Gehrlein (1983)). In actual large elections cycles have been searched so far only in a casuistic manner. They have been detected rarely; only two emirical studies find cycles in national elections to the best of our knowledge. 2 Kurrild-Klitgaard (2001) shows a cycle for a sample of 1994 Danish national election voters and Smith (2009) makes use of several polls and actual election outcomes to show a cycle in the 2009 Romanian presidential election. The purpose of the present paper is to look for Condorcet cycles in a large sample of national elections and to empirically assess their likelihood. We study electoral surveys from 147 national parliamentary elections in 62 different countries from 1996 to 2015. We take advantage of the richness of the surveys to look for cycles both among parties and among party leaders. Furthermore, the paper accounts for the fact that only samples of about 1000 to 2000 voters per election are included in the surveys. Cycles found in the sample of voters who participated in the election survey do not necessarily indicate a cycle in the entire population (see Regenwetter et al., 2002). Therefore, we bootstrap the cycle search procedure for each election and calculate probabilities that cycles occur in the actual electorate. A reason for the failure to observe electoral cycles in national elections may be that these electorates have largely onedimensional electoral preferences, for example along the left-right dimension. In a classic empirical study, Converse (1964) shows that the level of structure in the political preferences is higher among voters with higher levels of information about politics and with higher levels of education. Following this observation, we complete our analysis by splitting the national samples into several subsamples: We compare respon- 2 See Van Deemen (2014) for a good recent overview of the empirical search for majority cycles. 2

35 dents with high and low levels of education and likewise groups of politically well informed and less informed citizens to test whether education and political information reduce the probability of cycles. 2. Data and methodology 40 45 50 55 The data comes from the Comparative Study of Electoral Systems (CSES) database (modules 1-4) which collects surveys of post-election studies from 147 elections in 62 countries from 1996 to 2013. It includes information on political opinions of 225721 voters. Participants of the election studies in our dataset are asked to indicate if they like or dislike political parties and party leaders on a scale from 0 to 10. Following the procedure described in Van Deemen & Vergunst (1998),we interpret these two questions as ordinal preferences for parties and party leaders respectively and identify majority cycles. In a second step we bootstrap the cycle search procedure. For each election and both the party preferences and the party leader preferences we draw 10000 bootstrap samples and construct the skew-symmetric matrix described above in order to detect majority cycles and check the samples for the existence of a Condorcet winner. In a third step we split the sample into subgroups and calculate cycle probabilities for each subgroup in every election. This split is done according to voters level of information about politics and according to their level of education. Respondents are considered to be informed about politics if they could answer right at least two questions in a three question political information quiz. The subsample of voters with a high education level includes all respondents who completed secondary education. Both variables divide the sample into two similarly sized halves. In order to check whether the differences are significant we conduct two-sample Kolmogorov-Smirnov tests. 3

3. Empirical results and discussion 60 65 We find six majority cycles in the survey populations, three of these cycles relate to voters party preferences, three relate to preferences for party leaders. One cycle affects the most preferred alternatives and therefore no Condorcet winner exists. Table 1 lists all cycles along with the corresponding sample sizes, the number of alternatives and the empirical cycle probability calculated in the bootstrap exercise. In no case the probability of a cycle in the actual population exceeds 40%. Table 1 about here 70 75 80 85 Table 2 shows the results for subsamples of politically informed and uninformed voters respectively. Results in Table 3 are based on a split of the sample into voters with a high and a low level of education. Both comparisons demonstrate systematic differences between the subsamples. We find many more cycles in elections if the electorate is constrained to less informed or less educated voters. Most cycles that occur in groups of well informed voters apply to preferences for party leader whereas the politically uninformed would generate many cycles in their party preferences. The empirical cycle probabilities are also higher in some elections. Under the impartial culture assumption, less cycles should occur as the smaller number of voters in the subsample reduces mechanically the probability of a cycle. On the other hand, Tangian (2000) argues that cycles can be interpreted as errors in ranking candidates according to their strength or merits. In a large electorate these errors vanish and Condorcet cycles are less likely. Our results are in line with this view which may also account for the observation that most cycles do not include the top alternatives. Small parties and leaders are not well known by voters. Hence, less voters report a preference for these alternatives. And we may assume that the individual probability of errors in ranking unknown parties or party leaders is higher than in ranking well known alternatives. Both reasons explain why many of the cycles in our data are characterized by tiny majorities of few voters in pairwise comparisons 4

90 of small parties. Note further, that cycles in the entire survey population do not necessarily prevail in the subsamples. This is not surprising as our bootstrap exercise shows that even random draws from the survey participants would lead to cycles in at most 35% of all draws. For this reason, we focus on the empirical probability of cycles in the following. Table 2 about here Table 3 about here 95 100 In order to compare our subgroups of well-informed (well-educated) and lessinformed (less-educated) voters, we consider the empirical cycle propensities as a characteristic of each election. Figure 1 shows the distribution of the estimated bootstrap probabilities for the subsamples with high and low levels of information. According to a Kolmogorov-Smirnov test the cumulative density functions differ significantly. An electorate consisting of well-informed voters is more likely to end up in an election with a low cycle probability. This pattern holds both for preferences over parties and preferences over party leaders. Figure 1 about here 105 Figure 2 shows the same exercise for a sample split based on the education levels of voters. Again, we find significant differences in the distribution of cycle probabilities among the two subgroups with p-values of 0.14% and 5.72% respectively. Figure 2 about here 4. Conclusion 110 This paper confirms that majority cycles hardly occur in any election. Empirical cycle probabilities based on preference profiles of survey respondents are low; and this result holds regardless if people are asked to vote for parties or party leaders. Having data on preferences of many voters in a large set of national elections allows to analyze potential causes of high cycle probabilities. 5

115 120 125 One strategy is to split the survey samples into artificial subgroups sharing specific characteristics. We demonstrate this strategy by addressing the research question whether low political information and low levels of education in a population raise empirical cycle probabilities. We find that the subgroup of uninformed and less educated voters observes significantly higher cycle probabilities and is closer to a random assignment of preferences. Future research may follow and extend this approach by splitting samples according to other characteristics of voters or taking into account several dimensions simultaneously. Furthermore, it is still an open question whether a large number of voters raises or reduces the empirical probability of cycles. Controlling for the size of the bootstrap samples helps to test opposing theories empirically. References Black, D. (1958). The theory of committees and elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 130 Converse, P. E. (1964). The nature of belief systems in mass publics. In D. E. Apter (Ed.), Ideology and Its Discontents (pp. 206 61). New York: Free Press. Gehrlein, W. (1983). Condorcet s paradox. Theory and Decision, 15, 161 197. Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (2001). An empirical example of the condorcet paradox of voting in a large electorate. Public Choice, 107, 135 145. 135 Regenwetter, M., Adams, J., & Grofman, B. (2002). On the (sample) condorcet efficiency of majority rule: An alternative view of majority cycles and social homogeneity. Theory and Decision, 53, 153 186. Smith, W. D. (2009). The romanian 2009 presidential election featured one or more high condorcet cycles. RangeVoting. org., Center for Range Voting, 13. 140 Tangian, A. S. (2000). Unlikelihood of condorcets paradox in a large society. Social Choice and Welfare, 17, 337 365. 6

Van Deemen, A. (2014). Public Choice, 158, 311 330. On the empirical relevance of condorcets paradox. 145 Van Deemen, A., & Vergunst, N. (1998). Empirical evidence of paradoxes of voting in dutch elections. Public Choice, 97, 475 490. 7

5. Tables Table 1: List of Cycles Country Year Unit Voters Alternatives Top Cycle Bootstrap Switzerland 1999 Party 1938 5 0.3866 Philippines 2004 Party 1009 6 0.2884 Spain 2008 Party 1170 9 0.2199 Peru 2000 Leader 1091 6 0.2264 Czech Republic 2006 Leader 1902 5 0.3348 Denmark 2007 Leader 1418 9 x 0.3553 8

Table 2: Cycles by Level of Information Country Year Unit Voters Alternatives Top Cycle Bootstrap High Information Switzerland 2011 Party 1063 7 0.3156 Romania 1996 Leader 506 6 x 0.1714 Finland 2011 Leader 922 8 0.3230 New Zealand 2008 Leader 630 8 0.4112 Thailand 2011 Leader 30 8 0.7696 Low Information Albania 2005 Party 549 9 0.1387 France 2002 Party 515 9 0.2133 Italy 2006 Party 266 6 0.5894 Netherlands 2002 Party 786 9 0.1218 Norway 2001 Party 853 7 0.2503 Germany 2009 Party 846 6 0.4476 South Korea 2008 Party 97 7 0.4723 Philippines 2010 Party 329 7 0.2230 Switzerland 2011 Party 378 7 0.4423 Spain 2008 Leader 492 9 x 0.7079 9

Table 3: Cycles by Level of Education Country Year Unit Voters Alternatives Top Cycle Bootstrap High Education Lithuania 1997 Party 646 6 x 0.2410 Russian Federation 1999 Party 1343 6 0.2445 Great Britain 2005 Party 363 5 0.2434 Italy 2006 Party 632 6 0.3826 Chile 2009 Party 583 6 0.3255 Denmark 2007 Leader 1220 9 x 0.5036 Finland 2007 Leader 1042 8 0.2044 Montenegro 2012 Leader 310 8 0.3804 Low Education Republic Of Korea 2000 Party 263 6 0.1754 Bulgaria 2001 Party 467 7 0.2301 Denmark 2001 Party 415 8 0.3458 Finland 2003 Party 338 7 0.3016 Kyrgyzstan 2005 Party 32 7 0.6847 Philippines 2004 Party 514 6 0.5041 Belarus 2008 Party 30 7 0.9278 Switzerland 2007 Party 87 8 0.8776 Germany 2009 Party 1616 6 0.2320 Finland 2011 Party 174 8 0.5613 Hong Kong 2008 Party 186 7 0.5002 Israel 2006 Party 165 6 0.1810 Switzerland 2011 Party 115 7 0.5644 France 2012 Party 1339 6 0.4484 Thailand 2011 Party 1072 9 0.2310 Peru 2001 Leader 232 6 0.1338 Belarus 2008 Leader 33 7 0.9235 10

Spain 2008 Leader 748 9 0.5239 Slovenia 2008 Leader 216 8 0.1594 11

6. Figures Figure 1: Cycles and Information Party Cycle Probabilities by Information Leader Cycle Probabilities by Information Cumulative Probability High Information Voters Low Information Voters K S test: 0.2064 p value: 0.0047 Cumulative Probability High Information Voters Low Information Voters K S test: 0.2209 p value: 0.0150 Probability of Cycles Parties Probability of Cycles Leaders 12

Figure 2: Cycles and Education Party Cycle Probabilities by Education Leader Cycle Probabilities by Education Cumulative Probability High Education Voters Low Education Voters K S test: 0.2109 p value: 0.0014 Cumulative Probability High Education Voters Low Education Voters K S test: 0.1683 p value: 0.0572 Probability of Cycles Parties Probability of Cycles Leaders 13