SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE!

Similar documents
SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE!

SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE!

SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE!

SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE!

SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE!

Prior to 1940, the Austrian School was known primarily for its contributions

As Joseph Stiglitz sees matters, the euro suffers from a fatal. Book Review. The Euro: How a Common Currency. Journal of FALL 2017

SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE!

SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE!

A Tiger by the Tail. A 40-Years Running Commentary on Keynesianism by Hayek

SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE!

John Maynard Keynes v. Friedrich Hayek Part I: The Battle of Ideas (Commanding Heights) 2. What economic concepts did John Maynard Keynes invent?

Overview of the Austrian School theories of capital and business cycles and implications for agent-based modeling

Economic Growth & Population Decline What To Do About Latvia?

VITA. Short-Run Reserve Position Adjustment of New York City Banks (Chairman: Milton Friedman)

SCHOOLS OF ECONOMICS. Classical, Keynesian, & Monetary

10/7/2013 SCHOOLS OF ECONOMICS. Classical, Keynesian, & Monetary. as Neo- Classical Supply Side Trickle Down Free Trade CLASSICAL THEORY

SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE!

Obama Worse than Bush (translated from Polish by Irena Czernichowska)

The Rationale for Independent Monetary Policy

Did Hayek and Robbins Deepen the Great Depression? 1

ECO 171S: Hayek and the Austrian Tradition Syllabus

Celebrating 20 Years of the Bank of Mexico s Independence. Remarks by. Ben S. Bernanke. Chairman. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

As many astute economists have observed fiat money could well trigger either a serious

The present volume is an engaging and intriguing account. Book Review. How Global Currencies Work: Past, Present, and Future. Journal of SUMMER 2018

SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE!

Allan Meltzer and the History of the Federal Reserve. Michael D. Bordo. Rutgers, NBER, and the Hoover Institution, Stanford University

Review of Roger E. Backhouse s The puzzle of modern economics: science or ideology? Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2010, 214 pp.

VITA. Short-Run Reserve Position Adjustment of New York City Banks (Chairman: Milton Friedman)

The financial crisis, accompanying recession, and. Qu a r t e r ly Jo u r n a l of. Jo h n P. Co c h r a n. Vol. 14 N o.

This Expansion Looks Familiar

Globalization & the Battle of Ideas. Economic Theory and Practice in the 20 th Century

The recent financial crisis of generated a debate. Book Review. Monetary Regimes and Inflation: History, Economic, and Political

Friedrich A. Hayek: A Centenary Appreciation

Hey, there! My name is (Name), and I ve got some kinda heavy stuff on my mind.

Paul Krugman is a Keynesian, and I do not mean New Keynesian either. He is

FINANCIAL CRISIS ECON 464W

Introduction [to The Economics of the Great Depression]

Chapter Introduction. Section 1: Causes of the Depression Section 2: Americans Face Hard Times Section 3: Hoover s Response Fails

Borrowing Credibility: Foreign Financiers and Monetary Regimes

Sebastian Mallaby is the Paul A. Volcker Senior Fellow for International. Book Review. The Man Who Knew: The Life and Times of Alan Greenspan

TEKS 8C: Calculate percent composition and empirical and molecular formulas. Causes of the Great Depression

Why Monetary Freedom Matters Ron Paul

Froth and Bubble: The Inconsistency of Paul Krugman s Macroeconomic Analysis

LECTURE 2 The Effects of Monetary Changes: Narrative Evidence and Natural Experiments. August 29, 2018

Hawks and Doves at the Federal Reserve. Michael D Bordo, Rutgers University and the Hoover Institution, Stanford University

A CRITIQUE OF MONETARISM

The Nobel Roundtable. MICHAEL MILKEN: Welcome. Let s start with a. paul bliese

The Most Dangerous Idea in Federal Reserve History: Monetary Policy Doesn t Matter

Monetary Theory and Central Banking By Allan H. Meltzer * Carnegie Mellon University and The American Enterprise Institute

Communicating a Systematic Monetary Policy

A Perspective on the Economy and Monetary Policy

The Three Great Thinkers Who Changed Economics

The best books on Globalization

Systematic Policy and Forward Guidance

9 Some implications of capital heterogeneity Benjamin Powell*

IMPACT OF ASIAN FLU ON CANADIAN EXPORTS,

The present volume is an accomplished theoretical inquiry. Book Review. Journal of. Economics SUMMER Carmen Elena Dorobăț VOL. 20 N O.

From Boom to Bust. From Boom to Bust. Bulls vs. Bears: What to do about the Economy? The United States in the Great Depression

Friedman and the Bernanke-Taylor Debate on Rules versus Constrained Discretion

The 1920s, and the Great Depression.

4. Philip Cortney, The Economic Munich: The I.T.O. Charter, Inflation or Liberty, the 1929 Lesson (New York: Philosophical Library, 1949).

Economic Growth & Population Decline What To Do About Latvia? Edward Hugh Riga: March 2012

Government 7035: Political Economy

MARGINALIZED THEORIES OF BUSINESS CYCLE BASED ON STRATEGIC BEHAVIOR

From The Collected Works of Milton Friedman, compiled and edited by Robert Leeson and Charles G. Palm.

References: Shiller, R.J., (2000), Irrational Exuberance. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Program and Readings 2014 Summer Institute The History of Economics

SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE!

General Discussion: Cross-Border Macroeconomic Implications of Demographic Change

Thomas Oatley. (919) (Work) University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill. (202) (Home) Chapel Hill, NC

SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE!

Part 1. Economic Theory and the Economics Profession

Keynes and Hayek: Some Commonalities and Differences

Crash and Depression ( )

Recession in Japan: Part II Historical Aspects

SSUSH17 The student will analyze the causes and consequences of the Great Depression.

Governing Crises The Political Economy of Financial Booms and Busts

Is the recession over in New York?

China s Response to the Global Slowdown: The Best Macro is Good Micro

Using the Index of Economic Freedom

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Macroeconomics, Questions 6-7

How Friedman and Schwartz Became Monetarists

Book Review SUMMER Patrick Newman VOL. 19 N O Economics. Roger Lowenstein

Recession in Japan Part I

Twice the pride, double the fall

Liquidation Cycles and the Great Depression *

Hayek and Keynes: What Have We Learned?

SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE!

An interview with. Milton Friedman. America s best known libertarian economist

Volume Title: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, Volume 15. Volume URL:

A BRIEF BIOGRAPHICAL SKETCH OF FRIEDRICH A. HAYEK 1

ECONOMICS 115: THE WORLD ECONOMY IN THE 20 TH CENTURY PAST PROBLEM SETS Fall (First Set)

SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE!

Readings in the History of Modern Macroeconomics

CAPPELEN DAMM ACCESS UPDATE: THE PERFECT SLOSH

With Paul Samuelson. "The Dollar in Danger."* Moderated by Peter Lisagor. National Educational Television, New York, 17 March 1968.

Hay e k an d th e 21 s t Ce n t u r y

Volume Title: The Korean War and United States Economic Activity, Volume URL:

SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE!

Transcription:

SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE! The Independent Review does not accept pronouncements of government officials nor the conventional wisdom at face value. JOHN R. MACARTHUR, Publisher, Harper s The Independent Review is excellent. GARY BECKER, Noble Laureate in Economic Sciences Subscribe to The Independent Review and receive a free book of your choice* such as the 25th Anniversary Edition of Crisis and Leviathan: Critical Episodes in the Growth of American Government, by Founding Editor Robert Higgs. This quarterly journal, guided by co-editors Christopher J. Coyne, and Michael C. Munger, and Robert M. Whaples offers leading-edge insights on today s most critical issues in economics, healthcare, education, law, history, political science, philosophy, and sociology. Thought-provoking and educational, The Independent Review is blazing the way toward informed debate! Student? Educator? Journalist? Business or civic leader? Engaged citizen? This journal is for YOU! *Order today for more FREE book options Perfect for students or anyone on the go! The Independent Review is available on mobile devices or tablets: ios devices, Amazon Kindle Fire, or Android through Magzter. INDEPENDENT INSTITUTE, 100 SWAN WAY, OAKLAND, CA 94621 800-927-8733 REVIEW@INDEPENDENT.ORG PROMO CODE IRA1703

REVIEW ESSAY Reflections on Reflections A Consensus about the Great Depression? ROGER W. GARRISON In Reflections on the Great Depression (2002), leading economists who lived through and wrote about the Great Depression are invited to reflect on that horrific and still-puzzling episode. Randall E. Parker of East Carolina University (Greenville, North Carolina) conducted eleven interviews in 1997 and 1998, his questions sometimes provoking answers that will amuse and inform a wide variety of readers. The interviewees, five now deceased (indicated by an asterisk), were born during the first two decades of the twentieth century: Paul Samuelson, Milton Friedman, Moses Abramowitz*, Albert Hart*, Charles Kindleberger, Anna Schwartz, James Tobin*, Wassily Leontief*, Morris Adelman, Herbert Stein*, and Victor Zarnowitz. What do you think of monocausal explanations of the Great Depression? What was the initial impetus for the Great Depression, and what accounts for its depth? What ended the Great Depression? Could it happen again? Should the Federal Reserve be an arbiter of security prices? These questions and others about John Maynard Keynes s influence, the role of government, and the distribution of Roger W. Garrison is a professor of economics at Auburn University. The Independent Review, v. VIII, n.1, Summer 2003, ISSN 1086-1653, Copyright 2003, pp. 113 120. 113

114 R OGER W. GARRISON income create a common denominator among the varied discussions of the world between the wars. To put the questions and answers into perspective, Parker mentions in the preface his own empirical investigations (Fackler and Parker 1994), in which he put several monocausal explanations to the test. To pass the test, the hypothesized cause must explain (using 95 percent confidence bands) the depth and duration of the depression. Neither money nor debt nor gold flows could pass. It took a combination of causes to account for the actual movements in output over the course of the cycle. The explanations jointly deserving of our attention, as set out by Parker in an overview chapter, are Milton Friedman s monetary hypothesis, Ben Bernanke s debtdeflation hypothesis, and Barry Eichengreen s gold-standard hypothesis. Bernanke, now a governor of the Federal Reserve System, wrote the book s foreword. The discriminating reader will detect an unconscious blurring of correlation, explanation, and causation. Suppose a careless smoker starts a grass fire. After burning an acre or two of grass, the fire ignites a large pile of discarded tires. The heat intensifies markedly. Then gusting winds send the blaze into a nearby forest. The whole episode comes to be known as the Great Conflagration. Years later, pyrometricians put the various monocausal explanations to the test (using 95 percent confidence bands). Neither the old-tire hypothesis nor the gusting-winds hypothesis nor any other single hypothesis passes. (They overlook the careless-smoker hypothesis, which would have been a pyrometric nonstarter in any case.) It takes a combination of causes to account for the actual intensity and duration of the fire. Investigators less constrained by 95 percent confidence bands and more attuned to the distinction between correlation and causation would not hesitate to identify the careless smoker as the cause and to regard the old tires and the gusting winds as having enormously compounded the consequences. This verdict would stand even though the careless smoker by himself accounts for neither the intensity nor the duration of the fire. When asked What was the initial impetus for the Great Depression, and what accounts for its depth? Morris Adelman offers a revealing answer: I don t know what the initial impetus was, and I can t account for how deep it went except I would say that the second question is much more important than the first (p. 162). In other words, never mind what got it all started; the important thing is what made the bad situation worse! Herbert Stein attributes a similar view to Friedman and Schwartz: we were having an ordinary recession which was converted into the Great Depression by the mistakes of monetary policy (p. 174). The very use of the term ordinary recession signals that no cause need be identified. An ordinary recession is so, well, ordinary that the question of what caused it usually doesn t even arise. Some modern macroeconomists, Barry Eichengreen among them, use the term garden-variety recession to similar effect. The reader is led to believe that the ordinary or garden-variety recession itself has no particular claim on our attention and serves only as background for discussing the descent into deep depression. THE INDEPENDENT REVIEW

R EFLECTIONS ON R EFLECTIONS 115 Friedman, who doesn t share Adelman s agnosticism, gives his view of the issue: monetary developments [in the early 1930s] were the major explanation for the depth and the length of the contraction. As I ve said over and over again, I m not saying that that caused the initial recession.... And I don t doubt for a moment that the collapse of the stock market in 1929 played a role in the initial recession (p. 49). So, was the stock market run-up indicative of the final throes of an unsustainable boom? No. As Friedman makes clear later in the discussion, he s not at all suggesting that there was a boom-bust cycle: PARKER: Ben Bernanke has said that business cycle models should explain both the post-war and the interwar eras and that we shouldn t have two sets of models to explain them both. FRIEDMAN: I agree with that, but I go further. I don t believe there is such a thing as a business cycle [i.e., a boom-bust cycle]. I believe there are economic fluctuations [i.e., occasional lapses from full employment followed by recoveries]. PARKER: Oh, the plucking model, OK. FRIEDMAN: That s right. That is a single model which fits both the interwar and post-war. (pp. 54 55) In recent years, Bernanke (1983) has resurrected the old debt-deflation view of the Great Depression. Investors who are seriously in debt when a price deflation occurs are in big trouble. If there are enough such people and they all have to tighten their belts, then spending falls precipitously, and the whole economy is in big trouble especially the banks. In the face of bad loans and hard times, banks become more conservative. They build up their reserves, which intensifies the deflationary pressures. The big trouble gets bigger. This kind of self-aggravating process can turn a 1930 into a 1933. Parker describes the depression-inducing dynamics of debt cum deflation as the Nonmonetary/Financial hypothesis (p. 14). He recognizes, however, that this hypothesis is built on Friedman and Schwartz s monetary hypothesis. Clearly, the monetary aspect is crucial because otherwise there would be no accounting for the initial deflation. The debt, accumulated in the 1920s with little or no regard for the deflation that lay ahead, just helps to explain how a change in a nominal magnitude (the money supply) can have real consequences (reduced spending all around and hence reduced employment and output levels). Recent contributions to the debt-deflation literature (Fackler and Parker 2001) are aimed at answering the question: Did borrowers in the 1920s actually fail to anticipate the deflation in the 1930s?Yes, they actually did otherwise, they would not have agreed to borrow long term at positive nominal interest rates. The monetarists believe, however, that their own hypothesis can survive well with or without the debtdeflation flourish. Parker asks Anna Schwartz about the role of debt and deflation, referring to Irving Fisher s original 1933 article. Here, Schwartz, who sees the Fisher- VOLUME VIII, NUMBER 1, SUMMER 2003

116 R OGER W. GARRISON Bernanke perspective as overblown (p. 116), takes the opportunity to give us a little eyes-open history of economic thought: SCHWARTZ: I m not impressed with Fisher s contribution as an intellectual contribution. I think he was just explaining his own life (laughter). I mean here s this guy who s a million dollars in debt to his sister-in-law because he had played the stock market.... I don t blame him for expecting that the stock market would just continue in the direction in which it had been moving because he didn t really know what the Federal Reserve was going to do. But then when he got stuck with this enormous debt that he couldn t repay his sister-in-law, I think this seemed to him the explanation of why the Depression had happened. (p. 121) It s pretty clear what Schwartz thinks of Fisher, but what does she think of Friedman? Friedman believes that the collapse of the stock market in 1929 was what started the difficulties and that the Federal Reserve then made matters worse by allowing the money supply to collapse; Schwartz believes that the soaring stock market would have continued to soar if only the Federal Reserve hadn t cut the good times short with its untimely monetary stringency. Putting the stock market crash into proper perspective poses a problem for most business-cycle theorists. To explain the origins of the depression by pointing to the crash leaves them with a great deal of explaining to do. But to deny that the stock market played any causal role also requires some explaining. Were security prices in mid-1929 consistent with the fundamentals? If so, how had those fundamentals changed so dramatically since, say, 1925? And what then changed them again in the opposite direction? Were security prices dramatically out of line with the fundamentals in mid-1929? If so, what were the policies or market malfunctions that gave rise to overvalued equity shares? Was the stock market bubble just a symptom of a problem rather than the problem itself? If so, just what was the problem? Parker s Reflections cries out for more attention to the initial impetus question. The careless-smoker hypothesis advanced by the Austrian school focuses attention on a period well before Fisher s sister-in-law began making bad loans. Beginning in the early 1920s and with renewed resolve in 1927 and 1928, the Federal Reserve set itself the task of fostering economic growth. As things turned out, it fostered a little more growth than honest-to-god saving could sustain. Further, unduly favorable credit conditions throughout the decade account for both the increased indebtedness that Fisher and Bernanke are concerned about and the stock market run-up that Friedman and Schwartz are at odds about. In 1923, when F. A. Hayek first visited the United States, he saw a direct application of the theory of the business cycle spelled out in Ludwig von Mises s 1912 book The Theory of Money and Credit (reissued in 1953). The Austrian theory answers THE INDEPENDENT REVIEW

R EFLECTIONS ON R EFLECTIONS 117 the initial impetus question by showing how a credit-driven boom ends in a bust. The theory explains the ordinary recession though this particular recession was a bit on the extraordinary side owing to the historical setting. The relatively new and hence not well understood Federal Reserve was able to keep the boom going for a good many years. The theory does not purport to explain the actual depth and duration of the Great Depression, but it is consistent with the understanding that in the wake of the downturn all manner of policy blunders (monetary, fiscal, and regulatory) caused the depression to be much deeper and much longer than it otherwise would have been. Nor does the theory deny that some of the growth during the 1920s was real. In fact, the increases in real output offset in large part the inflationary pressures of easy money, keeping the general price level nearly constant and giving the illusion of macroeconomic health. (The careless-smoker analogy is not intended to suggest that carelessness was what underlay the Fed s pro-growth policies in the 1920s; it suggests only that the difference between Fed-fostered growth and otherwise healthy growth is difficult for econometricians to detect and, although crucial to our understanding of the whole episode, bears little on the issues of the depth and duration of the subsequent depression.) The Austrian theory does provide a sound analytical basis for answering Parker s oft-asked question, Should the Federal Reserve be an arbiter of security prices? Of course it should not. Under circumstances in which it has its own house in order, it need not and should not pass judgment on either relative or overall movements in security prices. But when those movements seem to be wholly unanchored in reality and to take on the features of an orgy or when they appear to be based on irrational exuberance, then the Federal Reserve should reevaluate its own role as a supplier of investment funds. To continue to fuel a speculative boom ignited by easy money is to have a tiger by the tail, an aspect of the Austrian theory explored by Sudha Shenoy (Hayek 1978). Did Parker or any of the interviewees have any inkling about the Austrian theory? Although that theory does not qualify as a modern explanation in Parker s book, his overview chapter contains a short section that identifies contemporary explanations of the Great Depression. One explanation is based on Say s law and the belief in the self-equilibrating powers of the market. The other is the Austrian explanation. Parker sets out the Austrian view, but without mentioning Mises or Hayek or any other Austrian economist: The Austrian school of thought argued that the Depression was the inevitable result of overinvestment during the 1920s. The best remedy for the situation was to let the Depression run its course so that the economy could be purified from negative effects of the false expansion. Government intervention was viewed by the Austrian school as a mechanism that would simply prolong the agony and make any subsequent depression worse than it would ordinarily be. (pp. 9 10) VOLUME VIII, NUMBER 1, SUMMER 2003

118 R OGER W. GARRISON Note that there is no hint here that the Austrians identify government intervention in the form of artificially low interest rates maintained by the Federal Reserve as the cause of the overinvestment. Also, as the Austrians always emphasized, it is not just overinvestment, but malinvestment (an intertemporal allocation of capital at odds with actual saving behavior) that characterizes the artificial boom and leads to a bust. Parker does not see the Austrians as offering an analytical framework (as laid out, for example, in Garrison 2001) for showing how interest-rate falsification has undesirable consequences. Instead, he sees their views as raw ethical judgments that underlie their moralizing about overly aggressive investment behavior and that support their reactionary political stance. Parker identifies the political counterpart to the Austrian theorists as the liquidationists : These individuals [the liquidationists] basically believed that economic agents should be forced to re-arrange their spending proclivities and alter their alleged profligate use of resources. If it took mass bankruptcies to produce this result and wipe the slate clean so that everyone could have a fresh start, then so be it. The liquidationists viewed the events of the Depression as an economic penance for the speculative excesses of the 1920s. Thus, the Depression was the price that was being paid for the misdeeds of the previous decade. (p. 9) Drawing from President Hoover s Memoirs (1952), Parker allows Treasury secretary Andrew Mellon to express the Austrian/liquidationist sentiments. The unbuttoned Mellon advises Hoover to [l]iquidate labor, liquidate stocks, liquidate the farmers, liquidate real estate.... [The depression] will purge the rottenness out of the system. High costs of living and high living will come down. People will work harder, live a more moral life. Values will be adjusted, and enterprising people will pick up the wrecks from less competent people (p. 9). When an interviewee even hints at the Austrian view of the problems in 1929, Parker responds with the question, Purge the rottenness out of the system? The words penance and purge, as used to denigrate the Austrian view, have the same flavor and intent as the word hangover in the dismissive treatment penned by Paul Krugman (1998). The contra-austrian message is clear: they don t teach; they preach. Friedman contrasts the theories taught at the University of Chicago with those taught at the London School of Economics (LSE, where Hayek presented and defended the Austrian theory), explaining why the LSE graduates were more receptive to Keynesian thinking: Abba Lerner (at the LSE) had been given a picture of incredible darkness, but Friedman (at Chicago) had been given a picture that we had things that we could do. Hence, Keynes had a message to bring [to Lerner and the Austrians], he had no message to bring [to Friedman and the Chicago economists] (p. 44). To Parker s suggestion that the Austrians wanted to purge the rottenness, Friedman, to his credit, responds, Well, I don t think Hayek or Lionel Robbins would have used that phrase (p. 43). THE INDEPENDENT REVIEW

R EFLECTIONS ON R EFLECTIONS 119 Parker, following Eichengreen (1992), recognizes that the gold standard provided a critical international link and that sterilization policies adopted by the United States kept gold flows from serving as an international equilibrating mechanism (pp. 16 19). Charles Kindleberger has always emphasized the international aspects of the forces that converted recession into depression, but he also claims to be a debt-deflation man (p.96). Like so many of the others, however, he is eclectic on the issue of the initial impetus, mentioning cryptically a series of bubbles: They go way up and something, I don t know what, pushes them back down (p. 97). For Kindleberger, the impetus to downward-moving bubbles was probably interest rates and the Hatry crisis. (English financier Clarence Hatry was disgraced and ruined in September 1929 when some of his loan collateral was revealed to be forged securities.) There is no hint in the discussion that the Federal Reserve with its easy-money/growth-fostering policies was the bubble blower. Kindleberger s one gratuitous mention of Mises epitomizes the modern attitude toward the Austrian school. In 1939, Kindleberger went to Switzerland for a threeyear stint at the Bank for International Settlements, but when France fell to Hitler in 1940, he decided he needed to go home. The Kindlebergers left Geneva on July 3 on the first leg of their journey, traveling by bus through the unoccupied part of France to Barcelona. While bussing across France and into Spain, they encountered an Austrian: KINDLEBERGER:... [W]hen we got to the border, I realized [that] behind me on the bus was Ludwig von Mises. He was feeling very badly and his wife wanted to have the window beside me closed. I wanted, because of my wife being pregnant, to have it open. I didn t realize who he was until we got to the border going into Spain. He was not my favorite economist. It wouldn t have done me any good to know who he was, I wouldn t change my attitude about the window. (p. 90) Kindleberger s sympathy for Mises is matched by the sympathy that modern macroeconomists have for the Austrian theory of boom and bust. It wouldn t do them any good to know what that theory actually is; they wouldn t change their attitudes about ordinary recessions and the Great Depression. Most of the interviewees suggest that it was the mobilization for entry into World War II or the money creation that financed that mobilization that eventually got the economy out of depression. Most hedge their answers about the possibility of another Great Depression. The monetarists believe or hope that at least the Federal Reserve had learned not to allow the money supply to collapse. These beliefs and hopes, however, are not accompanied by warnings against the Federal Reserve s fostering more economic growth than actual savings can sustain. In his brief concluding remarks, Parker points to the unfinished task of achieving a full understanding of the interwar experience. He imagines that the torch has been passed from the interviewees to Bernanke, Eichengreen, and a few other like-minded VOLUME VIII, NUMBER 1, SUMMER 2003

120 R OGER W. GARRISON researchers, and, on the basis of modern advances, he sees the profession as much closer than ever before to a consensus on the causes of the impetus, depth, protracted length, and worldwide spread (p. 201) of the Great Depression. Of course, he cannot expect modern Austrian macroeconomists to share in this assessment. References Bernanke, B. S. 1983. Nonmonetary Effects on the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression. American Economic Review 73, no. 3: 257 76. Eichengreen, B. 1992. Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression. New York: Oxford University Press. Fackler, J. S., and R. E. Parker. 1994. Accounting for the Great Depression: A Historical Decomposition. Journal of Macroeconomics 16, no. 2 (spring): 193 220.. 2001. Was Debt Deflation Operative During the Great Depression? Working paper, East Carolina University. Fisher, I. 1933. The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions. Econometrica 1, no. 4: 337 57. Garrison, R. W. 2001. Time and Money: The Macroeconomics of Capital Structure. London: Routledge. Hayek, F. A. 1978. A Tiger by the Tail: A 40-years Running Commentary on Keynesianism by Hayek. Compiled and introduced by Sudha R. Shenoy. London: Institute of Economic Affairs. Hoover, Herbert. 1952. The Memoirs of Herbert Hoover: The Great Depression, 1929 1941. New York: Macmillan. Krugman, Paul. 1998. The Hangover Theory: Are Recessions the Inevitable Payback for Good Times? Slate (December 4). At http://slate.msn.com. Mises, Ludwig von. [1912] 1953. The Theory of Money and Credit. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press. Parker, Randall, ed. 2002. Reflections on the Great Depression. Northampton, Mass.: Edward Elgar. THE INDEPENDENT REVIEW