NAFTA and Mexican Industrial Development

Similar documents
Chapter 13: NAFTA and Mexican Industrial Development

Trade Policy and Industrial Development. Lessons from Mexico

Chapter 12: North American Energy: A Clear Path Forward?

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N April Export Growth and Firm Survival

Heterogeneous Firms, Trade, and Links to Growth

ADJUSTMENT TO TRADE POLICY IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

Industrial Structure and Innovation: Notes Toward a New Strategy for Industrial Development in Mexico

Raymundo Miguel Campos-Vázquez. Center for Economic Studies, El Colegio de México, and consultant to the OECD. and. José Antonio Rodríguez-López

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France

ECO 7707: International Economic Relations

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

Trade liberalization and gender inequality

The China Syndrome. Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States. David H. Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon H.

Trade Costs and Export Decisions

Can free-trade policies help to reduce gender inequalities in employment and wages?

The North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) has raised Mexico s

ARTNeT Trade Economists Conference Trade in the Asian century - delivering on the promise of economic prosperity rd September 2014

Foreign Direct Investment and Wages in Indonesian Manufacturing

Earnings Inequality, Educational Attainment and Rates of Returns to Education after Mexico`s Economic Reforms

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Trade, skill-biased technical change and wages in Mexican manufacturing

Foreign market access and Chinese competition in India s textile and clothing industries

Labour demand and the distribution of wages in South African manufacturing exporters

Trade Policy, Agreements and Taxation of Multinationals

Are Mexican and U.S. Workers Complements or Substitutes? Raymond Robertson Texas A&M University and IZA

Trade Liberalization and the Wage Skill Premium: Evidence from Indonesia * Mary Amiti Federal Reserve Bank of New York and CEPR

The Backlash Against Globalization

Statistics to Measure Offshoring and its Impact

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

How does international trade affect household welfare?

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin

Determinants of Outward FDI for Thai Firms

Does Learning to Add up Add up? Lant Pritchett Presentation to Growth Commission October 19, 2007

Labor market consequences of trade openness and competition in foreign markets

Income Inequality and Trade Protection

Poverty Reduction and Economic Management The World Bank

Full file at

Productivity. Total Factor Productivity Across the Developing World

Test Bank for Economic Development. 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith

Labor Market Adjustments to Trade with China: The Case of Brazil

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

International Trade and Investment Economics Course Outline and Reading List

Trade, informality and employment in a lowincome country: The case of Vietnam

Trade Liberalization and Wage Inequality in India: A Mandated Wage Equation Approach

Distributional Effects of Globalization in Developing Countries *

Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins

POLICY OPTIONS AND CHALLENGES FOR DEVELOPING ASIA PERSPECTIVES FROM THE IMF AND ASIA APRIL 19-20, 2007 TOKYO

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

SEWING SUCCESS: EMPLOYMENT AND WAGES OF THE END OF THE MULTI- FIBRE ARRANGEMENT

CERDI, Etudes et Documents, E

Benefits and Challenges of Trade under NAFTA: The Case of Texas

Online Appendix. Capital Account Opening and Wage Inequality. Mauricio Larrain Columbia University. October 2014

Online Appendix for The Contribution of National Income Inequality to Regional Economic Divergence

Trade, Technology, and Institutions: How Do They Affect Wage Inequality? Evidence from Indian Manufacturing. Amit Sadhukhan 1.

Benefits and costs of free trade for less developed countries

Capital Profitability and Economic Growth

University of Hawai`i at Mānoa Department of Economics Working Paper Series

5A. Wage Structures in the Electronics Industry. Benjamin A. Campbell and Vincent M. Valvano

Discussion Paper Series

Globalization and Poverty Forthcoming, University of

Chapter 4. Preview. Introduction. Resources, Comparative Advantage, and Income Distribution

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Which firms benefit more from the own-firm and spillover effects of inward foreign direct investment?

UNION COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, FALL 2004 ECO 146 SEMINAR IN GLOBAL ECONOMIC ISSUES GLOBALIZATION AND LABOR MARKETS

Main Tables and Additional Tables accompanying The Effect of FDI on Job Separation

International Trade Revised: November 8, 2012 Latest version available at

Wage inequality and skill premium

The Effect of China on Mexico-U.S. Trade: Undoing NAFTA?

Simon Fraser University Department of Economics. Econ342: International Trade. Mid-Term Examination

Explaining the Unexplained: Residual Wage Inequality, Manufacturing Decline, and Low-Skilled Immigration. Unfinished Draft Not for Circulation

International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito

Understanding the dynamics of labor income inequality in Latin America (WB PRWP 7795)

CRS-2 Production Sharing and U.S.-Mexico Trade When a good is manufactured by firms in more than one country, it is known as production sharing, an ar

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different?

Trade Liberalization and Inequality: Re-examining Theory and Empirical Evidence

Inequality in Indonesia: Trends, drivers, policies

Labour Market Reform, Firm-level Employment Adjustment and Trade Liberalisation

Economics of the Trans- Pacific Partnership (TPP)

Global Trends in Location Selection Final results for 2005

International Import Competition and the Decision to Migrate: Evidence from Mexico

Asian Development Bank Institute. ADBI Working Paper Series INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND INEQUALITY. Shujiro Urata and Dionisius A.

Skills, Exports, and the Wages of Five Million Latin American Workers

The term developing countries does not have a precise definition, but it is a name given to many low and middle income countries.

Gendered Employment Data for Global CGE Modeling

The Effect of Globalization on Educational Attainment

International Trade and Inequality

Globalization: What Did We Miss?

Globalisation and Open Markets

The Effect of International Trade on Wages of Skilled and Unskilled Workers: Evidence from Brazil

Effects of globalization - economic growth. Giovanni Marin Department of Economics, Society, Politics Università degli Studi di Urbino Carlo Bo

Growth, Investment and Trade Challenges: India and Japan

Direction of trade and wage inequality

ECONOMICS 6421 (FALL 2009) ADVANCED INTERNATIONAL TRADE: THEORY AND POLICY

Rethinking Growth Policy The Schumpeterian Perspective. EEA Meeting Geneva, August 2016

Parliamentary Research Branch FREE TRADE IN NORTH AMERICA: THE MAQUILADORA FACTOR. Guy Beaumier Economics Division. December 1990

Development, Politics, and Inequality in Latin America and East Asia

Japan s Policy to Strengthen Economic Partnership. November 2003

International Import Competition and the Decision to Migrate: Evidence from Mexico

The Impact of Trade on Inequality in Developing Countries

Transcription:

Columbia University June 6, 2014

Mexico s Disappointing Growth Performance Despite concerted efforts at market-oriented reforms since the mid-1980s, Mexico s growth has underperformed that of other middle-income countries.

vs. Latin-American Countries Panel A. Latin America 1 Hanson: Why Isn t Mexico Rich? 989 Log per capita GDP (1980 = 0) 0.5 0 Mexico Brazil Venezuela Argentina Chile 0.5 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 Year Source: Panel Hanson B. Southeast (2010). Asia 1.5 Mexico Malaysia Thailand = 0) Indonesia Philippines

Introduction 0.5 Existing Approaches Sectoral Shifts and Innovation Conclusion vs. Asian Countries 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 Year Panel B. Southeast Asia 1.5 Log per capita GDP (1980 = 0) 1 0.5 0 Mexico Malaysia Thailand Indonesia Philippines 0.5 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 Year Source: Hanson (2010). Figure 1: Economic Growth in Comparison Countries (continued)

990 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLVIII (December 2010) vs. Eastern Europe Panel C. Eastern and Central Europe 0.8 Log per capita GDP (1980 = 0) 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 Mexico Hungary Turkey Bulgaria Romania 0.2 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 Year Source: Hanson (2010). Figure 1: Economic Growth in Comparison Countries (continued) are insufficient to explain the Mexican case. Because some countries in Latin America have NAFTA and Mexican done well Industrial in the last Development decade, Mexico s perforrelative to Asia and Europe, which during the second half of the twentieth century did converge toward U.S. income levels, was due pri-

Mexico s Disappointing Growth Performance (cont.) Big question: What role has NAFTA (or integration more broadly) played in this growth experience?

Mexico s Disappointing Growth Performance (cont.) Big question: What role has NAFTA (or integration more broadly) played in this growth experience? There are a number of plausible alternative factors that have contributed to the disappointing performance (Hanson, 2010; Kehoe and Ruhl, 2010): Monopolies and inefficient regulation (Arias et al., 2010). Underdeveloped credit markets (Haber, 2004). Informality and evasion (Levy, 2008). Corruption and, more recently, violence.... All of these likely played a role.

Mexico s Disappointing Growth Performance (cont.) Big question: What role has NAFTA (or integration more broadly) played in this growth experience? There are a number of plausible alternative factors that have contributed to the disappointing performance (Hanson, 2010; Kehoe and Ruhl, 2010): Monopolies and inefficient regulation (Arias et al., 2010). Underdeveloped credit markets (Haber, 2004). Informality and evasion (Levy, 2008). Corruption and, more recently, violence.... All of these likely played a role. But let s focus for now on trade/integration.

Plan of Talk Introduction Some Observations about Existing Approaches Sectoral Shifts and Innovation Conclusion

The Empirical Challenge As many others have noted, evaluating NAFTA is difficult because other things changed at the same time: Trade liberalization of mid-1980s. Events in 1990s may have been delayed reaction. Peso crisis. As Krueger (2000) and others have noted, devaluation was much larger (50% nominal devaluation) than tariff changes (10% reductions in Mexico, 3-5% in US).

The Empirical Challenge As many others have noted, evaluating NAFTA is difficult because other things changed at the same time: Trade liberalization of mid-1980s. Events in 1990s may have been delayed reaction. Peso crisis. As Krueger (2000) and others have noted, devaluation was much larger (50% nominal devaluation) than tariff changes (10% reductions in Mexico, 3-5% in US). Two broad categories of approaches to evaluating the effects of NAFTA: Applied general equilibrium modeling. Reduced-form, typically difference-in-differences. I will argue that there is something missing from each.

Applied General Equilibrium Modeling Ably reviewed by Kehoe (2005), and yesterday s keynote.

Applied General Equilibrium Modeling Ably reviewed by Kehoe (2005), and yesterday s keynote. Advantage: Can make theoretically well-grounded statements about general-equilibrium effects, welfare.

Applied General Equilibrium Modeling Ably reviewed by Kehoe (2005), and yesterday s keynote. Advantage: Can make theoretically well-grounded statements about general-equilibrium effects, welfare. Issue: Valid only if the model is right. (A big if. )

Applied General Equilibrium Modeling Ably reviewed by Kehoe (2005), and yesterday s keynote. Advantage: Can make theoretically well-grounded statements about general-equilibrium effects, welfare. Issue: Valid only if the model is right. (A big if. ) My reading of Tim s reading: Applied GE models did not perform particularly well in predicting the effects of NAFTA. One issue is new goods margin. Aggregate changes seem to be driven largely by TFP changes. But models for the most part do not endogenize TFP. It may be that we applied GE modelers eventually decide that the biggest effect of liberalization of trade and capital flows is on productivity through changing the distribution of firms and encouraging technology adoption rather than the effects emphasized by the models used to analyze the impact of NAFTA. (Kehoe, 2005, p. 372)

Reduced-Form Approaches A number of authors have followed what De la Cruz et al. (2013) call econometric approaches, e.g. difference-in-differences.

Reduced-Form Approaches A number of authors have followed what De la Cruz et al. (2013) call econometric approaches, e.g. difference-in-differences. Advantage: Require weaker assumptions ex ante.

Reduced-Form Approaches A number of authors have followed what De la Cruz et al. (2013) call econometric approaches, e.g. difference-in-differences. Advantage: Require weaker assumptions ex ante. Issue: generally have to give up on making statements about general equilibrium effects, welfare.

Reduced-Form Approaches A number of authors have followed what De la Cruz et al. (2013) call econometric approaches, e.g. difference-in-differences. Advantage: Require weaker assumptions ex ante. Issue: generally have to give up on making statements about general equilibrium effects, welfare. De la Cruz et al. (2013) provide a nice review. Here I ll make a few observations, with a focus on effects on productivity in Mexico.

Lopez Cordova (2003) Emphasizes 3 channels: Import-discipline effect. Improved access to intermediate inputs, machinery. Reallocation toward more productive plants.

Lopez Cordova (2003) Emphasizes 3 channels: Import-discipline effect. Improved access to intermediate inputs, machinery. Reallocation toward more productive plants. Using data from Encuesta Industrial Anual for 1993-2000, first estimates TFP using Olley and Pakes (1996) method.

Lopez Cordova (2003) Emphasizes 3 channels: Import-discipline effect. Improved access to intermediate inputs, machinery. Reallocation toward more productive plants. Using data from Encuesta Industrial Anual for 1993-2000, first estimates TFP using Olley and Pakes (1996) method. Then regresses TFP on tariffs, controlling for plant, industry, geographical characteristics.

t 1 s 3 1 c o Lopez Cordova (2003) (cont.) Of <0 "> 10 & o oo 8^r T? OO t? o un o o oo oo o o o o * lo '? on lo o o (NO OO O O O O O CD O O rn oo CD oo OOO rnr oin rn 00 O CD CD O* O O* O P*. CD VO 0> un 00 on CD CD ^T CD uo O o cd o CD O CD O un CD O CD CD CD CD O i? II &J VJ O? <* oo vp o o o o ^- r- r- vo r? > O Tf r? t?,-; O O O O r^d?=s LO o Tf r- O -3 O CD O O % % _^ on i^.?_,?s os *? rs MIS VO Un ^ OMTl?tf- t? r? VO r? CD CD ^t- r? r? r? OO O CD??' CD 00 tj- rsi r^ O O CD CD CD O CD O $ t vpoo 0000 CT* on rnoo r? cr\ vooo ^-r????^- rs ts 00 "*J- rn <?3" crv CD vpcd "T rs ^-oo ts?? t? r? oovo ^r on ^"t? CTJON Or- O?-; OJ (N CD CD OO O'O O O O O O* O :=3 00 I?. VO ', _. -. SS?;:?:= OO CD CD r- CD?2? O CD* o>ro on on SIS OOr- o> ** o> *? r- vo "^- on 00 o on rv on rn Or r-cd OOO OOCT? Or- t? OO un O O??; rn??; un on 00*-; oo??; "?^00 CDCD i-^o O O CDCD CDCD CDCD U^ VO 00 00 00 CD CD CD O O von vo un o\ un rn rs t? 00 00 00 VO ^" r- CD?^ r? rn CD OAr- ON r? CD CD CD CD CD CD I S -2 i 1? c w c.5 I S E -S t s 5 i_l.?.5? u_? ui_ uj: B-?i fo s

Lopez Cordova (2003) (cont.) Findings: Mexican tariffs TFP U.S. tariffs TFP Use of imported inputs does not seem to have robust positive effect on TFP.

Lopez Cordova (2003) (cont.) Findings: Mexican tariffs TFP U.S. tariffs TFP Use of imported inputs does not seem to have robust positive effect on TFP. There are things to criticize here: TFP lumps mark-ups, measurment error, possibly output and input quality with technical efficiency. Did not include plant effects. Are results driven by cross-sectional variation? but overall the results are credible that NAFTA had positive within-sector effects on productivity.

Introduction Existing Approaches Data source: EIA Non integrated Fully Integrated that enhance access to Sectoral Shifts and Innovation Conclusion Exporters Importers source of a country s co (Bernard & Bradford Je not find evidence that ex De Hoyos and Iacovone Figure 4. Labor productivity (2013) performance by integration status. growth. However, a poss dent improvements in th explanation behind the 1994 1996 descriptive analysis (Sect 1998 2000 2002 Finally, consistent with year Hoekman, 2000; Evenett appears to be an importa Exporter and Importer Just Exporting Just Importing plants acquired, or with p ever, data limitations do BANXICO and Authors Calculations Source: INEGI, nel in more detail becaus Figure 5. Impact of NAFTA on productivity by integration status for all the foreign ownership of firms. son, we decided not to pu of FDI and the potential The results of this paper confirm the importance of the import-competition channel. As previously suggested in various of productivity changes this study, even if we are Figure plots coefficients from regression of log value-added per worker on empirical studies (Fernandes, 2007; Pavcnik, 2002; Tybout & analysis. Treatment Effect.1 0.1.2.3 time * dummies for importer/exporter/both. Results robust to throwing out switchers. NOTES NAFTA and Mexican Industrial 1. Development In the paper we refer interchangeably to firm or plant to identify the 4. See for Eric example Verhoogen Markuse

Iacovone (2012) L. Iacovone / Journal of Development Economics 99 (2012) 474 485 481 1.5 Marginal Effect of % Tariff Change on % Productivity Growth OLS FE (3) (4) 1 0.260 0.391 0.5 (0.015) (0.014) 0.012 0.015 0 (0.002) (0.002) 0.173 0.499 (0.008) (0.011) -0.5 0.002 0.006 (0.001) (0.001) -1 0.045 0.086 OLS FE (0.003) (0.013) -1.5 0.021 0.004 1% 5% 10% 25% 50% Mean 75% 90% 95% 99% (0.002) (0.003) 0.083 0.026 Percentile - Distance from Frontier (0.009) (0.016) 0.004 0.006 Fig. 3. Marginal effect of tariffs on productivity growth. (0.001) (0.002) 0.006 0.004 Second, we run a simple regression to evaluate the correlation between the NAFTA total tariff cuts between 1994 and 2002 and average (0.001) (0.002) Yes No Yes No measures of capital or skill intensity at the 6-digit industry level in Yes Yes effects). 1994. The results suggest that while there is a positive correlation between No Yes tariff cuts and skill intensity this is not statistically significant Yes Yes (see Table 9 in the online appendix). 44,176 44,176 leading firms 0.075 0.217 Third, in we each arguesector. that if the HO reallocation was at play we should observe sales increasing in sectors characterized by tariff reductions. However, in columns (1) and (2) of Table 1, we exactly showed that Effects calculated from regression of log value-added/worker on interaction of distance to frontier and level of tariff (and industry or plant Distance is ratio of value-added/worker to avg value-added/worker of 5

Verhoogen (2008) 100 90 80 Figure IV Exports, High-quality Models as Percentage of VW Output Percentage of total output 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 % output exported % output New Beetle/Jetta/Golf 0 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 Notes: Output measured in physical units. Omitted model from upper curve is the Original Beetle. Data from Bulletins of the Asociacion Mexicana de la Industria Automotriz (Mexican Automobile Industry Association). Notes: Uses data from the Bulletins of the Asociación Mexicana de la Industria Automotriz (AMIA). Production measured in number of vehicles.

Verhoogen (2008) (cont.) -Parametric Regressions, Changes 1993-1997 and 1997-2001 App. Fig. Vb: Changes in log white-collar wage 0.2 94-1997 98-2001 Δ log real white-collar wage 0.1 0-0.1-0.2 change 1993-1997 change 1997-2001 1 2-0.3-3 -2-1 0 1 2 log domestic sales, initial year App. Fig. Vd: Changes in log wage ratio Notes: Uses data from balanced panel of non-maquiladora plants from the Encuesta Industrial Anual (EIA). 0.05

Existing Approaches: Summary Both approaches have made progress, but both also seem to me to be missing something important.

Existing Approaches: Summary Both approaches have made progress, but both also seem to me to be missing something important. Applied GE:

Existing Approaches: Summary Both approaches have made progress, but both also seem to me to be missing something important. Applied GE: Sectoral shifts central to analysis.

Existing Approaches: Summary Both approaches have made progress, but both also seem to me to be missing something important. Applied GE: Sectoral shifts central to analysis. But relatively little attention to productivity changes that are endogenous to trade liberalization.

Existing Approaches: Summary Both approaches have made progress, but both also seem to me to be missing something important. Applied GE: Sectoral shifts central to analysis. But relatively little attention to productivity changes that are endogenous to trade liberalization. Reduced-form:

Existing Approaches: Summary Both approaches have made progress, but both also seem to me to be missing something important. Applied GE: Sectoral shifts central to analysis. But relatively little attention to productivity changes that are endogenous to trade liberalization. Reduced-form: Documents productivity changes.

Existing Approaches: Summary Both approaches have made progress, but both also seem to me to be missing something important. Applied GE: Sectoral shifts central to analysis. But relatively little attention to productivity changes that are endogenous to trade liberalization. Reduced-form: Documents productivity changes. But relatively little attention to effects of sectoral shifts on ongoing productivity growth.

Sectoral Shifts and Innovation Old-fashioned idea (Prebisch, 1950; Matsuyama, 1992): Different activities are associated with different inherent rates of innovation, productivity growth. Liberalization changes to pattern of specialization, may lead to specialization in non-dynamic activities.

Sectoral Shifts and Innovation Old-fashioned idea (Prebisch, 1950; Matsuyama, 1992): Different activities are associated with different inherent rates of innovation, productivity growth. Liberalization changes to pattern of specialization, may lead to specialization in non-dynamic activities. What follows is very low-tech, more analytical narrative than definitive analysis. The hope is that it stimulates more in-depth research into the Mexican and similar cases.

Sectoral Shifts and Innovation Old-fashioned idea (Prebisch, 1950; Matsuyama, 1992): Different activities are associated with different inherent rates of innovation, productivity growth. Liberalization changes to pattern of specialization, may lead to specialization in non-dynamic activities. What follows is very low-tech, more analytical narrative than definitive analysis. The hope is that it stimulates more in-depth research into the Mexican and similar cases. No attempt to separate effects of NAFTA, peso devaluation, lingering effects of 1980s liberalization. All probably point in same direction.

Sectoral Shifts and Innovation Old-fashioned idea (Prebisch, 1950; Matsuyama, 1992): Different activities are associated with different inherent rates of innovation, productivity growth. Liberalization changes to pattern of specialization, may lead to specialization in non-dynamic activities. What follows is very low-tech, more analytical narrative than definitive analysis. The hope is that it stimulates more in-depth research into the Mexican and similar cases. No attempt to separate effects of NAFTA, peso devaluation, lingering effects of 1980s liberalization. All probably point in same direction. More details on my website (text of a talk I gave in Monterrey, published in Boletin Informativo Techint.)

Employment Growth vs. Skill Intensity, 1988-1998 change in log(employment), 1988 1998 1.5 1.5 0.5 1 1.5 2 Apparel & textile prod. Transportation equip. Electrical/electronic prod. Other 4 digit NAICS industries 0.1.2.3.4.5.6 Share >=12 yrs education (in large plants), 1998 Notes: Data on employment growth are from the INEGI Economic Censuses from 1989 and 1999 (containing information from previous year). Data on schooling are from 1999 ENESTyC. Each symbol represents a 4-digit industry in the North American Industrial Classification System (NAICS). The size of the symbols reflect employment in the industry in 1998. The fitted regression line is weighted by employment in 1998. See Figure A1 of Verhoogen (2008).

Employment Growth vs. Capital Intensity, 1988-1998 change in log(employment), 1988 1998 1.5 1.5 0.5 1 1.5 2 Apparel & textile prod. Transportation equip. Electrical/electronic prod. Other 4 digit NAICS industries 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 log capital labor ratio, 1998 Notes: Data on employment growth and capital-labor ratio are from the INEGI Economic Censuses from 1989 and 1999 (containing information from previous year). Each symbol represents a 4-digit industry in the North American Industrial Classification System (NAICS). The size of the symbols reflect employment in the industry in 1998. The fitted regression line is weighted by employment in 1998. A similar graph (using a different industry classification) appeared as Figure A2 of Verhoogen (2008).

Employment Growth vs. Skill Intensity, 1998-2008 change in log(employment), 1998 2008 1.5 1.5 0.5 1 1.5 2 Apparel & textile prod. Transportation equip. Electrical/electronic prod. Other 4 digit NAICS industries 0.1.2.3.4.5.6 Share >=12 yrs education (in large plants), 1998 Notes: Data on employment growth are from the INEGI Economic Censuses from 1989 and 1999 (containing information from previous year). Data on schooling are from 1999 ENESTyC. Each symbol represents a 4-digit industry in the North American Industrial Classification System (NAICS). The size of the symbols reflect employment in the industry in 1998. The fitted regression line is weighted by employment in 1998.

Employment Growth vs. Capital Intensity, 1998-2008 change in log(employment), 1998 2008 1.5 1.5 0.5 1 1.5 2 Apparel & textile prod. Transportation equip. Electrical/electronic prod. Other 4 digit NAICS industries 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 log capital labor ratio, 1998 Notes: Data on employment growth are from the INEGI Economic Censuses from 1989 and 1999 (containing information from previous year). Data on schooling are from 1999 ENESTyC. Each symbol represents a 4-digit industry in the North American Industrial Classification System (NAICS). The size of the symbols reflect employment in the industry in 1998. The fitted regression line is weighted by employment in 1998.

Maquiladora and Total Industry Employment Apparel Electrical and Electronic Equipment Employment (thousands) 0 200 400 600 all NAICS 315 maquiladoras Employment (thousands) 0 200 400 600 All NAICS 334 and 335 maquiladoras 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Transportation Equipment Employment (thousands) 0 200 400 600 All NAICS 336 maquiladoras 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Notes: Maquiladora employment from EMIME for 1988-2006; total industry employment from Economic Censuses of 1989, 1994, 1999, 2004, and 2009. Apparel and textile products (maquila group 2) mapped to NAICS 315 (apparel manufacturing); transportation equipment (maquila group 6) to NAICS 336 (transportation equipment manufacturing); electrical and electronic equipment (maquila groups 8 and 9) to NAICS 334 and 335 (computer and electronic equipment; and electrical equipment, appliances, and components).

Means by Sub-Sector: Apparel, Elect. & Trans. Equip. non-maquiladoras non-exporters exporters maquiladoras (1) (2) (3) Employment 315.43 438.97 969.67 (8.23) (11.07) (30.02) Export percentage of sales 30.81 96.52 (0.72) (0.63) Foreign ownership indicator 0.08 0.29 0.84 (0.01) (0.01) (0.02) Capital-labor ratio 254.26 309.07 54.87 (19.11) (14.45) (7.18) Share with >= 12 years schooling 0.28 0.32 0.19 (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) Percentage blue-collar 70.18 70.75 83.04 (0.56) (0.46) (0.63) Years of schooling, blue-collar 7.86 8.15 7.37 (0.04) (0.04) (0.06) Blue-collar hourly wage 3.59 3.92 3.83 (0.06) (0.05) (0.10) White-collar hourly wage 7.45 9.32 9.33 (0.14) (0.15) (0.27) Turnover rate 41.47 40.54 72.37 (1.22) (1.06) (2.66) Tenure (years) 6.25 6.59 3.53 (0.09) (0.08) (0.08) N 1423 1774 557 Notes: Standard errors of means in parentheses. Sample is plants with 100 employees in 1999 ENESTyC. Capital-labor ratio measured in thousands of 1998 pesos; blue-collar and white-collar hourly wage in 1998 pesos. Average 1998 nominal exchange rate: 9.1 pesos/dollar. Apparel Transport Equip. Electronics

The Story So Far From 1988-1998, manufacturing sector specialized in less capital- and skill-intensive activities, both across sectors and within sectors (i.e. to maquilas).

The Story So Far From 1988-1998, manufacturing sector specialized in less capital- and skill-intensive activities, both across sectors and within sectors (i.e. to maquilas). From 1998-2008, these sectors/subsectors tended to stagnate.

Role of China A common explanation: Mexico had bad luck. Just as Mexico was poised to grow, China entered. China had similar pattern of specialization in exports to U.S.

Role of China A common explanation: Mexico had bad luck. Just as Mexico was poised to grow, China entered. China had similar pattern of specialization in exports to U.S. There is definitely evidence to support the China story: Utar and Torres Ruiz (2013) yesterday. Kumler (2014): applies approach of Autor, Dorn and Hanson (2013) in Mexico. Lopez Cordova, Micco and Molina (2008), Hanson and Robertson (2010), Hsieh and Ossa (2011). China-Mexico export similarity US import shares

Role of China A common explanation: Mexico had bad luck. Just as Mexico was poised to grow, China entered. China had similar pattern of specialization in exports to U.S. There is definitely evidence to support the China story: Utar and Torres Ruiz (2013) yesterday. Kumler (2014): applies approach of Autor, Dorn and Hanson (2013) in Mexico. Lopez Cordova, Micco and Molina (2008), Hanson and Robertson (2010), Hsieh and Ossa (2011). China-Mexico export similarity US import shares But here I would like to argue that China is not the whole story, that Mexico would have had problems even if China had not entered.

R&D Measure, ENESTyC 1999 Survey asked: Since 1997, has the establishment undertaken R&D? (If yes) What did the R&D principally consist of? Design of new products Process improvements Product quality improvements Design/Improvement/Manufacture of machinery or equipment Other N.B.: This is a broad, inclusive definition of R&D, not just patents. Not perfect, but not bad as a first pass. Code as 0/1.

R&D Intensity vs Skill Intensity, 1998 Share of plants performing R&D, 1998 0.5 1 Apparel & textile prod. Transportation equip. Electrical/electronic prod. Other 4 digit NAICS industries 0.1.2.3.4.5.6 Share >= 12 years schooling, 1998 Notes: Size of plotting symbols reflects employment in industry. The fitted regression line is weighted by employment. The estimated slope is 0.53 with standard error 0.13; the R 2 is 0.16. Industry-level averages are for large plants ( 100 employees).

R&D Intensity vs Capital Intensity, 1998 Share of plants performing R&D, 1998 0.5 1 Apparel & textile prod. Transportation equip. Electrical/electronic prod. Other 4 digit NAICS industries 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 log capital labor ratio, 1998 Notes: Size of plotting symbols reflects employment in industry. The fitted regression line is weighted by employment. The estimated slope is 0.05 with standard error 0.01; the R 2 is 0.14. Industry-level averages are for large plants ( 100 employees).

R&D Intensity by Sector non-maquiladoras non-exporters exporters maquiladoras (1) (2) (3) All manufacturing 0.36 0.50 0.41 (0.01) (0.01) (0.02) Apparel 0.19 0.33 0.34 (0.03) (0.04) (0.05) Electrical and Electronic Products 0.35 0.54 0.45 (0.07) (0.04) (0.03) Transportation Equipment 0.40 0.62 0.54 (0.07) (0.04) (0.10) Source: ENESTyC 1999.

INNOVATION IN MEXICO: NAFTA IS NOT ENOUGH 251 Alternative Innovation Measure I: Patents per Capita Figure 6.2 Patents per Million Workers, 1960 2000 4.5 4.0 3.5 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0 450 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 1960s Latin America and the Caribbean Mexico 1960s 1970s 1970s 1980s 1980s 1990 94 1990 94 1995 2000 1995 2000 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 1960s 1960s 1970s East Asia 1970s 1980s 1990 94 Republic of Korea 1980s 1990 94 United States Canada High-income countries 1995 2000 1995 2000 Source: U.S. Office of Patents and Trademarks. Notes: From Lederman, Maloney and Servén (2005), based on data from the U.S. Office of Patents and Trademarks. global and long time coverage, and especially because it is commonly understood that the United States offers perhaps the most advanced lev-

Alternative Innovation Measure II: R&D Spending/GDP Country R&D spending/gdp (%) Mexico.38 Chile.65 China.65 Korea 2.34 U.S. 2.59 Canada 1.76 Notes: Data from World Bank World Development Indicators for 1998.

Summary Integration led Mexico to specialize in less capital- and skill-intensive activities, both across and within sectors.

Summary Integration led Mexico to specialize in less capital- and skill-intensive activities, both across and within sectors. These sectors that Mexico tended to be less innovative. This did not have to be true. But the correlation appears quite robust.

Summary Integration led Mexico to specialize in less capital- and skill-intensive activities, both across and within sectors. These sectors that Mexico tended to be less innovative. This did not have to be true. But the correlation appears quite robust. The sectoral shifts thus tended to dampen the overall rate of innovation in the economy.

Summary Integration led Mexico to specialize in less capital- and skill-intensive activities, both across and within sectors. These sectors that Mexico tended to be less innovative. This did not have to be true. But the correlation appears quite robust. The sectoral shifts thus tended to dampen the overall rate of innovation in the economy. What if China had not entered? We don t observe the counterfactual, but my sense is that there would always be another country moving up the product ladder Malaysia, Thailand, Indonesia, Vietnam,...

Further Thoughts More research is needed, needless to say.

Further Thoughts More research is needed, needless to say. But patterns suggest that there may be a trade-off between static allocative efficiency and long-term productivity growth. Liberalization alone may not to be enough to bring about sustained growth.

Further Thoughts More research is needed, needless to say. But patterns suggest that there may be a trade-off between static allocative efficiency and long-term productivity growth. Liberalization alone may not to be enough to bring about sustained growth. My own view is that policy-makers should consider interventions to promote the sorts of activities that generate innovation and productivity growth. This argument relies on the idea that innovation generates positive externalities, which I am exploring empirically in other work with co-authors (Atkin et al., 2014)

Further Thoughts (cont.) I do not want to argue that such interventions need to happen at the border, in the form of tariffs or other trade barriers.

Further Thoughts (cont.) I do not want to argue that such interventions need to happen at the border, in the form of tariffs or other trade barriers. And it is true that governments have no special knowledge about which sectors/firms/ideas/technologies are going to be successful in the future.

Further Thoughts (cont.) I do not want to argue that such interventions need to happen at the border, in the form of tariffs or other trade barriers. And it is true that governments have no special knowledge about which sectors/firms/ideas/technologies are going to be successful in the future. But I think there is a strong case for policies that provide broad-based (sometimes called horizontal (Lederman and Maloney, 2012)) support for innovative activities.

References I Arias, Javier, Oliver Azuara, Pedro Bernal, James J. Heckman, and Cajeme Villarreal, Policies To Promote Growth and Economic Efficiency in Mexico, 2010. NBER working paper no. 16554. Atkin, David, Azam Chaudhry, Shamyla Chaudry, Amit K. Khandelwal, and, Organizational Barriers to Technology Adoption: Evidence from Soccer-Ball Producers in Pakistan, 2014. Mimeo, Columbia University. Autor, David H., David Dorn, and Gordon H. Hanson, The China Syndrome: Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States, American Economic Review, 2013, 103 (6), 2121 68. De Hoyos, Rafael E. and Leonardo Iacovone, Economic Performance under NAFTA: A Firm-Level Analysis of the Trade-productivity Linkages, World Development, 2013, 44 (0), 180 193. De la Cruz, Justino, David Riker, and Bennet Voorhees, Econometric Estimates of the Effects of NAFTA: A Review of the Literature, 2013. U.S. International Trade Commission Office of Economics Working Paper 2013-12A, Dec. Devlin, Robert, Antoni Estevadeordal, and Andres Rodriguez-Clare, The Emergence of China: Challenges and Opportunities for Latin America and the Carribean, Harvard University Press, 2006. Haber, Stephen, Why Institutions Matter: Banking and Economic Growth in Mexico, 2004. Stanford Center for International Development working paper no. 234. Hanson, Gordon H., Why Isn t Mexico Rich?., Journal of Economic Literature, 2010, 48 (4), 987 1004. and Raymond Robertson, China and the Manufacturing Exports of Other Developing Countries, in China s Growing Role in World Trade, NBER Conference Report series. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press, 2010, pp. 137 159.

References II Hsieh, Chang-Tai and Ralph Ossa, A Global View of Productivity Growth in China, 2011. NBER working paper no. 16778. Iacovone, Leonardo, The better you are the stronger it makes you: Evidence on the asymmetric impact of liberalization, Journal of Development Economics, 2012, 99 (2), 474 485. Kehoe, Timothy J., An Evaluation of the Performance of Applied General Equilibrium Models of the Impact of NAFTA, in Timothy J. Kehoe, T. N. Srinivasan, and John Whalley, eds., Frontiers in Applied General Equilibrium Modeling: In Honor of Herbert Scarf, Cambridge University Press, 2005. and Kim J. Ruhl, Why Have Economic Reforms in Mexico Not Generated Growth?., Journal of Economic Literature, 2010, 48 (4), 1005 1027. Krueger, Anne, NAFTA s Effects: A Preliminary Assessment, World Economy, June 2000, 23 (6), 761 75. Kumler, Todd, Chinese Competition and Mexican Labor Markets, 2014. Unpub. paper, Columbia University. Lederman, Daniel and William Maloney, Does What You Export Matter? In Search of Empirical Guidance for Industrial Policies, Washington DC: The World Bank, 2012.,, and Luis Servén, Lessons from NAFTA for Latin America and the Caribbean, Stanford CA: Stanford University Press, 2005. Levy, Santiago, Good Intentions, Bad Outcomes: Social Policy, Informality and Economic Growth in Mexico, Brookings Institution Press, Washington D.C., 2008. Lopez Cordova, Ernesto, NAFTA and Manufacturing Productivity in Mexico, Economia: Journal of the Latin American and Caribbean Economic Association, 2003, 4 (1), 55 88.

References III, Alejandro Micco, and Danielken Molina, How Sensitive Are Latin American Exports to Chinese Competition in the U.S. Market?, Economia: Journal of the Latin American and Caribbean Economic Association, 2008, 8 (2), 117. Matsuyama, Kiminori, Agricultural Productivity, Comparative Advantage, and Economic Growth, Journal of Economic Theory, 1992, 58. Olley, G. Steven and Ariel Pakes, The Dynamics of Productivity in the Telecommunications Industry, Econometrica, 1996, 64 (6), 1263 1297. Prebisch, Raul, The Economic Development of Latin America and its Principal Problems, 1950. New York: United Nations, Reprinted in Economic Bulletin for Latin America in 1962. Utar, Hale and Luis B. Torres Ruiz, International Competition and Industrial Evolution: Evidence from the Impact of Chinese Competition on Mexican Maquiladoras, Journal of Development Economics, 2013, 105, 267 287. Verhoogen, Eric, Trade, Quality Upgrading and Wage Inequality in the Mexican Manufacturing Sector, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2008, 123 (2), 489 530.

Means by Sub-Sector: Apparel non-maquiladoras non-exporters exporters maquiladoras (1) (2) (3) Employment 260.19 460.66 813.88 (17.90) (39.51) (57.79) Export percentage of sales 46.93 97.40 (3.53) (1.13) Foreign ownership indicator 0.02 0.05 0.60 (0.01) (0.02) (0.05) Capital-labor ratio 64.96 48.38 28.90 (29.22) (8.87) (7.56) Share with >= 12 years schooling 0.15 0.18 0.14 (0.02) (0.02) (0.01) Percentage blue-collar 84.66 82.91 88.48 (1.62) (1.46) (1.18) Years of schooling, blue-collar 7.25 7.40 7.21 (0.16) (0.14) (0.14) Blue-collar hourly wage 2.34 2.43 3.03 (0.13) (0.11) (0.17) White-collar hourly wage 5.50 6.38 6.84 (0.44) (0.55) (0.50) Turnover rate 55.17 60.19 60.20 (4.51) (5.44) (4.90) Tenure (years) 4.91 4.45 3.29 (0.31) (0.29) (0.16) N 112 105 111 Notes: Standard errors of means in parentheses. Sample is plants with 100 employees in 1999 ENESTyC. Capital-labor ratio measured in thousands of 1998 pesos; blue-collar and white-collar hourly wage in 1998 pesos. Average 1998 nominal exchange rate: 9.1 pesos/dollar. Return

Means by Sub-Sector: Transportation Equipment non-maquiladoras non-exporters exporters maquiladoras (1) (2) (3) Employment 344.24 637.01 1342.07 (46.90) (52.91) (82.97) Export percentage of sales 41.32 96.33 (2.68) (1.28) Foreign ownership indicator 0.28 0.49 0.97 (0.07) (0.04) (0.02) Capital-labor ratio 212.92 294.49 57.30 (90.57) (46.77) (22.49) Share with >= 12 years schooling 0.27 0.34 0.20 (0.02) (0.02) (0.01) Percentage blue-collar 75.35 73.40 84.29 (1.89) (1.01) (1.48) Years of schooling, blue-collar 7.79 8.60 7.43 (0.19) (0.12) (0.14) Blue-collar hourly wage 3.55 4.73 3.64 (0.26) (0.22) (0.19) White-collar hourly wage 7.24 11.17 9.81 (0.61) (0.52) (0.65) Turnover rate 45.99 33.11 69.47 (7.59) (3.18) (6.74) Tenure (years) 5.37 6.88 3.74 (0.34) (0.28) (0.20) N 46 141 92 Notes: Standard errors of means in parentheses. Sample is plants with 100 employees in 1999 ENESTyC. Capital-labor ratio measured in thousands of 1998 pesos; blue-collar and white-collar hourly wage in 1998 pesos. Average 1998 nominal exchange rate: 9.1 pesos/dollar. Return

Means by Sub-Sector: Electrical/Electronic Equipment non-maquiladoras non-exporters exporters maquiladoras (1) (2) (3) Employment 334.83 585.75 1081.90 (105.70) (56.59) (51.35) Export percentage of sales 39.94 98.24 (3.33) (0.78) Foreign ownership indicator 0.25 0.52 0.92 (0.09) (0.05) (0.02) Capital-labor ratio 132.03 223.10 68.35 (74.50) (26.16) (14.69) Share with >= 12 years schooling 0.29 0.31 0.22 (0.04) (0.02) (0.01) Percentage blue-collar 73.35 71.88 80.79 (3.56) (1.57) (1.06) Years of schooling, blue-collar 8.03 8.52 7.54 (0.27) (0.12) (0.09) Blue-collar hourly wage 3.04 3.84 4.15 (0.25) (0.17) (0.17) White-collar hourly wage 8.74 10.17 10.82 (1.00) (0.53) (0.48) Turnover rate 39.68 41.19 73.60 (5.52) (4.09) (4.56) Tenure (years) 6.18 6.21 3.50 (0.64) (0.29) (0.12) N 24 109 191 Notes: Standard errors of means in parentheses. Sample is plants with 100 employees in 1999 ENESTyC. Capital-labor ratio measured in thousands of 1998 pesos; blue-collar and white-collar hourly wage in 1998 pesos. Average 1998 nominal exchange rate: 9.1 pesos/dollar. Return

US Import Shares from China, Mexico Hanson: Why Isn t Mexico Rich? 1001 0.1 Mexico China 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 Year Source: Hanson (2010). Return Figure 2: Share of U.S. Manufacturing Imports comparative advantage in another third of its products (including automobiles and auto parts, industrial machinery, and beverages). (2010) take a more theoretical approach, introducing Ricardian productivity differences into a Marc J. Melitz (2003) model

The increasing similarity between the Chinese and Latin America export baskets is not unlike the Introductiongrowth in the similarity Existing between Approaches East Asia (China excluded) Sectoral and Latin Shifts America. and Figure Innovation 5.2 shows the Conclusion ESI values between selected Latin American countries and regions and East Asia. The similarity of exports between Latin America (particularly Brazil and Mexico) and East Asian economies was relatively pronounced in the early-1990s; this similarity has increased during the same period, Export particularly Similarity for Mexico and between Latin America as a whole. Mexico and China 6 Figure 5.2 Export Similarity between Selected Latin American Countries and East Asia in the US Market, 1992-2002 45 40 35 30 Percent 25 20 15 10 5 0 Latin America Argentina Brazil Chile Colombia Mexico Central America 1992 1995 2000 2002 Source: IDB-INT calculations based on UN/Comtrade data. Within manufacturing product categories, moreover, China s export prices (measured in unit Source: values) Devlin, are generally Estevadeordal lower and than Rodriguez-Clare the prices received (2006). by other developing economies in Latin America Return and Asia. The premium received by those countries over China is highest in machinery and lowest in apparel. One explanation for this differential is that products from those regions offer higher quality or have more attributes than products from China, thereby raising their value. This would be consistent with differences in comparative advantage: countries that are relatively abundant in human NAFTA and and Mexican physical Industrial capital can Development improve quality or add product features. A competing explanation is that the