Gender Gap of Immigrant Groups in the United States

Similar documents
Refugee Versus Economic Immigrant Labor Market Assimilation in the United States: A Case Study of Vietnamese Refugees

The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians

Returns from Self-Employment: Using Human Capital Theory to Compare U.S. Natives and Immigrants

CLACLS. A Profile of Latino Citizenship in the United States: Demographic, Educational and Economic Trends between 1990 and 2013

Mexicans in New York City, : A Visual Data Base

Economic assimilation of Mexican and Chinese immigrants in the United States: is there wage convergence?

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

English Language Proficiency and Wage Rates of Mexican Immigrants

Returns to Education in the Albanian Labor Market

IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY

POLICY Volume 5, Issue 8 October RETHINKING THE EFFECTS OF IMMIGRATION ON WAGES: New Data and Analysis from by Giovanni Peri, Ph.D.

Since 1965, the US has seen increasingly large

The Effect of Niche Occupations on Standard of Living: A Closer Look at Chinese, Filipino, and Asian Indian Immigrants

The Latino Population of New York City, 2008

Peruvians in the United States

Immigrant Employment and Earnings Growth in Canada and the U.S.: Evidence from Longitudinal data

A Profile of Latina Women in New York City, 2007

Transferability of Skills, Income Growth and Labor Market Outcomes of Recent Immigrants in the United States. Karla Diaz Hadzisadikovic*

Second Generation Educational Attainment

DETERMINANTS OF INTERNAL MIGRATION IN PAKISTAN

Dominicans in New York City

Labor Force patterns of Mexican women in Mexico and United States. What changes and what remains?

REMITTANCE TRANSFERS TO ARMENIA: PRELIMINARY SURVEY DATA ANALYSIS

CLACLS. Demographic, Economic, and Social Transformations in Bronx Community District 5:

Labor Market Performance of Immigrants in Early Twentieth-Century America

Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia. Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware. and

Gender Variations in the Socioeconomic Attainment of Immigrants in Canada

The Effects of Political and Demographic Variables on Christian Coalition Scores

WHO MIGRATES? SELECTIVITY IN MIGRATION

Latin American Immigration in the United States: Is There Wage Assimilation Across the Wage Distribution?

Fertility Rates among Mexicans in Traditional And New States of Settlement, 2006

Permanent Disadvantage or Gradual Integration: Explaining the Immigrant-Native Earnings Gap in Sweden

Demographic, Economic and Social Transformations in Bronx Community District 4: High Bridge, Concourse and Mount Eden,

Cons. Pros. University of Connecticut, USA, and IZA, Germany. Keywords: immigration, female labor supply, fertility, childcare, time use

DOES POST-MIGRATION EDUCATION IMPROVE LABOUR MARKET PERFORMANCE?: Finding from Four Cities in Indonesia i

DATA PROFILES OF IMMIGRANTS IN THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA

Pulling Open the Sticky Door

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Abstract/Policy Abstract

PROJECTING THE LABOUR SUPPLY TO 2024

Latino Voter Registration and Participation Rates in the November 2016 Presidential Election

Educational Attainment: Analysis by Immigrant Generation

5. Destination Consumption

Characteristics of the Ethnographic Sample of First- and Second-Generation Latin American Immigrants in the New York to Philadelphia Urban Corridor

Demographic, Economic, and Social Transformations in Queens Community District 3: East Elmhurst, Jackson Heights, and North Corona,

Rev. soc. polit., god. 25, br. 3, str , Zagreb 2018.

The Demography of the Labor Force in Emerging Markets

Does Immigration Reduce Wages?

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Illegal Immigration. When a Mexican worker leaves Mexico and moves to the US he is emigrating from Mexico and immigrating to the US.

Extrapolated Versus Actual Rates of Violent Crime, California and the United States, from a 1992 Vantage Point

The Economic Impact of Crimes In The United States: A Statistical Analysis on Education, Unemployment And Poverty

United States House Elections Post-Citizens United: The Influence of Unbridled Spending

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

to the United States:

The Effects of Immigration on Age Structure and Fertility in the United States

Explaining the 40 Year Old Wage Differential: Race and Gender in the United States

Demographic, Economic, and Social Transformations in Brooklyn Community District 4: Bushwick,

The Employment of Low-Skilled Immigrant Men in the United States

Residential segregation and socioeconomic outcomes When did ghettos go bad?

LATINO DATA PROJECT. Astrid S. Rodríguez Ph.D. Candidate, Educational Psychology. Center for Latin American, Caribbean, and Latino Studies

Copyright subsists in all papers and content posted on this site.

THE ENGLISH LANGUAGE FLUENCY AND OCCUPATIONAL SUCCESS OF ETHNIC MINORITY IMMIGRANT MEN LIVING IN ENGLISH METROPOLITAN AREAS

Employment Rate Gaps between Immigrants and Non-immigrants in. Canada in the Last Three Decades

Are Refugees Different from Economic Immigrants? Some Empirical Evidence on the Heterogeneity of Immigrant Groups in the U.S.

The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices

THE EFFECT OF EARLY VOTING AND THE LENGTH OF EARLY VOTING ON VOTER TURNOUT

The Immigrant Double Disadvantage among Blacks in the United States. Katharine M. Donato Anna Jacobs Brittany Hearne

Language Proficiency and Earnings of Non-Official Language. Mother Tongue Immigrants: The Case of Toronto, Montreal and Quebec City

A Gravitational Model of Crime Flows in Normal, Illinois:

High Technology Agglomeration and Gender Inequalities

Over the past three decades, the share of middle-skill jobs in the

Astrid S. Rodríguez Fellow, Center for Latin American, Caribbean & Latino Studies. Center for Latin American, Caribbean & Latino Studies

Occupational Choice of High Skilled Immigrants in the United States

EFFECTS OF ONTARIO S IMMIGRATION POLICY ON YOUNG NON- PERMANENT RESIDENTS BETWEEN 2001 AND Lu Lin

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

Determinants of Violent Crime in the U.S: Evidence from State Level Data

SIMPLE LINEAR REGRESSION OF CPS DATA

APPENDIX H. Success of Businesses in the Dane County Construction Industry

Chapter One: people & demographics

Ecuadorians in the United States

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach

Emigrating Israeli Families Identification Using Official Israeli Databases

The Economics of Crime: An Analysis of Crime Rates in America

A Study of the Earning Profiles of Young and Second Generation Immigrants in Canada by Tianhui Xu ( )

The Labor Market Status of Foreign Born Vietnamese Americans

3.3 DETERMINANTS OF THE CULTURAL INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS

Earnings Inequality and the Gender Wage Gap. in U.S. Metropolitan Areas. Zsuzsa Daczó

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, SELF-SELECTION, AND THE DISTRIBUTION OF WAGES: EVIDENCE FROM MEXICO AND THE UNITED STATES

The Impact of Licensing Decentralization on Firm Location Choice: the Case of Indonesia

Executive summary. Strong records of economic growth in the Asia-Pacific region have benefited many workers.

Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immigrants

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men

Substitution Between Individual and Cultural Capital: Pre-Migration Labor Supply, Culture and US Labor Market Outcomes Among Immigrant Woman

The Labour Market Performance of Immigrant and. Canadian-born Workers by Age Groups. By Yulong Hou ( )

THE ROLE OF INFORMATION PROCESSING SKILLS IN DETERMINING THE GENDER AND LINGUISTIC WAGE GAP IN ESTONIA

A Note on International Migrants Savings and Incomes

Transcription:

The Park Place Economist Volume 11 Issue 1 Article 14 2003 Gender Gap of Immigrant Groups in the United States Desislava Hristova '03 Illinois Wesleyan University Recommended Citation Hristova '03, Desislava (2003) "Gender Gap of Immigrant Groups in the United States," The Park Place Economist: Vol. 11 Available at: http://digitalcommons.iwu.edu/parkplace/vol11/iss1/14 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by The Ames Library, the Andrew W. Mellon Center for Curricular and Faculty Development, the Office of the Provost and the Office of the President. It has been accepted for inclusion in Digital Commons @ IWU by the faculty at Illinois Wesleyan University. For more information, please contact digitalcommons@iwu.edu. Copyright is owned by the author of this document.

Gender Gap of Immigrant Groups in the United States Abstract The purpose of this paper is to explore the determinants of the gender gaps in the U.S. of immigrant groups from different countries. More specifically, the purpose of this paper is two-folded. First, it will explore how in theory the social norms in the country of origin determine the gender gap through two avenues. Second, it will create an empirical model to test the hypotheses generated by the theory. This article is available in The Park Place Economist: http://digitalcommons.iwu.edu/parkplace/vol11/iss1/14

Gender gap of Immigrant groups in the United States Gender Gap of Immigrant Groups in the United States I. Introduction The gender wage gap is a phenomenon that ap pears to persist and prevail in many countries; however, the level of the gender gap is far from uniform from country to country. For example, in 1990 the average wage of a woman working in manufacturing in Brazil was 54% of the average male s wage in that industry, whereas in Myanmar this percentage was 106 (Statistics Division of the United Nations Secretariat, 2000). Moreover, researchers have found evidence that there are statistically significant differences in the gender wage gap across countries (Antecol, 2001). The variation in the gender gap across nations seems to persist even after immigration i.e. immigration groups from different countries exhibit different gender gaps in the same host country. For instance, in 1990 working Syrian female immigrants earn on average 28% of the male working immigrants from the same group, whereas for Russian immigrants this percentage was 100 (Ruggles and Sobek, 1997). To explain the variation of the gender gap across immigrant groups from different countries after they arrive in the U.S., we need to explore the determinants of the gender gap in general. This paper will argue that the gender gap of an immigrant group in the U.S. is determined mainly by social norms in the country of origin. In addition, it will also be argued that the effect of social norms takes place through two avenues. First, social norms determine the investments in formal education, which is an important determinant of earnings. Furthermore, social norms determine the pattern of participation in the labor market, the family structure and the choice of a field of work. Immigrant Groups from different Countries exhibit different gender gaps in the same host country Desislava Hristova The purpose of this paper is to explore the determinants of the gender gaps in the U.S. of immigrant groups from different countries. More specifically, the purpose of this paper is two-folded. First, it will explore how in theory the social norms in the country of origin determine the gender gap through two avenues. Second, it will create an empirical model to test the hypotheses generated by the theory. The rest of this paper is organized as follows. The next section will describe the theory relevant to the subject of gender gap and discuss how it relates to immigrant groups in particular. Section III will describe the hypotheses generated by the theory and the empirical model that will be used to test the hypotheses. Section IV presents the results of the test and discusses those results in the context of the theory. Section V will draw conclusions and expand on the policy implications that follow from the results. II. Theory and Literature Review As mentioned earlier, two main avenues through which social norms in the country of origin influence the gender gap will be discussed in this paper. First, this section will discuss the effect that takes place through formal education investment decisions. Then, other possible ways in which social norms can reflect on the gender gap will be considered. Effect of Country-of-Origin Gender Norms Through Formal Education One of the avenues through which the social norms affect the gender gap is through the choice of investment in formal education. By investigating the theoretical connection between societal values and personal preferences we will draw conclusions about The Park Place Economist Volume XI 37

the gender gap of immigrant groups. A simple supply and demand model can explain why higher levels of human capital, and formal education in particular, generally earn higher rewards. The accumulation of formal education one type of human capital increases the productivity of a worker. It is widely accepted that the relationship between education and earnings is significant (Chiswick, 1978). Since under competitive assumptions the marginal productivity of the worker is equal to the worker s wage, higher levels of formal education in general translate into higher earnings. The payoff of each dollar spent on education is on average between 1.05 and 1.15 dollars (Psacharopoulos, 1985). However, the acquisition of formal education comes only at the expense of direct costs, forgone earnings and leisure. For example, the cost of a college degree is comprised of tuition costs, and the opportunity costs of the time spent in school rather than in the labor market or at leisure (Parsons, 1974). Thus, economists often perceive accumulation of formal education as an investment that will yield returns in terms of higher wages (Parsons, 1974; Sicilian and Grossberg, 2001; Khan, 1997). Assuming that people are rational, the investment in formal education will depend on the payoff of the investment; more specifically, a person will choose a level of investment that maximizes her gains. This is Desislava Hristova the main idea behind the human capital theory. We will consider a specific type of formal education investment college education. Let an individual be considering whether to pursue a college degree; this decision is discrete rather than continuous and the problem of maximization is simply a problem of choosing the better of two options. Figure 1 shows the costs and benefits that one has to take into consideration when deciding whether or not to obtain a college degree (Blau, 2002). Both the college graduate and high school graduate s earnings increase with experience; however, the college graduate s earnings increase faster than do the high school graduate s as the higher qualifications of the college graduate allows her to benefit more from on the job training. Thus, the person making the decision will choose to invest in a college degree if the present value of the benefits is greater than the present value of the sum of the indirect and direct costs. However, if the person making the decision expects to interrupt her career for caring for children, then the benefits of the degree change as shown in Figure 2. The new benefit consists of only the highlighted parts of the graph. While the woman is out of the labor market her wage does not increase. Moreover, when the woman interrupts her career, her experience before the interruption matters less than if there was no interruption. Thus, when a woman goes Figure 1 The costs and benefits of a college degree. (Blau, 2002) Benefits College Graduate Earnings Opportunity cost High school Graduate Explicit Cost Experience 38 The Park Place Economist Volume XI

Gender gap of Immigrant groups in the United States back to work after the interruption, she has to start at a lower salary than the one at which she left (Blau, 2002). Thus, the personal preference to interrupt her career decreases the worker s payoff of obtaining a college degree and makes it less likely that she will choose to pursue higher education. If this preference is shared by women in a certain country, but not by the men in the country, then we will observe a gender formal education gap. In fact, gender norms in a country affect such preferences. There are several reasons to believe that this is true. For example, in a society in which women hold relatively disadvantaged position in the labor market the lack of same-sex role models of the same nationality might increase the perceived discrimination and the statistical discrimination. Women will then be discouraged from participating consistently in the labor market. Second, in a society in which women are expected to participate less than men in the labor market, there might be higher costs such as social disapproval for women than for men of labor force participation. Human capital, and formal education in particular, can be thought of as a stock of income-producing skill and knowledge that is acquired through a flow of investment over an individual s lifetime. When a worker chooses to immigrate, they carry with themselves human capital baggage. Moreover, the level of formal education accumulation can in fact be predicted to be fixed in the short run for older immigrants. One reason is that once formal education is accumulated, the cost is usually sunk. Although formal education eventually wears out (by forgetting) and becomes obsolete, it is fixed in the short run. Moreover, additional accumulation of human capital requires both significant preliminary planning, as well as time and funds. For younger immigrants with less experience in the work force and less formal education the opportunity cost of the time spent in school will be lower and they will be more likely to pursue more education. For older immigrants however, the opportunity cost is higher and their formal educational attainment is likely to be fixed in the short run. Additionally, one might find it more difficult to borrow during the educational investment period (Parsons, 1974). Immigrants may experience even greater difficulty in financing their education as they often have a less established credit history and since they often spend a significant amount of money to immigrate. Such difficulties will additionally make older immigrants formal education fixed and thus, human capital gender gaps would carry over as the immigrants enter the U.S. To summarize, gender norms can affect the immigrant group gender gap in the U.S. by affecting the accumulation of formal education. The reason to Figure 2: The costs and benefits of a college degree when there is an interruption in the career. (Blau, 2002) Benefits Earnings Benefits to college graduate with interruption Opportunity cost Explicit Cost Onset of break in career End of break in career Experience The Park Place Economist Volume XI 39

40 believe that formal education gap will carry on to the new society is that formal education is fixed in the short run. Having considered how gender norms in the country of origin of the immigrants affect the gender gap in the U.S. through formal education, we will now explore other avenues through which the social norms affect the gender gap. Effect of Country-of-Origin Gender Norms Through Non-Formal-Education Avenues Family Labor Division One avenue through which the gender norms in the country of origin can affect the gender gap of the group in the U.S. is family structure. If women arrive in the new country with their family, the Cournot- Nash model of family decision making (Chen and Woolley, 2001) predicts that their decisions of whether to pursue an uninterrupted career might be taken by the family as the deciding unit rather than by the woman as an individual. Even though individuals within the family attempt to maximize their own utility, they are interdependent because they care about each other and because they share assets (e.g. housing) and responsibilities (e.g. child care) (Chen and Woolley, 2001). Thus, decisions concerning labor division are likely to be taken by the family as the deciding unit. If there is a preexisting division of labor within the family before immigration, this division might persist after immigration even if it is not benefit maximizing for the woman. If the family comes from a society in which the societal model dictates that the woman should devote little time to work outside the home, the inert division of labor within the family will result in inert pseudo-preferences of the woman. Choice of Occupation and Accumulation of Experience in the Country of Origin Economists reason that there is an additional explanation of the gender gap. Wages in technical fields of work are higher than the average and growing (Berman, Bound and Machin, 1998), but women are less likely than men to pursue a mathematics major in college (Weinberger, 1999). In fact, even though women represented 46% of the United States labor force in 1996, they held only 22% of the jobs in mathematics, science or engineering (Hanson, 1996). One possible explanation of this is that individuals who expect that their labor market participation will be interrupted, for child bearing for example, might avoid The Park Place Economist Volume XI Desislava Hristova fields such as science, computer science, engineering, in which change is rapid (Blau, et al, 2002). Thus, if traditional gender roles require that the woman interrupt her career to care for her children, she will be less likely to take on a job in such a field. The choice of a field of work usually requires preliminary planning and is thus less likely to change after immigration. This is an additional reason of why traditional gender roles in the native society can influence the gender gap in the host country (through the women s choice of field of work). Moreover, the work experience of an immigrant depends on the labor force participation in the country of origin. If traditional gender roles in the country of origin require that a woman spend little time in the work force, a woman immigrant will be less likely to have much work experience when she enters the U.S. Since experience is one of the determinants of earnings, a work experience gap will lead to a higher gender gap in the host country. To conclude, the gender norms in the country of origin of the immigrant group affect the gender gap of the group in the U.S. through avenues other than human capital, as well. Namely, gender norms affect the group s gender gap in the U.S. through the inert family structure as well as through carrying choices of field of specialization and work experience obtained in the country of origin. III. Hypotheses and Empirical Model The data used in the empirical section of this work is extracted from the Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (1998), the International Labour Organization Bureau of Statistics (1998-2002), Ruggles and Sobek et. al. (1997), the Statistics Division of the United Nations Secretariat (2000) and the United Nations Children s Fund (1999). The data used is from the years 1980 and 1990. All data is an average for countries or an average for immigrant groups from different countries. As discussed in the previous section, gender norms in the country of origin affect the gender gap in the host country in two ways through formal education accumulation on one hand, and through choice of field, work experience in the country of origin and inert family labor division on the other. This is also illustrated in Figure 3. Thus, the two hypotheses to be tested will be associated with those two avenues. The independent variable, which will measure the gender gap, will be ImmWoMen the average

Gender gap of Immigrant groups in the United States Figure 3: Illustration of the avenues through which gender norms in the country of origin affect the gender gap in the U.S. Formal Education Gender Norms in the Country of Origin Family labor division Gender gap of the immigrant group in the U.S. Choice of Occupation and Experience in the Country of Origin U.S. wage of working women in the immigrant group divided by the average U.S. wage earned by working men in the same group. The data for this variable is extracted from Steven and Mathew Sobek et. al. (1997). The averages are computed only for working individuals so that people who are students, are in a training program, or are retired are excluded. It is important to acknowledge that this might result in a lower gender gap than the real gender gap in earnings (if women participate in the work force less). This is necessary because the theory is based only on cases of individuals who are participating in the labor market. Moreover, the exclusion of non-working individuals is consistent in all other measures. The reason that wages are used rather than total income is that the gender wage gap is of concern especially because men and women earn different wages, not because they receive different incomes as a whole. The theory presented in Section II advocates that one of the factors determining the gender wage Table 1: Determinants of the group gender gap, the proxies used to estimate them and the predicted effect on the gender gap of the immigrant group. Dependent Variable Proxy Symbol used Source Exp. sign 1 - Gender Wage Gap Ratio of working immigrant women's average wage to working immigrant men's average wage Effect of Gender Norms in the Country of Origin to be Captured ImmWoMen Steven and Mathew Sobek et. al. (1997) Through formal education Ratio of working women's immigrant average education rescaled to working immigrant men's EdWoMen Russel and Sobek et. al. (1997) (+) Through the family division of labor, through choice of career and work experience in the source country Ratio of women's to men's average wages in manufacturing in the native country NatWoMen * (+) * Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (1998), International Labour Organization Bureau of Statistics (1998-2002), Statistics Division of the United Nations Secretariat (2000) and United Nations Children s Fund (1999) The Park Place Economist Volume XI 41

42 gap of the immigrant group in the U.S. will be the formal education. The reason that this factor will be significant in explaining the variation of the gender gap across immigrant groups is because any significant human capital gap in the country of origin is expected to persist. As argued in Section II, the lower the formal education gap in the immigrant group, the lower we can expect the gender wage gap to be. This follows simply from the fact that formal education accumulation pays off in terms of higher wages as argued in the previous section. The variable used to measure education will be the recoded education variable from the Ruggles and Sobek et. al. (1997). The recoded education variable depends on the number of grades completed and degrees received rather than on the number of years of study. Thus, the variable takes value 1 for 0 years to kindergarten, 2 for grades 1 through 4, etc. all the way to 9 for a graduate or medical school degree. The variable used to measure the education gap will be EdWoMen the average recoded education for women divided by the average recoded education for men. The higher this ratio, the lower the gender wage capital cap and thus, the higher the ratio of women s average to men s average wage. This way, the expected coefficient associated with EdWoMen is positive. The previous section also concluded that the native gender norms effect consists not only of an effect through formal education but also of an effect through the somewhat rigid family division of labor, gender differences in choice of career and in work experience accumulated in the country of origin. To capture this effect, it is necessary to include a measure of gender norms. A somewhat imperfect measure of the gender norms is the ratio of women s average salaries to men s average wages in the country of origin. More specifically, the proxy chosen NatWoMen will be the ratio of average women s wages in manufacturing to average men s wages in manufacturing in the country of origin. Naturally, NatWoMen is not a perfect measure of the societal gender norms. The reason that manufacturing is chosen is because of data availability and because manufacturing wages depend on experience but little on education. Thus, this measure partly avoids the correlation with EdWoMen. The sources from which the data is extracted will be the Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (1998), International Labour Organization Bureau of Statistics (1998-2002), Statistics Division of the United The Park Place Economist Volume XI Desislava Hristova Nations Secretariat (2000) and United Nations Children s Fund (1999). In this model NatWoMen can be expected to account for the effect of the gender norms other than through formal education. We can expect that the higher the native ratio of women s to men s salaries, the higher the ratio of wages for the immigrant group. Thus, the expected sign of the coefficient associated with the native wage ratio is positive. Therefore, the empirical model will be equation (1) ImmWoMen = A*EdWoMen + B*NatWoMen + C (1) The main hypotheses are that the coefficients A and B are positive and significant. In the next section A and B are estimated through a linear regression and the results are discussed in the context of the hypotheses and the theory presented. IV. Empirical Test and Results The linear least-square regression with ImmWoMen as the dependent variable and EdWoMen and NatWoMen as the independent variables was run. The coefficients that the regression yielded and their significance are described in Table 2. Table 2: Coefficients from the linear regression analysis with dependent variable ImmWoMen. R 2 is 74%. Variable Coefficient t value Significance Constant.272 2.463 018 EdWoMen.346 10.846.000 NatWoMen -.115 -.797.430 The regression explains 74% of the variation of the dependent variable (Adjusted R Square is.74). Thus, the model is relatively successful in explaining the gender wage gaps of immigrant groups. Also, the coefficient of the human capital proxy the education ratio EdWoMen has the expected sign and is highly significant in explaining the wage ratio ImmWoMen of immigrant groups. This means that the gender wage gap is in fact significantly positively correlated with the gender formal education gap. However, NatWoMen is not significant in

Gender gap of Immigrant groups in the United States explaining ImmWoMen. Therefore, possibly, the effect of gender norms through family division of labor and the choice of field of work is not as significant as expected. It is possible that, in reality, the family inert division of labor is less restricting to the individual s profit maximizing decisions than theorized. It is important to mention that not all immigrants immigrate in the U.S. with their families. The effect of gender norms through the field of specialization, on the other hand, might be accounted for by the education variable. The level of education required is higher for a dynamically changing field. Therefore, the human capital gap is highly correlated with the different participation of men and women in the highly dynamic fields. It is also important to note that the measure used for the gender social norms in the country of origin is quite limited. V. Conclusion and Policy Implications The most important finding of this study is that formal education gender gap is a significant determinant of the gender wage gaps of immigrant groups in the U.S. Moreover, when controlling for the formal education gender gap of the group in the U.S., other factors related to the gender norms prove to be insignificant in explaining the gender gap of the immigrant groups in the same host country. It can be concluded that the main determinant of the gender gaps of immigrant groups in the U.S. is the human capital gender gap. Gender gap is usually perceived as an undesirable phenomenon. To facilitate the overcoming of the gender gap the government could facilitate the acquisition of formal education of immigrant women who have switched their preferences towards longer labor market participation but do not have the means to change their formal education accordingly. One incentive system that could achieve this effect would be one that secures easier financing of education for the targeted group. Future studies would benefit from more explicit measures of the gender norms in the country of origin. Two examples of such more specific measures are the size of the average family and the proportion of women who choose dynamically changing fields. Berman, Eli et. al. Implications of Skill-Biased Technological Change: International Evidence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics Nov 1998: 1245-79 Chen, Zhigi and Frances Woolley. A Cournot-Nash Model of Family Decision Making. The Economic Journal Oct 2001: 722-48 Chiswick, Barry R. The Effect of Americanization on the Earnings of Foreign-born Men. Journal of Political Economy 1978: 897-922 Statistical yearbook for Latin America and the Caribbean 1998 Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean, 1998 International Labour Organization Bureau of Statistics LABORSTA, http://laborsta.ilo.org/, International Labour Organization 1998-2002 Khan, Aliya Hashmi. Post-migration Investment in Education by Immigration in the United States. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 1997: 285-313 Parsons, Donald. The Cost of School Time, Forgone Earnings, and Human Capital Formation. The Journal of Political Economy 1974: 251-66 Psacharopoulos, George. Returns to Education: A Further International Update and Implications. Journal of Human Resources Fall 1985: 583-604 Ruggles, Steven and Mathew Sobek et. al. Integrated Public Use Microdata Series: Version 2.0, www.ipums.org Minneapolis: Historical Census Projects, University of Minnesota, 1997 Sicilian, Paul and Adam Grossberg. Investment in Human Capital and Gender Wage Differences: Evidence From the NLSY. Applied Economics 2001: 463-71 Statistics Division of the United Nations Secretariat. Women s Indicators and Statistics Database (Wistat). CD ROM. United Nations, 2000 United Nations Children s Fund. The Progress of Nations 1999. UNICEF, 1999 Weinberger, Catherine J. Mathematical College Majors and the Gender Gap in Wages. Industrial Relations July 1999: 407-13 Welch, Finis. The Human Capital Approach: An Appraisal. The American Economic Review 1975: 63-73 References Antecol, Heather. Sex Differences: Immigrants. Journal of Human Resources Winter 2001: 119 The Park Place Economist Volume XI 43