A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality

Similar documents
A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality

Migrant Wages, Human Capital Accumulation and Return Migration

Firm Dynamics and Immigration: The Case of High-Skilled Immigration

Managing migration from the traditional to modern sector in developing countries

Immigration, Human Capital and the Welfare of Natives

Does Learning to Add up Add up? Lant Pritchett Presentation to Growth Commission October 19, 2007

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lectures 8 and 9: Political Agency

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS

A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution

Accounting for the role of occupational change on earnings in Europe and Central Asia Maurizio Bussolo, Iván Torre and Hernan Winkler (World Bank)

Human Capital and Income Inequality: New Facts and Some Explanations

Determinants of International Migration

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different?

Trade and Inequality: From Theory to Estimation

Commission on Growth and Development Cognitive Skills and Economic Development

The Mystery of Economic Growth by Elhanan Helpman. Chiara Criscuolo Centre for Economic Performance London School of Economics

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications

High-Skilled Immigration, STEM Employment, and Routine-Biased Technical Change

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE ANALYTICS OF THE WAGE EFFECT OF IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018

Young, Educated, Unemployed

Rethinking Growth Policy The Schumpeterian Perspective. EEA Meeting Geneva, August 2016

Income and wealth inequalities

High-Skilled Immigration, STEM Employment, and Non-Routine-Biased Technical Change

Investment-Specific Technological Change, Skill Accumulation, and Wage Inequality

Lessons from Schumpeterian Growth Theory

IMPLICATIONS OF WAGE BARGAINING SYSTEMS ON REGIONAL DIFFERENTIATION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION LUMINITA VOCHITA, GEORGE CIOBANU, ANDREEA CIOBANU

Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immigrants

Educational Choice, Rural-Urban Migration and Economic Development

Revista Economica 65:6 (2015) ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AS AN INTERRELATION BETWEEN WEALTH, COMPETITIVENESS, AND INTELLECTUAL CAPITAL EMPIRICAL EVIDENCES

High-Skilled Immigration, STEM Employment, and Non-Routine-Biased Technical Change

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis Nanak Kakwani

Workers, Firms and Wage Dynamics

Female Migration, Human Capital and Fertility

The Labor Market Effects of Reducing Undocumented Immigrants

Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016

Migration Options for Skilled Labor and Optimal Investment in Human Capital

High-Skilled Immigration, STEM Employment, and Non-Routine-Biased Technical Change

Climate Change Around the World

East Asian Currency Union

NERO INTEGRATION OF REFUGEES (NORDIC COUNTRIES) Emily Farchy, ELS/IMD

THE ALLOCATION OF TALENT IN BRAZIL AND INDIA. Kanat Abdulla

New Directions in Schumpeterian Growth Theory*

by Jim Dolmas and Gregory W. Huffman

Optimal Voting Rules for International Organizations, with an. Application to the UN

The Aggregate Productivity Effects of Internal Migration: Evidence from Indonesia

Wage Rigidity and Spatial Misallocation: Evidence from Italy and Germany

The Wage Effects of Immigration and Emigration

Distribution of income and wealth among individuals: theoretical perspectives. Joseph E. Stiglitz Bangalore Advanced Graduate Workshop July 2016

Political Skill and the Democratic Politics of Investment Protection

Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights in a. Product-cycle Model of Skills Accumulation

Essays on Economic Growth and China s Urbanization

Liquidity Constraints and Investment in International Migration:

Is This Time Different? The Opportunities and Challenges of Artificial Intelligence

Immigrants Inflows, Native outflows, and the Local Labor Market Impact of Higher Immigration David Card

Accounting for Fertility Decline During the Transition to Growth

Computerization and Immigration: Theory and Evidence from the United States 1

Estimating the foreign-born population on a current basis. Georges Lemaitre and Cécile Thoreau

Honors General Exam Part 1: Microeconomics (33 points) Harvard University

Regional Wage Differentiation and Wage Bargaining Systems in the EU

Tilburg University. Can a brain drain be good for growth? Mountford, A.W. Publication date: Link to publication

You Reap What You Sow

UK Productivity Gap: Skills, management and innovation

The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008)

Is the Great Gatsby Curve Robust?

Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany

Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins

Family Reunification or Point-based Immigration System? The Case of the United States and Mexico

LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES

GDP per capita was lowest in the Czech Republic and the Republic of Korea. For more details, see page 3.

Online Appendix for. Home Away From Home? Foreign Demand and London House Prices

Earnings Inequality: Stylized Facts, Underlying Causes, and Policy

PIER Working Paper

Rankings: Universities vs. National Higher Education Systems. Benoit Millot

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET EFFECTS OF REDUCING THE NUMBER OF ILLEGAL IMMIGRANTS. Andri Chassamboulli Giovanni Peri

Venezuela s Growth experience *

Do Institutions have a Greater Effect on Female Entrepreneurs?

Taiwan s Development Strategy for the Next Phase. Dr. San, Gee Vice Chairman Taiwan External Trade Development Council Taiwan

ISSUE BRIEF: U.S. Immigration Priorities in a Global Context

Inclusion and Gender Equality in China

The Past, Present and Future. of U.S. Income Inequality

Caste Networks in the Modern Indian Economy

Trading Goods or Human Capital

Migration With Endogenous Social Networks in China

Within-Job Wage Inequality: Performance Pay and Job Fitness

Discussion of "Risk Shocks" by Larry Christiano

III. Wage Inequality and Labour Market Institutions

Earnings Inequality: Stylized Facts, Underlying Causes, and Policy

Professor Christina Romer. LECTURE 14 RISING INEQUALITY March 6, 2018

Matthew A. Cole and Eric Neumayer. The pitfalls of convergence analysis : is the income gap really widening?

Migration and Consumption Insurance in Bangladesh

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

Immigration Reform, Economic Growth, and the Fiscal Challenge Douglas Holtz- Eakin l April 2013

MIT Spring 2018: Lecture 2 The Canonical Model of Skill Differentials

Inequality: Empirics, Causes, Consequences, and Implications. Marshall Steinbaum. December 10, Washington Center for Equitable Growth 1/26

An example of public goods

Industrial & Labor Relations Review

Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries

Labor Market Deregulation and Wage Dispersion: Does Product Market Competition Matter? The case of the EU Electricity Industry

Transcription:

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality Chad Jones and Jihee Kim Forthcoming, Journal of Political Economy A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 1

Top Income Inequality in the United States and France INCOME SHARE OF TOP 0.1 PERCENT 8% 6% United States 4% 2% France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Source: World Top Incomes Database (Alvaredo, Atkinson, Piketty, Saez) YEAR A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 2

Related literature Empirics: Piketty and Saez (2003), Aghion et al (2015), Guvenen-Kaplan-Song (2015) and many more Rent Seeking: Piketty, Saez, and Stantcheva (2011) and Rothschild and Scheuer (2011) Finance: Philippon-Reshef (2009), Bell-Van Reenen (2010) Not just finance: Bakija-Cole-Heim (2010), Kaplan-Rauh Pareto-generating mechanisms: Gabaix (1999, 2009), Luttmer (2007, 2010), Reed (2001). GLLM (2015). Use Pareto to get growth: Kortum (1997), Lucas and Moll (2013), Perla and Tonetti (2013). Pareto wealth distribution: Benhabib-Bisin-Zhu (2011), Nirei (2009), Moll (2012), Piketty-Saez (2012), Piketty-Zucman (2014), Aoki-Nirei (2015) A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 3

Outline Facts from World Top Incomes Database Simple model Full model Empirical work using IRS public use panel tax returns Numerical examples A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 4

Top Income Inequality around the World TOP 1% SHARE, 2006-08 20 South Africa 18 United States 16 14 United Kingdom Canada Singapore Germany 45-degree line 12 10 8 6 Norway Australia Sweden Denmark Ireland Korea Taiwan Switzerland Italy Japan France Spain New Zealand Netherlands Mauritius 4 2 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 TOP 1% SHARE, 1980-82 A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 5

The Composition of the Top 0.1 Percent Income Share TOP 0.1 PERCENT INCOME SHARE 14% 12% 10% 8% Capital gains 6% 4% Business income 2% Capital income Wages and Salaries 0% 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 YEAR A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 6

The Pareto Nature of Labor Income INCOME RATIO: MEAN( Y Y>Z ) / Z 10 9 8 7 6 Equals 1 1 η if Pareto... 5 4 3 2005 2 1980 1 $0 $500k $1.0m $1.5m $2.0m $2.5m $3.0m WAGE + ENTREPRENEURIAL INCOME CUTOFF, Z A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 7

Pareto Distributions Pr[Y > y] = ( y y 0 ) ξ Let S(p) = share of income going to the top p percentiles, and η 1/ξ be a measure of Pareto inequality: S(p) = ( 100 p ) η 1 If η = 1/2, then share to Top 1% is 100 1/2.10 If η = 3/4, then share to Top 1% is 100 1/4.32 Fractal: Let S(a) = share of 10a s income going to top a: S(a) = 10 η 1 A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 8

Fractal Inequality Shares in the United States FRACTAL SHARES (PERCENT) 45 40 35 From 20% in 1970 to 35% in 2010 S(.01) 30 25 20 S(.1) S(1) 15 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 YEAR A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 9

The Power-Law Inequality Exponentη, United States 1 + LOG 10 (TOP SHARE) 0.65 0.6 0.55 0.5 η rises from.33 in 1970 to.55 in 2010 η(.01) 0.45 0.4 0.35 0.3 η(.1) η(1) 0.25 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 YEAR A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 10

Skill-Biased Technical Change? Let x i = skill and w = wage per unit skill If Pr[x i > x] = x 1/η x, then y i = wx α i Pr[y i > y] = ( ȳ w ) 1/ηy where η y = αη x That is y i is Pareto with inequality parameter η y SBTC ( w) shifts distribution right but η y unchanged. α would raise Pareto inequality... This paper: why is x Pareto, and why α A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 11

A Simple Model Cantelli (1921), Steindl (1965), Gabaix (2009) A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 12

Key Idea: Exponential growth w/ death Pareto INCOME Exponential growth Creative destruction Initial TIME A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 13

Simple Model for Intuition Exponential growth often leads to a Pareto distribution. Entrepreneurs New entrepreneur ( top earner ) earns y 0 Income after x years of experience: y(x) = y 0 e µx Poisson replacement process at rate δ Stationary distribution of experience is exponential Pr[Experience > x] = e δx A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 14

What fraction of people have income greater thany? Equals fraction with at least x(y) years of experience Therefore x(y) = 1 µ log ( y y 0 ) Pr[Income > y] = Pr[Experience > x(y)] = e δx(y) ( y = y 0 ) δ µ So power law inequality is given by η y = µ δ A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 15

Intuition Why does the Pareto result emerge? Log of income experience (Exponential growth) Experience exponential (Poisson process) Therefore log income is exponential Income Pareto! A Pareto distribution emerges from exponential growth experienced for an exponentially distributed amount of time. Full model: endogenize µ and δ and how they change A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 16

Why is experience exponentially distributed? Let F(x,t) denote the distribution of experience at time t How does it evolve over discrete interval t? F(x,t+ t) F(x,t) = δ t(1 F(x,t)) }{{} inflow from above x Dividing both sides by t = x and taking the limit [F(x,t) F(x x,t)] }{{} outflow as top folks age F(x,t) t = δ(1 F(x,t)) F(x,t) x Stationary: F(x) such that F(x,t) exponential solution. t = 0. Integrating gives the A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 17

The Model Pareto distribution in partial eqm GE with exogenous research Full general equilibrium A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 18

Entrepreneur s Problem Choose {e t } to maximize expected discounted utility: U(c,l) = logc+βlogl c t = ψ t x t e t +l t +τ = 1 dx t = µ(e t )x t dt+σx t db t µ(e) = φe x = idiosyncratic productivity of a variety = determined in GE (grows) δ = endogenous creative destruction δ = exogenous destruction ψ t A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 19

Entrepreneur s Problem HJB Form The Bellman equation for the entreprenueur: ρv(x t,t) = max e t logψ t +logx t +βlog(ω e t )+ E[dV(x t,t)] dt +(δ + δ)(v w (t) V(x t,t)) where Ω 1 τ Note: the capital gain term is E[dV(x t,t)] dt = µ(e t )x t V x (x t,t)+ 1 2 σ2 x 2 tv xx (x t,t)+v t (x t,t) A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 20

Solution for Entrepreneur s Problem Equilibrium effort is constant: e = 1 τ 1 φ β(ρ+δ + δ) Comparative statics: τ e : higher taxes φ e : better technology for converting effort into x δ or δ e : more destruction A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 21

Stationary Distribution of Entrepreneur s Income Unit measure of entrepreneurs / varieties Displaced in two ways Exogenous misallocation ( δ): new entrepreneur x 0. Endogenous creative destruction (δ): inherit existing productivity x. Distribution f(x,t) satisfies Kolmogorov forward equation: f(x,t) t = δf(x,t) x [µ(e )xf(x,t)]+ 1 2 2 [ σ 2 x 2 x 2 f(x,t) ] Stationary distribution lim t f(x,t) = f(x) solves f(x,t) t = 0 A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 22

Guess that f( ) takes the Pareto form f(x) = Cx ξ 1 ξ = µ σ 2 + ( µ σ 2 ) 2 + 2 δ σ 2 µ µ(e ) 1 2 σ2 = φ(1 τ) β(ρ+δ + δ) 1 2 σ2 Power-law inequality is therefore given by η = 1/ξ A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 23

Comparative Statics (givenδ ) η = 1/ξ, ξ = µ σ 2 + ( µ σ 2 ) 2 + 2 δ σ 2 µ = φ(1 τ) β(ρ+δ + δ) 1 2 σ2 Power-law inequality η increases if φ: better technology for converting effort into x δ or δ: less destruction τ: Lower taxes β: Lower utility weight on leisure A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 24

Luttmer and GLLM Problems with basic random growth model: Luttmer (2011): Cannot produce rockets like Google or Uber Gabaix, Lasry, Lions, and Moll (2015): Slow transition dynamics Solution from Luttmer/GLLM: Introduce heterogeneous mean growth rates: e.g. high versus low Here: φ H > φ L with Poisson rate p of transition (H L) A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 25

Pareto Inequality with Heterogeneous Growth Rates η = 1/ξ H, ξ H = µ H σ 2 + ) ( µ 2 H σ 2 + 2( δ + p) σ 2 µ H = φ H (1 τ) β(ρ+δ + δ) 1 2 σ2 This adopts Gabaix, Lasry, Lions, and Moll (2015) Why it helps quantitatively: φ H : Fast growth allows for Google / Uber p: Rate at which high growth types transit to low growth types raises the speed of convergence = δ + p. A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 26

Growth and Creative Destruction Final output Y = ( 1 0 Y θ i di ) 1/θ Production of variety i Y i = γ n t xα i L i Resource constraint L t +R t +1 = N, L t 1 0 L itdi Flow rate of innovation ṅ t = λ(1 z)r t Creative destruction δ t = ṅ t A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 27

Equilibrium with Monopolistic Competition Suppose R/ L = s where L N 1. Define X 1 0 x idi = x 0 1 η. Markup is 1/θ. Aggregate PF Y t = γ n t Xα L Wage for L Profits for variety i w t = θγ n t Xα π it = (1 θ)γ n t Xα L ( x i ) ( X xi ) wt X Definition of ψ t ψ t = (1 θ)γ n t Xα 1 L Note that η has a level effect on output and wages. A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 28

Growth and Inequality in the s case Creative destruction and growth δ = λr = λ(1 z) s L g y = ṅlogγ = λ(1 z) s Llogγ Does rising top inequality always reflect positive changes? No! s (more research) or z (less innovation blocking) Raise growth and reduce inequality via creative destruction. A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 29

Endogenizing Research and Growth A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 30

Endogenizings = R/ L Worker: ρv w (t) = logw t + dv W (t) dt Researcher: ρv R (t) = log( mw t )+ dv R (t) dt + λ ( E[V(x,t)] V R (t) ) + δ R ( V(x0,t) V R (t) ) Equilibrium: V w (t) = V R (t) A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 31

Stationary equilibrium solution Drift of log x µ H = φ H (1 τ) β(ρ+δ + δ) 1 2 σ2 H Pareto inequality η = 1/ξ, ξ = µ H σ 2 H + ) ( µ 2 H σ + 2( δ+ p) H 2 σh 2 Creative destruction δ = λ(1 z)s L Growth g = δ logγ Research allocation V w (s ) = V R (s ) A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 32

Varying the x-technology parameterφ POWER LAW INEQUALITY 1 GROWTH RATE (PERCENT) 4 0.75 3 0.50 2 0.25 1 0 0 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 33

Why does φ reduce growth? φ e µ Two effects GE effect: technological improvement economy more productive so higher profits, but also higher wages Allocative effect: raises Pareto inequality (η), so x i X is more dispersed Elogπ i /w is lower. Risk averse agents undertake less research. Positive level effect raises both profits and wages. Riskier research lower research and lower long-run growth. A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 34

How the model works φ raises top inequality, but leaves the growth rate of the economy unchanged. Surprising: a linear differential equation for x. Key: the distribution of x is stationary! Higher φ has a positive level effect through higher inequality, raising everyone s wage. But growth comes via research, not through x... Lucas at micro level, Romer/AH at macro level A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 35

Growth and Inequality Growth and inequality tend to move in opposite directions! Two reasons 1. Faster growth more creative destruction Less time for inequality to grow Entrepreneurs may work less hard to grow market 2. With greater inequality, research is riskier! Riskier research less research lower growth Transition dynamics ambiguous effects on growth in medium run A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 36

Possible explanations: Rising U.S. Inequality Technology (e.g. WWW) Entrepreneur s effort is more productive η Worldwide phenomenon, not just U.S. Ambiguous effects on U.S. growth (research is riskier!) Lower taxes on top incomes Increase effort by entrepreneur s η A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 37

Possible explanations: Inequality in France Efficiency-reducing explanations Delayed adoption of good technologies (WWW) Increased misallocation (killing off entrepreneurs more quickly) Efficiency-enhancing explanations Increased subsidies to research (more creative destruction) Reduction in blocking of innovations (more creative destruction) A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 38

Micro Evidence A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 39

Overview Geometric random walk with drift = canonical DGP in the empirical literature on income dynamics. Survey by Meghir and Pistaferri (2011) The distribution of growth rates for the Top 10% earners Guvenen, Karahan, Ozkan, Song (2015) for 1995-96 IRS public use panel for 1979 1990 (small sample) A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 40

Growth Rates of Top 10% Incomes, 1995 1996 DENSITY 6 5 1 in 100: rise by a factor of 3.0 1 in 1,000: rise by a factor of 6.8 1 in 10,000: rise by a factor of 24.6 4 3 2 1 0 From Guvenen et al (2015) δ +δ { }} { µ H {}}{ -5-4 -3-2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 ANNUAL LOG CHANGE, 1995-96 A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 41

Decomposing Pareto Inequality: Social Security Data PARETO INEQUALITY, 0.54 0.53 0.52 0.51 All together 0.5 0.49 0.48 0.47 0.46 only 0.45 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 YEAR A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 42

Pareto Inequality: IRS Data PARETO INEQUALITY, 0.7 0.65 0.6 0.55 0.5 0.45 0.4 0.35 η Entrepreneurial income Both Wages and salaries 0.3 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 YEAR A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 43

One-Time Shocks toφ H, p, andτ PARETO INEQUALITY, 0.65 η 0.6 0.55 0.5 τ φ H 0.45 0.4 p 0.35 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 YEAR A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 44

One-Time Shocks toφ H, p, andτ GDP PER PERSON 1600 800 τ φ H 400 p 200 100 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 YEAR A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 45

The Dynamic Response to IRS/SSA-Inspired Shocks PARETO INEQUALITY, η 0.7 Entrepreneurial income (IRS data) 0.65 0.6 Wages, salaries, and entrepreneurial income (IRS data) 0.55 0.5 Wages and salaries (SSA data) 0.45 0.4 0.35 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 YEAR A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 46

The Dynamic Response to IRS/SSA-Inspired Shocks GDP PER PERSON 800 Entrepreneurial income (IRS data) 400 Wages, salaries, and entrepreneurial income (IRS data) Wages and salaries (SSA data) 200 100 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 YEAR A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 47

Conclusions: Understanding top income inequality Information technology / WWW: Entrepreneurial effort is more productive: φ η Worldwide phenomenon (?) Why else might inequality rise by less in France? Less innovation blocking / more research: raises creative destruction Regulations limiting rapid growth: p and φ Theory suggests rich connections between: models of top inequality micro data on income dynamics A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality p. 48