LETTERS & NOTES ON REGULATION

Similar documents
End user involvement in Internet Governance: why and how

CORK UNIVERSITY BUSINESS SCHOOL POLICY FORUM. FRIDAY NOVEMBER 3, 2017 Devere Hall, Áras na Mac Léinn, UCC.

IT for Change's Contribution to the Consultations on Enhanced Cooperation being held at the United Nations Headquarters in New York in December 2010

Aspects of the New Public Finance

Boundaries to business action at the public policy interface Issues and implications for BP-Azerbaijan

Corporate Compliance and Responsibility Committee - Terms of Reference

Dalrymple Bay Coal Terminal User Group

Children s Commissioner Review NGO Co-ordinating Group

Consultation Response

Brexit What might it mean for a city like Milton Keynes? Valerie Conway MRICS Development Consultant David Lock Associates

As Prepared for Delivery. Partners in Progress: Expanding Economic Opportunity Across the Americas. AmCham Panama

Effective Harmonisation within the European Electronic Communications Sector

Role of Government in the Energy Sector

SASKATCHEWAN ASSOCIATION OF MEDICAL RADIATION TECHNOLOGISTS COUNCIL POLICY MANUAL

Submission by the Scottish Legal Services Ombudsman

The City of London Law Society Competition Law Committee

Capitalism in an Age of Robots

Simon Communities of Ireland submission to the Garda Síochána Corporate Strategy

Transmission Maintenance Coordination Committee Charter

The Emerging Powerhouse: Opportunities, Trends & Risks of the African Economic Climate

Energy Policy Act of 2005

The Home Office response to the Independent Chief Inspectors of Borders and Immigration s report: An Inspection of the Right to Rent scheme

Russell Group evidence to the Home Affairs Select Committee immigration inquiry

Competition and EU policy-making

Social Economy of Republic of Korea: Conditions of Success and Policy Direction

IMAD NAJIB FAKHOURY, JORDAN

President Trump Signs Executive Order Instructing Agencies to Minimize Burdens of the ACA

Police-Community Engagement and Counter-Terrorism: Developing a regional, national and international hub. UK-US Workshop Summary Report December 2010

ARIX BIOSCIENCE PLC TERMS OF REFERENCE FOR AUDIT AND RISK COMMITTEE

Common Good: An interview with Lord Stephen Green, UK Minister for Trade and Investment. Complimentary article reprint.

Competition law and competition policy: lessons from developing and transition economies

ABOUT THE IVEY SCHOOL OF BUSINESS, UNIVERSITY OF WESTERN ONTARIO

American Swiss Foundation Annual Gala Dinner New York, June 9, 2014

A MANIFESTO FOR JUSTICE

Executive Committee Terms of Reference

STRUCTURAL AND ADMINISTRATIVE REFORM IN THE MANAGEMENT OF BANGLADESH RAILWAY

Geneva, Switzerland 20 November Mr. Hamadoun Toure, Director, ITU/BDT and other Directors

Report of the Justice in Wales Working Group

European & External Relations committee International Engagement inquiry Scotch Whisky Association response January 2015

Foundations of Wisconsin s Regulatory Role ZACH RAMIREZ, WISCONSIN LEGISLATIVE COUNCIL

Private sector-led challenges to anti-competitive behaviour. Growth and fairness: private sector-led challenges to anti-competitive behaviour

OF MULTILATERAL TRADE NEGOTIATIONS

Internet Governance and G20

Submission By. to the Economic Development, Science and Innovation Committee. on the. Commerce (Criminalisation of Cartels) Amendment Bill

THE NEW HAMPSHIRE SITE EVALUATION COMMITTEE AN INTRODUCTION TO THE COMMITTEE AND ITS PROCESS

Independent review of the Financial Reporting Council s enforcement procedures sanctions

A5 KELDA HOLDINGS LTD AUDIT COMMITTEE TERMS OF REFERENCE

Module 6: Alcoholism, Drug Abuse and Corruption

"The Enlargement of the EU: Impact on the EU-Russia bilateral cooperation"

Xi Jinping s Policy Challenges. Tony Saich Canon Institute Tokyo October 9, 2018

Brexit: Unite demands protections for you

Tanzania: Decoding the Magufuli way and forging a path for constructive private sector engagement - August 2016

INDIAN ECONOMY CURRENT AFFAIRS 2017 NATIONAL IPR POLICY, 2016

INDIA G20 National Remittance Plan

So today we pay homage to the founding fathers that helped set up this great institution.

Memorandum to the New Prime Minister re Canada-United States Trade Relations

Executive summary 2013:2

PREPARED REMARKS FOR COMMERCE SECRETARY GARY LOCKE Asia Society and Woodrow Wilson Center event on Chinese FDI Washington, DC Wednesday, May 4, 2011

CHARTER OF THE NOMINATING AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE COMMITTEE OF THE NORTHWEST INDIANA BANCORP AND PEOPLES BANK SB BOARD OF DIRECTORS

Welcome to Study Unit 1 of Business Government and Society.

Evolution of dispute resolution under the FIDIC Red Book. Bill Smith, Partner 10 May 2018

3. Assessment if the economic development in the Balkans and the Poverty Reduction Strategy Process (PRSP).

BARRICK GOLD CORPORATION. Corporate Governance & Nominating Committee Mandate

Thank you David (Johnstone) for your warm introduction and for inviting me to talk to your spring Conference on managing land in the public interest.

Kavita Rai Dam Development: The Dynamics of Social Inequality in a Hydropower Project in Nepal. Gottingen: Cuvillier Verlag.

IERA IDAHO ENERGY RESOURCES AUTHORITY ACT. Title 67, Chapter 89, Idaho Code IDAHO ENERGY RESOURCES AUTHORITY ACT

Corporate Governance Framework. Version 3

SUPPORTING YOUNG PEOPLE LEAVING CARE IN SCOTLAND

UNITED NATIONS EDUCATIONAL, SCIENTIFIC AND CULTURAL ORGANIZATION EXECUTIVE BOARD. Hundred and fiftieth Session

CORPORATE GOVERNANCE PRINCIPLES Revised February 14, 2019

The Cities. Unit 1: The Gilded Age ( )

Alberta Liberal Party 2016 Policy and Principles Convention Resolutions. Table of Contents

Federal Labor Laws. Paul K. Rainsberger, Director University of Missouri Labor Education Program Revised, April 2004

THE COMPANIES ACT 2006 PRIVATE COMPANY LIMITED BY GUARANTEE ARTICLES OF ASSOCIATION. YORKSHIRE 2019 LIMITED Incorporated 24 November 2016

1st Floor, 10 Victoria Street, London SW1H 0NN T F

AMERICAN ELECTRIC POWER COMPANY, INC. COMMITTEE ON DIRECTORS AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE CHARTER Amended as of December 6, 2016

EY UK Additional information

Exploring the fast/slow thinking: implications for political analysis: Gerry Stoker, March 2016

Strategies to Combat State Capture and Administrative Corruption in Transition Economies

Audit Committee Terms of Reference

THE BUSINESS CLIMATE INDEX SURVEY 2008

PRIVATIZATION ACT NO. 2 OF 2005 LAWS OF KENYA

WHY WE ARE REVIEWING THE ACT

Federal-State Relations in Energy Law in the United States of America

a co-operative agenda for Wales 2016

Maritime Goods Movement Act

CMP285. CUSC Governance Reform Levelling the Playing Field. CUSC Modification Proposal Form

Paradigms Shifts and Major Economic Institutions

EUROPE AND AMERICA: LOSING THEIR BEARINGS?

Future EU Trade Policy: Achieving Europe's Strategic Goals

The Labour Party Manifesto

The economic impact of the University of Exeter s international students

2018 AASHTO LEGISLATIVE ACTION AGENDA For Consideration by Congress and the Trump Administration

The Competitiveness of Financial Centers: A Swiss View

Retail Pharmacy in Ireland

2016 Lobbyists Act Legislative Review. Recommended Amendments to the Alberta Lobbyists Act and the Lobbyists Act General Regulation

Overview. Main Findings. The Global Weighted Average has also been steady in the last quarter, and is now recorded at 6.62 percent.

Who will speak, and who will listen? Comments on Burawoy and public sociology 1

THE WAY FORWARD CHAPTER 11. Contributed by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development and the World Trade Organization

THE SPEAKER S COMMITTEE ON THE ELECTORAL COMMISSION

Transcription:

LETTERS & NOTES ON REGULATION Capture of independent sectoral regulators Regina Finn and Simon Less No. 2.2 June 2013 REGULATORY POLICY INSTITUTE

Letters and notes on Regulation, Vol. 2 Published by the Regulatory Policy Institute 300 Banbury Road, Oxford OX2 7ED, UK www.rpieurope.org First published June 2013 Regulatory Policy Institute

Regina Finn 1 and Simon Less 2 Capture of independent sectoral regulators Capture is an ever present risk to the benefits of independent sectoral regulation. The primary mode of capture may shift over time. Political capture', or undue influence, is a key current threat. Conventionally, capture is the tendency for regulators to take decisions that are biased in favour of the interests of the industry they regulate rather than the customers or wider society on whose behalf they regulate. The archetype is capture of appointment of the regulator him or herself. In 1887, the Interstate Commerce Commission was established to regulate prices of the US railroad robber barons. The industry secured the appointment of a lawyer as chairman, with strong experience of railroad industry acquired by acting on behalf of his railroad clients. The regulator soon operated as the co-ordinator of the railroad cartel. But even without such blatant capture, regulators commonly suffer from capture in more subtle ways. One way is encroaching capture of a regulator s staff through sheer weight of engagement with the regulated industry. Regulatory staff have frequent contact with the industry to secure the information and deep sectoral expertise they need. It s human nature for views to tend to become socialised with those whom we come frequently into contact with. As John Kay has put it: Many of the people who run regulated companies are agreeable, committed individuals who are properly affronted by any suggestion that their activities do not serve the public good. Few members of the public, by contrast, ever make contact with a regulatory agency.so even the regulator with the best intentions comes to see issues in much the same way as the corporate officers he deals with every day. You require both an abrasive personality and considerable intellectual curiosity to do the job in any other way. This form of capture may act principally to influence the regulatory agenda: the set of issues that are looked at and prioritised by the regulator. It may therefore be less easy to spot than capture of the decisions themselves. Some believe that one example was Oftel s prioritisation of the issue of resale over Local Loop Unbundling and challenging the dominant telecoms operator BT. Another example may be the attention that has historically been paid to the issue of financing costs in the water sector. How can regulators guard against this route to capture apart from cultivating more abrasive personalities? 1 Chief Executive of Ofwat. 2 Chair of the Regulatory Policy Institute s Advisory Board and a Senior Consultant to Policy Exchange. 1

Regulators need regular external review and challenge of their priorities - from strong non-executive board members, quinquennial reviews, outside advisers like Ofwat s Future Regulation Advisory Panel, and from the OFT (in future, the Competition and Markets Authority). Regulators must spend enough time engaging directly with voices other than the regulated industry, including entrants, and customers (unmediated by regulated industry). Negotiated settlement direct negotiation between the regulated industry and customers under regulatory oversight is one important approach to countervailing regulatory capture, where it can be made to work in a given sector. The Civil Aviation Authority has used negotiated settlement. Both Ofwat and the Water Industry Commission for Scotland are experimenting with Customer Challenge Groups: local, independent groups including customers and customer representatives, who are playing a key role in the price reviews by challenging companies business plans. A third form of capture is when a sectoral regulator effectively captures itself, though its own historic way of doing things. A regulator may naturally be committed to particular regulatory processes that it has spent time and effort honing, but that commitment may outlive the usefulness of the processes. Relatedly, a regulator may become captured by a way of thinking that its historic regulatory approach nurtures. For example, a certain command and control way of thinking may arise from an historic regulatory approach like Ofwat s - of prescribing the details of standards, outputs and tariffs. These effects may be reinforced by regulatory staff simply becoming comfortable doing what they have long done. What may have worked in a previous period is not necessarily best approach today. The world is constantly changing: more demanding customers; environmental and economic challenges; technological developments; rising commodity scarcity; increased sector maturity; opportunities for new markets; new entrants. A regulator captured by its historic approaches will tend to overlook, or even resist, a need for change in regulatory approach in response. Self-capture can be reinforced by external interests vested in the historic ways of doing things. Stakeholders who wish to see a market made to deliver certain outcomes may not, for example, welcome a change of regulatory approach away from command and control. The regulated industry too may act reinforce this form of capture if the historic regulatory processes tend to protect incumbents, if the industry has learnt how to game current processes, or if a culture of dependency on the regulatory processes has developed. It is hard for regulators not to suffer from some self-capture. Again John Kay: It requires a considerable effort of imagination to visualise that any industry might be organised very differently from the way that industry is organised now. 2

To combat this tendency, there is a case for regular disruptive change, to stop processes and cultures getting too entrenched. Disruptive change could focus on overhauling the overall regulatory model. Ofwat s Future Price Limits project is an example. Current market reform in the water sector is also a key disruptive change. Change could focus on personnel, perhaps substantially slimming down a regulator between each regulatory cycle. For Ofwat, opening a London office helped refresh the organisation. Most radically, change could be institutional, replacing or merging regulators, as has happened to Offer, Ofgas, Oftel, Postcomm and others: Of course the benefits need to be weighed against the inevitable costs of institutional change The fourth mode of capture is through politics, in other words the undue influence of politics over the proper domain of independent regulation. A quarter century ago, one key reason for the policy innovation of independent sectoral regulators was to secure independence from politicians. Politicians are lobbied by industry and other sectional interests and politicians feel understandable pressure to respond to this and to the short-term political imperatives of the day. Independent sectoral regulators were created to take a number of narrow decisions, sheltered from political pressure and volatility (within clear statutory duties). Regulators decisions often shape the environment for major investments in long-lived assets, and stat independence reduces the political risk premium for investors. In water, huge investment well over 100 billion in 23 years has been achieved at low cost. But are some now forgetting the reasons for such independence from undue political influence? Politicians are naturally tempted to secure their objectives using tools that are available, and economic regulators can be potentially powerful tools. Over time governments have increasingly acted on this temptation. Of course political involvement in the regulated sectors is inevitable, and appropriate. But where, and the way, politicians get involved affects the unintended costs of that involvement. John Kay: There needs to be ultimate political responsibility, but the wise minister will exercise it extremely sparingly, and may wish to tie him or herself to the mast to avoid the siren voices of the Today programme. The way politicians have sought to achieve their legitimate - political objectives on the environment has been the main case study in increasing political influence over sectoral regulators. Beginning with the Renewable Obligation through to the Energy Bill and Electricity Market Reform, governments have increasingly taken into their own hands the detailed specification of contracts and market outcomes, increasingly limiting the role of the market and economic regulator. Moreover, rising energy bills as a result of higher international energy prices and government energy policies have led to strong political pressure on the independent regulator to take action about something else: improving 3

competition in the energy retail market. This has led to joint government / independent regulator proposals to restrict numbers of energy tariffs. Fiscal policy, and particularly deficit reduction, is another driver of costly political influence. For example, governments have resisted the regulator s proposals for more onrail competition and the potential benefits for customers and the economy instead prioritising economic rents to the Exchequer from monopoly franchises. There also appears to be a trend towards directly reigning in the independence of sectoral regulators boards. A number of board appointments have recently been for shorter terms, and ministers have taken an increasingly hands-on role in the appointment processes of non-executive directors. There is a risk that increasing willingness of governments to interfere in regulated sectors emboldens vested interests, who try to influence economic regulation by going around the independent regulator to government. But it is important not to paint too gloomy a picture. Independent regulation continues to deliver benefits through providing a degree of regulatory certainty. And the Department for Business is implementing a strong new competition regulator, in the Competition and Markets Authority. Can steps be taken to maintain the benefits of independent regulation in the face of the emerging trend toward politicisation? Of course regulators must maintain a clear-sighted focus on discharging their statutory duties, including to protect the interests of customers. But there can be immense pressure on regulators to roll with the political tide. It may be that independent regulation is an innovation that can t be sustained in the long term. Stephen Littlechild s original report did envisage economic regulation as a largely transitional phenomenon (on the road to competition). Or can we envisage a new settlement? Perhaps with a greater role for the Competition and Markets Authority, which may be more protected from undue political influence. And perhaps there is scope for a greater role for the Department of Business in relation to sectoral regulators, drawing a clearer line between independent sectoral regulation and the delivery of wider government policy objectives. 4