challenges for developing economies under the WTO

Similar documents
Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 109 ( 2014 ) The East Asian Model of Economic Development and Developing Countries

Economic Development: Miracle, Crisis and Regionalism

China After the East Asian Crisis

Explaining Asian Outward FDI

Chapter 5: Internationalization & Industrialization

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Globalization and the Evolution of Trade - Pasquale M. Sgro

Support Materials. GCE Economics H061/H461: Exemplar Materials. AS/A Level Economics

Creating an enabling business environment in Asia: To what extent is public support warranted?

for developing countries

Chapter 10 Trade Policy in Developing Countries

Chapter Organization. Introduction. Introduction. Import-Substituting Industrialization. Import-Substituting Industrialization

ASIAN CURRENCY CRISES IMPACT ON THAILAND, INDONESIA& SOUTH KOREA

Development Strategy. for. Myanmar

Globalisation and Open Markets

SECTION THREE BENEFITS OF THE JSEPA

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

The economic crisis in the low income CIS: fiscal consequences and policy responses. Sudharshan Canagarajah World Bank June 2010

Current Situation and Outlook of Asia and the Pacific

Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction: Lessons from the Malaysian Experience

The 1989 TDRI Year-End Conference

Neo-liberalism and the Asian Financial Crisis

Western Balkans Countries In Focus Of Global Economic Crisis

THAILAND SYSTEMATIC COUNTRY DIAGNOSTIC Public Engagement

Latin America in the New Global Order. Vittorio Corbo Governor Central Bank of Chile

Remittances and the Macroeconomic Impact of the Global Economic Crisis in the Kyrgyz Republic and Tajikistan

Globalization GLOBALIZATION REGIONAL TABLES. Introduction. Key Trends. Key Indicators for Asia and the Pacific 2009

The Nanning-Singapore Economic Corridor:

Gertrude Tumpel-Gugerell: The euro benefits and challenges

Globalization and its Impact on Poverty in Pakistan. Sohail J. Malik Ph.D. Islamabad May 10, 2006

POLICY OPTIONS AND CHALLENGES FOR DEVELOPING ASIA PERSPECTIVES FROM THE IMF AND ASIA APRIL 19-20, 2007 TOKYO

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern

Vietnam s Current Development Policies: An Overview

Committee for Development Planning

ASEAN ECONOMIC BULLETIN January 2016

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

The Future of Global Trade Policy

To be opened on receipt

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Shuji Uchikawa

UNDERSTANDING TRADE, DEVELOPMENT, AND POVERTY REDUCTION

VENEZUELA: Oil, Inflation and Prospects for Long-Term Growth

6. Policy Recommendations on How to Strengthen Financial Cooperation in Asia Wang Tongsan

Putting development back in the WTO

CHAPTER 12: The Problem of Global Inequality

Lecture 1. Overview of the Ghanaian Economy. Michael Insaidoo

Chapter 11. Trade Policy in Developing Countries

International Development and Aid

INCLUSIVE GROWTH AND POLICIES: THE ASIAN EXPERIENCE. Thangavel Palanivel Chief Economist for Asia-Pacific UNDP, New York

9.1 Human Development Index Development improving the material conditions diffusion of knowledge and technology Measure by HDI

Since the Vietnam War ended in 1975, the

11 The Future of Global Trade Policy

Assessing Barriers to Trade in Education Services in Developing ESCAP Countries: An Empirical Exercise WTO/ARTNeT Short-term Research Project

Trade, Employment and Inclusive Growth in Asia. Douglas H. Brooks Jakarta, Indonesia 10 December 2012

The Challenge of Inclusive Growth: Making Growth Work for the Poor

Informal Summary Economic and Social Council High-Level Segment

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Has Globalization Helped or Hindered Economic Development? (EA)

The term developing countries does not have a precise definition, but it is a name given to many low and middle income countries.

Employment opportunities and challenges in an increasingly integrated Asia and the Pacific

WORLD ECONOMIC EXPANSION in the first half of the 1960's has

Emerging Market Consumers: A comparative study of Latin America and Asia-Pacific

POLI 12D: International Relations Sections 1, 6

Expanding the Number of Semi-skilled and Skilled Emigrant Workers from Southeast Asia to East Asia

Contemporary Human Geography, 2e. Chapter 9. Development. Lectures. Karl Byrand, University of Wisconsin-Sheboygan Pearson Education, Inc.

How Can Globalization Become More Pro-Poor?

The Asian Development Bank. Transportation Infrastructure in Asia and the Pacific

HAS GROWTH PEAKED? 2018 growth forecasts revised upwards as broad-based recovery continues

IMPACT OF GLOBALIZATION ON POVERTY: CASE STUDY OF PAKISTAN

ASEAN: THE AEC IS HERE, FINALLY 2030: NOMINAL GDP USD TRILLION US CHINA EURO AREA ASEAN JAPAN UK $20.8 $34.6 IN IN

Norwich Economic Papers Volume 6 (June 2012)

Making Growth Work for the Poor: The Challenge of Inclusive Growth

BBB3633 Malaysian Economics

The Comparative Advantage of Nations: Shifting Trends and Policy Implications

WESTERN BALKANS COUNTRIES IN FOCUS OF GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS

Global Economic Prospects 2004: Realizing the Development Promise of the Doha Agenda

ASIAN TRANSFORMATIONS: An Inquiry into the Development of Nations

3 1-1 GDP GDP growth rate Population size Labor force Labor participation rate Employed population

Declining Industries, Mechanisms of Structural Adjustment, and Trade Policy in Pacific Basin Economies. Hugh Patrick. Working Paper No.

Oxfam Education

What Thailand Needs to Do to Become a High-Income Country

Services Trade Liberalization between the European Union and Africa Caribbean and Pacific Countries: A Dynamic Approach

Online Consultation for the Preparation of the Tajikistan Systematic Country Diagnostic. Dushanbe, Tajikistan March 2017

GDP Per Capita. Constant 2000 US$

Malaysia experienced rapid economic

Trade led Growth in Times of Crisis Asia Pacific Trade Economists Conference 2 3 November 2009, Bangkok. Session 13

The IISD Global Subsidies Initiative Barriers to Reforming Fossil Fuel Subsidies: Lessons Learned from Asia

Trade Policy in PRC and India in the New Era of Slower World Growth:

Global Trends in Wages

Arndt-Corden Department of Economics Public Lecture. Australian National University, Canberra, 23 May 2017

East Asian Currency Union

Market Openness & The Labor Market

Trade, informality and jobs. Kee Beom Kim ILO Regional Office for Asia and the Pacific

Report. This version available at: Originally available from LSE IDEAS. Available in LSE Research Online: May 2012

GROUP OF FIFTEEN The Summit Level Group of Developing Countries

Analyzing the Nature and Quantifying the Magnitude of the Employment Linkage 03

THE MACROECONOMIC IMPACT OF REMITTANCES IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES. Ralph CHAMI Middle East and Central Asia Department The International Monetary Fund

Economic Outlook and Macro Economic Policies

THE AEC PROGRESS, CHALLENGES AND PROSPECTS

The role of the private sector in generating new investments, employment and financing for development

COMMENTS ON L. ALAN WINTERS, TRADE LIBERALISATION, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND POVERTY

GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS & GENDER EQUALITY THREATS, OPPORTUNITIES AND NECESSITIES

Transcription:

Asia Pacific School of Economics and Government WORKING PAPERS world trade organization P olicy challenges for developing economies under the WTO Bhanupong Nidhiprabha 03-12 Asia Pacific School of Economics and Government THE AUSTRALIAN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY http://apsem.anu.edu.au

Asia Pacific Press 2003 page 2 Asia Pacific Press 2003 This work is copyright. Apart from those uses which may be permitted under the Copyright Act 1968 as amended, no part may be reproduced by any process without written permission from the publisher. The opinions contained in the series are those of the authors, and not necessarily of the Asia Pacific School of Economics and Government at The Australian National University. ISSN 1447-9486 Bhanupong Nidhiprabha, Thammasat University, Bangkok This paper was presented at a workshop 'WTO: issues for developing countries' at the 46th Annual Conference of the Australian Agricultural and Resource Economics Society (AARES) in Canberra, 13 15 February 2002. Key to symbols used in tables n.a. not applicable.. not available - zero. insignificant Abbreviations ADB BOT FDI IMF NEER REER Asian Development Bank Bank of Thailand foreign direct investment International Monetary Funds Nominal effective exchange rate Real effective exchange rate

Asia Pacific Press 2003 page 3 Policy challenges for developing countries under the WTO Economic development involves a transformation from traditional to modern, which can raise per capita income and improve quality of life. Engagement in international trade tends to hasten this transformation, however it does not fully ensure successful economic development. As well as undertaking trade reform through WTO agreements, developing countries need to create and implement complementary domestic policies. This paper examines Thailand, in order to identify challenges faced by developing countries in this respect, and makes recommendations about how to minimise the undesirable consequences of trade liberalisation. Protectionism and WTO negotiations Both industrial and developing countries use tariff and non-tariff barriers to protect their economies from foreign competition. After eight rounds of trade negotiations, tariff rates on manufactures have been brought down to their current low level. A study by Hertel and Martin (2000) shows that tariff walls for agricultural products remain higher than for manufactured products (Table 1). This is true for both high-income and low-income countries. Degree of agricultural production remains high in developing countries, who are understandably reluctant to negotiate for the reduction of agricultural tariff rates, however this is also true for industrial countries, who have much to gain from agricultural trade negotiations. In 1995, the total implied value of tariff on imported agricultural products collected by industrial countries was $53 billion, compared to $34 billion collected by developing countries. Despite obvious efficiency gains, special-interest groups with powerful lobbying machines still hamper negotiations. Since tariff revenues are predominantly raised from imports of manufactured goods, developing countries have a lot more to lose than industrial countries. In 1995, the total implied value of tariffs on imported manufactured goods collected by developing countries was $160 billion, while that collected by industrial countries was $39 billion. These figures imply that the road to agricultural trade liberalisation will be long and rough. Industrial countries can usually afford price distortions in their economies, but developing countries tend to be constrained by their tax capacity. The tariff revenues developing countries obtain from manufactured goods tend to be higher than those they obtain from agricultural products, because developing countries are net importers of manufactured goods. Since they are food producing countries, they have good reason to be afraid of competition from more efficient farmers in industrial countries. Furthermore, production and export subsidies in industrial countries tend to be much higher than developing countries can afford. As comparative advantage shifts towards skilled labour intensive products, competition between domestic and foreign manufacturers becomes more intense. According to Martin and Ianchovichina (2001), the number of anti-dumping initiations taken against China, Korea and Taiwan between 1995 and 1996 was 137, 75 and 47 respectively. For the European Union and the United States, the number was 179 and 66. Measured as an index of initiations per dollar value of exports, the severity of anti-dumping measures can be seen from Table 2, where the index of 100 corresponds to anti-dumping measures taken against Japan.

Asia Pacific Press 2003 page 4 Table 1 Average tariffs and implied tariffs in industrial and developing countries, 1995 Importing region Exporting region Manufactures Industrial 0.8 ($16b) 10.9 ($93b) Developing 3.4 ($23b) 12.8 ($57b) Agricultural Industrial 15.9 ($37b) 21.5 ($20b) Developing 15.1 ($16b) 18.3 ($14b) Source: Hertel, T.W. and Martin, W., 2000. Liberalizing agriculture and manufactures in a millennium round: implications for developing countries, The World Economy, 23:455 69. Table 2 Anti-dumping initiations against rich and poor countries, 1995 99 Number Initiations per exports* India 38 1079 China 137 776 Indonesia 36 691 Korea 75 564 Thailand 30 509 Taiwan 47 386 European Union 179 106 United States 66 105 Japan 44 100 Australia 3 56 Note: * Exports in $US, Japan = 100 Source: Martin, W. and Ianchovichina, E., 2001. Implications of China s accession to the World Trade Organization for China and the WTO, The World Economy, 24(9):1,205 19. Economic recession has usually been followed by increased protectionism, as the history of US trade policy attests, and the global slowdown of 2001 would have significantly encouraged the use and abuse of anti-dumping measures. Clearly, antidumping measures are now widely accepted as tools of domestic protection, and the WTO must endeavour to abolish them, since they can actually become enemies to growth and development. The majority of anti-dumping initiations have been taken not to counteract predatory behaviour but to hamper competition from more efficient foreign exporters. The WTO dispute settlement process must be made fairer. According to Hoekman and Mavroidis (2000), developing countries are underrepresented in dispute settlement. Between April 1994 and March 1999, the great majority of cases involved the United States and the European Union (Table 3). Developing countries are obviously at a disadvantage in dispute settlement. Stiglitz (2000) argues that the principles of fairness and comprehensiveness in trade negotiations must be upheld if developing countries are to return to the negotiating tables. Otherwise, proponents of inward-oriented policies would declare relations between industrial and developing countries to be exploitative and conflicting. A comprehensive approach to negotiations implies that many different aspects of policy reform are considered simultaneously. Athukorala (2000) has suggested that the WTO should coordinate with

Asia Pacific Press 2003 page 5 Table 3 WTO dispute settlement (number of cases), April 1994 March 1999 Complainant Respondent United States 54 30 European Union 43 26 India 8 12 Japan 7 12 Thailand 4 1 Australia 2 6 Philippines 2 2 Korea 2 10 Malaysia 1 1 Indonesia 1 4 Sri Lanka 1 0 Source: Hoekman, B.M. and Mavroidis, P.C., 2000. WTO dispute settlement, transparency and surveillance, The World Economy, 23:527 42. other international financial development institutions, which could provide loans to be used to relieve the high adjustment costs of agricultural reform. Trade reform and development: the case of Thailand Thailand s economic development during the period 1970 2000 can be used to identify the salient features of the intricate nexus between trade and development. Since 1970, Thailand has undergone a gradual transformation from a predominantly agricultural economy to one whose growth is led mainly by manufactured exports (Figure 1). In the early 1980s, rising manufacturing output exceeded falling agricultural output. The structure of exports followed a similar pattern of change (Figure 2). This is a stylised scenario that has occurred in many developing countries during the early stages of economic development. The greater the degree of a country s involvement in the global economy, the faster its structural changes in output, trade and employment. The crossover points for shares of agriculture and manufacturing in output, export and employment are indicators of the degree of economic development. Korea and Taiwan reached these crossover points long before Thailand, and both countries were able to benefit from market access to industrial countries. At the same time, these two countries implemented domestic policies that enabled them to exploit their comparative advantages. It should be noted that countries comparative advantages are changing, reflecting changing endowment and rising costs of production. Thailand has lost its comparative advantage in primary commodities to other less-developed developing countries, however its comparative advantage has shifted towards high value added agricultural products. Since profitability dictates the movement of resources among sectors (Figure 3), the manufacturing sector is not able to generate as much employment as the non-traded sector, which has attracted capital inflows and domestic credit extension in response to higher relative product prices. Although many agricultural labourers have migrated into the nontraded sector, the majority remain in agriculture. The employment structure in Thailand differs greatly from the employment structures in Taiwan and South Korea. Given similar per capita income, the South Korean and

Asia Pacific Press 2003 page 6 Figure 1 Structural output changes in the Thai economy, 1984 2001 80 Percentage of total employment 60 40 20 Non-tradables Agriculture Manufactures 0 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 Source: Bank of Thailand, n.d. Quarterly Bulletin, Various issues, The Economic Research Department, Bank of Thailand, Bangkok, Available online at http://www.bot.or.th/bothomepage/databank/articlesandpublications/ quarter_report_e.htm. Figure 2 The rising importance of Thailand s manufactures exports, 1977 2000 90 Percentage of total exports 60 30 Manufactures Agriculture 0 1977 1981 1985 1989 1993 1997 Source: Bank of Thailand, n.d. Quarterly Bulletin, Various issues, The Economic Research Department, Bank of Thailand, Bangkok, Available online at http://www.bot.or.th/bothomepage/databank/articlesandpublications/ quarter_report_e.htm.

Asia Pacific Press 2003 page 7 Figure 3 Shifts in Thailand s employment structure, 1984 2001 80 Percentage of total employmen 60 40 20 Agriculture Non-tradables Manufactures 0 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 Source: For 1972 93, Asian Development Bank, 1996. Key Indicators of Developing Asian and Pacific Countries, Vol. XXVII, Asian Development Bank, Manila; for 1993 99, National Statistical Office of Thailand, 2001. Labour Force Survey, Table 9: Number of Employed Persons by Industry and Sex, 1989 2000, Social Statistics Division, National Statistical Office of Thailand, Bangkok. Available online at http://www.nso.go.th/ eng/stat/lfstab9.html. Taiwanese industrial sectors have been able to absorb more labour than the industrial sector in Thailand. If agricultural sector productivity remains low, loss of comparative advantage may become a problem, leading to unemployment, migration, poverty and increased income disparities. According to Warr (2000), protection in the Thai agricultural sector remains at a higher level than protection in the manufacturing sector, which has undergone drastic tariff reform since 1994. It is possible that the low productivity of the Thai agricultural sector was caused by its high level of protection and lack of competition from outsiders. The manufacturing sector s capacity to pull labour from the agricultural sector is constrained by the level of export demand. If foreign direct investment (FDI) employs capital-intensive technology, the employment effects of capital flows will be minimal, and productivity differential among sectors will not improve income distribution. The reason labour-saving technology is used predominantly in the manufacturing sector has to do with the exchange rate and industrial promotion policy. Again, trade reform in the manufacturing sector can lead to impressive growth in exports and output, but other complementary policies must be implemented simultaneously in order to avoid unintended and undesirable outcomes. Since 1970, Thailand has followed outward-oriented policies. Figure 4 shows the negative relationship between the average tariff rate and trade intensity value the ratio of the combined values of exports and imports to GDP the latter rising from 26 per cent in

Asia Pacific Press 2003 page 8 1970 to 120 per cent in 2000. As Warr (2000) observes, Thailand has continued to adhere to the principles of trade liberalisation even after the 1997 currency crisis. Gradual reform was evident in the gradual decline of the average tariff rate since 1970, and a sharp cut in the average tariff rate occurred in the early 1970s, with mild stagnation in the late 1970s. It is expected that the average tax rate will be even lower after 2005, when tariff protection in normal tract industries is eliminated. One of Thailand s great policy mistakes was the premature liberalisation of the capital account in the early 1990s. Huge and rapid capital inflows created unsustainable booms and, together with weak financial institutions and inadequate financial supervision, the subsequent collapse of the fixed exchange rate economy. Figure 4 exhibits the degree of openness in the capital account as measured by the ratio of net capital flow to GDP. Rapid capital inflows actually became capital flight immediately after the poor export performance of 1996. A high degree of dependency on world trade and world capital markets can bring rapid growth but at the same time can have extreme negative effects during global recession. Export dependency and vulnerability If a country s economy is driven mainly by exports, the share of exports in its GDP will be very high, an acceptable situation as long as external conditions are favourable. In fact, between 1970 and 1995, Southeast Asian countries rapidly raised their per capita income by penetrating markets in developed countries, and these countries rapid rebound in 1999 2000 was due to robust growth in the United States. In 2001, however, Thailand experienced a growth rate of 1.5 per cent, or one-third of the 2000 growth rate, mainly because of the 2001 slump in the US economy, which had repercussions for the growth rate of the rest of the world. The ratio of Thailand s exports and services to GDP was 60 per cent, compared with less than 25 per cent for China. China s relatively low level of dependence on exports helped it moderate the decline in its growth rate from 8 to 7.3 per cent in 2001. Meanwhile small countries with large export shares in their GDP such as Hong Kong and Singapore suffered severely. Thus, increased globalisation through trade reform can lead to high levels of vulnerability to external shocks, and pro-trade countries must realise that the global economy is not immune to fluctuations in the output of major producers. China s accession to the WTO will increase its dependence on exports in the long run, however new WTO members can use their domestic policies to lessen the impact of external shocks. Protection of the domestic economy from global slowdown depends partly on the implementation of fiscal expansion policies, which are limited by public debt levels. The ability of the Thai government to engineer recovery is limited because its public debt is around 60 per cent of GDP, whereas China s is only 30 per cent of GDP. Thus, China can employ public spending to cushion the fall in export demand. Other countries that are subject to IMF conditionality or the Economic Union s requirement to keep budget deficit at a certain percentage of GDP will not be able to maintain the same level of aggregate demand in the face of export shortfalls. Financial discipline and fiscal prudence are therefore required to set a maximum level of public debt.

Asia Pacific Press 2003 page 9 Figure 4 Degree of openness and average tariff rate, 1970 2000 30 160 20 10 Average tariff rate Trade intensity (RHS) 120 80 0 1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998-10 Net capital flow/gdp 40-20 0 Source: Author s calculations based on Bank of Thailand, n.d. Quarterly Bulletin, Various issues, The Economic Research Department, Bank of Thailand, Bangkok, Available online at http://www.bot.or.th/bothomepage/ databank/articlesandpublications/quarter_report_e.htm. Figure 5 Effective exchange rates, relative producer prices of agriculture and industry, and relative prices of tradable and non-tradable goods, 1970 2000 115 Pagri/Pind (1976=100) 105 95 85 75 PT/PNT (1970=100) REER/NEER1/(1970=100) 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Note: 1 Nominal Effective Exchange Rate (NEER) is based on the annual average exchange rate between the baht and the currencies of Thailand s major trading partners. The currency weight is based on each country s average aggregate trade share (1985 2000) and the shares as Japan 35.5, U.S 31.3, Singapore 14.3, Malaysia 7.1, Germany 6.3 and U.K 5.4. Real Effective Exchange Rate (REER) is an adjustment to domestic versus foreign GDP deflators. Source: International Monetary Fund (IMF), n.d. International Financial Statistics, Statistics Department, IMF, Washington DC, Available online to subscribers at http://ifs.apdi.net/imf/; and Bank of Thailand, n.d. Quarterly Bulletin, Various issues, The Economic Research Department, Bank of Thailand, Bangkok, Available online at http://www.bot.or.th/bothomepage/databank/articlesandpublications/quarter_report_e.htm.

Asia Pacific Press 2003 page 10 Loss of tariff revenue after trade reform Because low per capita income and inefficient tax administration in developing countries tend to hamper direct taxation, these countries derive most of their tax revenues from trade and indirect taxes. Compared to income taxes, trade taxes are particularly important for low-income countries on account of their lower collection costs and lesser susceptibility to tax evasion. Taxes on agricultural exports and manufactured imports are vital to the fiscal health of low-income developing countries. Trade liberalisation entails losses in revenue and can significantly reduce budgetary funds allocated to the building of infrastructure. This is why gradual reform is preferable to a big-bang approach. As Huang et al. (2000) have pointed out, since 1980 China has reformed its agricultural sector gradually. As a result, China s accession to the WTO has not caused great disruption and has had only a modest impact on output and rural incomes. Following this example, other developing countries should not have to fear the possibility of a renminbi devaluation. When labour migrates to the manufacturing and service sectors, the structure of taxation generally evolves towards greater reliance on direct taxes. Thus, developing countries need to find alternatives to trade taxes, such as value-added taxes. Fear of tariff revenue loss may be unfounded, since revenue from corporate income taxes can offset the decline in customs revenues, provided trade actually enhances growth. Export taxes are instruments of inward-oriented development strategy, which gives unequal incentives to domestic and foreign product supply. In addition, export taxes tend to have a strong redistributive effect, with people working in the agricultural sector and living below the poverty line generally the most affected. To sum up, developing countries need to overhaul their tax systems so as to prevent volatile trade volumes from affecting their finances. Declining terms of trade and income distribution The increased efficiency of production and consumption and improved terms of trade involved in trade reform can give rise to significant welfare gains, however the terms of trade may move in favour of the manufactures exporting countries as opposed to agricultural product exporting countries. In Thailand, for example, between 1993 and 1996, the terms of trade between agricultural products and manufactures improved, and income inequality was reduced to its lowest-ever level. Since labour s share in agriculture remained very large, however, deteriorating terms of trade in agriculture after 1996 led to increased income inequality. The implication of worsening terms of trade is therefore quite clear: they can profoundly affect income inequality. Furthermore, declining terms of trade have a negative impact on the balance of trade and can hamper poverty eradication. In the face of falling agricultural export prices, developing countries might form cartels in order to shore up their agricultural export prices. Some Southeast Asian countries have substantial shares in world trade of rubber, rice and coffee, and are therefore tempted to form cartels for these products. It is worth mentioning, however, that cartels have their own inherent problems, for example production control and monitoring. In the short run, when export demand is low, cartels can temporarily reverse price declines, however if substitutes are developed then the cartels might lose their markets permanently.

Asia Pacific Press 2003 page 11 Trade and capital account liberalisation can contribute to positive growth and poverty alleviation in developing countries, however the impact on income distribution can be both positive and negative. If labour is paid for the value of its marginal product, capital control liberalisation can raise the marginal productivity of labour in capital-intensive sectors. Income distribution can be worsened if distribution of capital goods is skewed towards modern sectors, where labour productivity is high because of a high ratio of capital to labour, achieved through FDI and credit concentration. Unequal distribution of money and physical capital due to capital liberalisation can increase income inequality. Furthermore, if the price of non-traded goods rises relative to that of traded goods because of Dutch disease, then income disparity between workers in the non-traded sector and traded sector can widen. Labour migration, urban poverty and political instability can complicate development in countries that suddenly open themselves up to foreign capital. In 1989, the top bottom ratio of the national income of the richest 20 per cent of countries to that of the poorest 20 per cent was 59, indicating great inequality. Different measures of income inequality also point to increasing income inequality among nations, and Wade (2001) argues that global organisations like the World Bank and the WTO should seriously address the issue. Developing countries need to be aware that ushering a national economy into the global economy does not automatically reduce national income inequality, nor is it certain that open-door policies to trade and foreign investment will enable developing countries to bring their living standards up to the level of those of industrial countries. Parallel policy preparation To prevent unintended and undesirable outcomes of trade liberalisation, developing countries must create new economic policies in keeping with the changing economic environment. The lesson from the 1997 currency crisis in Thailand is that the fixed exchange rate regime is incompatible with a world of high capital mobility. The fixed exchange rate or currency board can produce price stability for periods, as in the case of Argentina between 1991 and 2001, but it cannot work indefinitely in a volatile environment of international trade and investment. Developing countries need to gradually adjust their exchange rates to reflect differentials between domestic and foreign inflation rates. Figure 5 shows how overvaluation of the baht began in 1985 and continued up until the crisis in 1997. There is thus reason to doubt the sustainability of remaining fixed exchange rate economies like China and Hong Kong. A flexible exchange rate can mitigate the impact of external shocks, and a gradual shift from a fixed to a flexible exchange rate regime as in the case of Australia in the 1980s would incur lower adjustment costs than Thailand s sudden jump into the float currency. According to the WTO, Southeast Asian nations have nothing to fear from China s accession (Supachai and Clifford 2002). The main reasons for Southeast Asian businessmen to fear China s accession to the WTO are the low costs of Chinese labourintensive production, the end of textile quotas, and the possible diversion of FDI away from Southeast Asia towards China. In order to assuage this fear, Supachai and Clifford (2002) cite a study that shows a positive correlation between FDI in China and FDI in Southeast Asia. It should be noted, however, that such a positive correlation can result

Asia Pacific Press 2003 page 12 from a scale effect due to enlarged world capital fund portfolios. Distribution of FDI flow depends very much on relative rates of return in different regions. Because of the shift in the production structure of manufactures exports from labour-intensive to skilled labourintensive products, FDI flows these days are attracted not by low wage rates as in the 1970s, but largely by pools of skilled labour (Noorbakhsh et al. 2001). Since FDI now flows to places where human capital is abundant, developing countries wanting to attract FDI must increase public spending on human capital and education. Conclusion Negotiations to reduce trade barriers in agriculture will prove more difficult than those to reduce tariff barriers in manufactures. Anti-dumping measures have too often been used as disguised protection. The WTO dispute settlement process is not likely to succeed unless both developing and industrial countries adhere to the principle of fairness. Trade liberalisation through WTO commitments can significantly alter developing countries production and employment structures, and developing countries will undoubtedly encounter problems of job destruction in sectors with comparative disadvantage. Although export-led growth can reduce poverty, it can also increase income inequality. In addition, integration into the global economy can heighten vulnerability to negative external shocks. Developing countries must create new macroeconomic policies in anticpation of the adverse consequences of trade liberalisation. References Asian Development Bank, 1996. Key Indicators of Developing Asian and Pacific Countries, Vol. XXVII, Asian Development Bank, Manila Athukorala, P., 2000. Agricultural trade policy in South Asia: the role of the Uruguay Round and policy options for the future WTO agenda, Journal of Asian Economics, 11(2):169 94. Bank of Thailand, n.d. Quarterly Bulletin, Various issues, The Economic Research Department, Bank of Thailand, Bangkok, Available online at http://www.bot.or.th/ bothomepage/databank/articlesandpublications/quarter_report_e.htm. Hertel, T.W. and Martin, W., 2000. Liberalizing agriculture and manufactures in a millennium round: implications for developing countries, The World Economy, 23:455 69. Hoekman, B.M. and Mavroidis, P.C., 2000. WTO dispute settlement, transparency and surveillance, The World Economy, 23:527 42. Huang, J., Rozelle, S. and Linxiu, Z., 2000. WTO and agriculture: radical reforms or the continuation of gradual transition, China Economic Review, 11(4):397 402. International Monetary Fund (IMF), n.d. International Financial Statistics, Statistics Department, IMF, Washington DC, Available online to subscribers at http:// ifs.apdi.net/imf/.

Asia Pacific Press 2003 page 13 Martin, W. and Ianchovichina, E., 2001. Implications of China s accession to the World Trade Organization for China and the WTO, The World Economy, 24(9):1205 19. National Statistical Office of Thailand, 2001. Labour Force Survey, Table 9: Number of Employed Persons by Industry and Sex, 1989 2000, Social Statistics Division, National Statistical Office of Thailand, Bangkok, Available online at http:// www.nso.go.th/eng/stat/lfstab9.html. Noorbakhsh, F., Palioni, A. and Youssef, A., 2001. Human capital and FDI inflows to developing countries: new empirical evidence, World Development, 29(9):1593 610. Panitchpakdi, S. and Clifford, M.L., 2002. China and the WTO: changing China, changing world trade, John Wiley, Singapore. Stiglitz, J.E., 2000. Two principles for the next round, or How to bring developing countries in from the cold, The World Economy, 23(4):437 54. Timothy, J., 2000. The agricultural negotiations: an overflowing agenda, Review of Federal Reserve Bank of Saint Louis, 82(4):53 72. Wade, R.H., 2001. The rising inequality of world income distribution Finance and Development, December:37 9. Warr, P.G., 2000. Thailand s post-crisis trade policies: the 1999 WTO review, The World Economy, 23(9):1215 36.