Corruption: Winner Takes All

Similar documents
DEFINING AND MEASURING CORRUPTION AND ITS IMPACT

What is corruption? Corruption is the abuse of power for private gain (TI).

Lobbying and Bribery

Chapter 7 Institutions and economics growth

CORRUPTION & POVERTY IN NIGERIA

The spectre of corruption

Corruption: Costs and Mitigation Strategies

Governance, Corruption, and Public Finance: An Overview

It is the responsibility of all Fletcher Personnel to understand and comply with this Policy, including any reporting requirements set out below.

THE CORRUPTION AND THE ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE

Forms of Civic Engagement and Corruption

Why Does Inequality Matter? T. M. Scanlon. Chapter 8: Unequal Outcomes. It is well known that there has been an enormous increase in inequality in the

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Executive summary 2013:2

Corruption Spotlight. GOVERNANCE and THE LAW BACKGROUND NOTE. Mushtaq H. Khan University of London. Public Disclosure Authorized

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis

rules, including whether and how the state should intervene in market activity.

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES?

Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees

Corruption: Causes and consequences

IEP Risk and Peace. Institute for Economics and Peace. Steve Killelea, Executive Chairman. Monday, 18th November 2013 EIB, Luxemburg

Measurement and Global Trends in Central Bank Autonomy (CBA)

PRIVATIZATION AND INSTITUTIONAL CHOICE

China Thrives Despite Corruption

CODING: Words stricken are deletions; words underlined are additions. hb er

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Testimony to the United States Senate Budget Committee Hearing on Opportunity, Mobility, and Inequality in Today's Economy April 1, 2014

Transparency, Accountability and Citizen s Engagement

Section 1: Microeconomics. 1.1 Competitive Markets: Demand and Supply. IB Econ Syllabus Outline. Markets Ø The Nature of Markets

Chinese Economic Reform from an International Perspective

CORRUPTION AND OPTIMAL LAW ENFORCEMENT. A. Mitchell Polinsky Steven Shavell. Discussion Paper No /2000. Harvard Law School Cambridge, MA 02138

Thinkwell s Homeschool Economics Course Lesson Plan: 36 weeks

Testing Leniency Programs Experimentally

Hungary. Basic facts The development of the quality of democracy in Hungary. The overall quality of democracy

The Effects of Corruption on Government Expenditures: Arab Countries Experience

Governance Review Paper Section IV: Does Corruption Matter?

The water services crisis is essentially a crisis of governance

Measuring and Reducing the Impact of Corruption in Infrastructure

Annex B. Application of Chapter Five and Relationship to other Chapters

Yet the World Bank Enterprise Surveys suggest that there is much room for improvement in service quality and accountability

Regulation and Regulatory Environment: Case Study of Bhutan

Is Malawi losing the battle against Cashgate?

STUDY OF PRIVATE SECTOR PERCEPTIONS OF CORRUPTION

Boris Divjak Director of U4 Anti-Corruption Resource Centre (Bergen, Norway) Transparency International School on Integrity, Vilnius 07 July 2015

Corruption in Kenya, 2005: Is NARC Fulfilling Its Campaign Promise?

The Corporate Value of (Corrupt) Lobbying

CORRUPTION PERCEPTIONS INDEX CORRUPTION PERCEPTIONS INDEX (CPI) 2015 SURVEY RESULTS

An Examination of China s Development Factors and Governance Indicators over the Period

» Be aware of the complexity of the causes and cures for. » Understand that controlling white-collar crime is one of our

The Concept of Human Development Index

Corruption and Good Governance

CREATING A LEARNING SOCIETY. Joseph E. Stiglitz The London School of Economics and Political Science The Amartya Sen Lecture June 2012

Chapter 9 Investment, Trade in Services and Temporary Entry of Business Persons. Section A Investment

The Way Forward: Pathways toward Transformative Change

The 2017 TRACE Matrix Bribery Risk Matrix

Optimizing Foreign Aid to Developing Countries: A Study of Aid, Economic Freedom, and Growth

Tourism, Poverty and Taxation: A Case of Thailand

Stocktaking report on business integrity and anti-bribery legislation, policies and practices in twenty african countries

LEBANON - A MODEL FOR BUSINESS IN THE MIDDLE EAST

The State, the Market, And Development. Joseph E. Stiglitz World Institute for Development Economics Research September 2015

BRIBERY ACT 2010: JOINT PROSECUTION GUIDANCE OF THE DIRECTOR OF THE SERIOUS FRAUD OFFICE AND THE DIRECTOR OF PUBLIC PROSECUTIONS

The Political Challenges of Economic Reforms in Latin America. Overview of the Political Status of Market-Oriented Reform

Democracy or Dictatorship: Does It Make a Difference?

CORRUPTION AND GOVERNMENT. Lessons for Portugal Susan Rose-Ackerman

Discussion Paper Series A No.533

Economic Assistance to Russia: Ineffectual, Politicized, and Corrupt?

ANTI-BRIBERY POLICY 1 POLICY STATEMENT

COLLECTIVE ACCOUNTABILITY THE KEY TO SUCCESSFUL POLICY IMPLEMENTATION

The Transparency International

CHAPTER 1 Introduction: BRIC and the World Economy

CORRUPTION AND VIOLENT CONFLICT

Globalization and its Impact on Poverty in Pakistan. Sohail J. Malik Ph.D. Islamabad May 10, 2006

Property Rights and the Rule of Law

The abuse of entrusted power by public officials in their

Corruption and Political System

Achieving Corporate Integrity

C. THE FIGHT AGAINST CORRUPTION IN THE ECONOMY

Gertrude Tumpel-Gugerell: The euro benefits and challenges

The Emerging Powerhouse: Opportunities, Trends & Risks of the African Economic Climate

Market failures. If markets "work perfectly well", governments should just play their minimal role, which is to:

CHAPTER 9 TRADE IN SERVICES. commercial presence means any type of business or professional establishment, including through:

Best Buy Anti-Corruption Policy

(ii) sufficient transparency, fair competition and adequate ex-ante publicity must be ensured;

Copyright is owned by the Author of the thesis. Permission is given for a copy to be downloaded by an individual for the purpose of research and

REVITALIZING OUR DEMOCRATIC FABRIC

CORRUPTION AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT. EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPEAN STATES

Domestic Structure, Economic Growth, and Russian Foreign Policy

Mohammad Ghodsi: Summary of Ph.D. Dissertation Trade Policy, Trade Conflicts, Determinants, and Consequences of Protectionism

Evidence from Randomized Evaluations of Governance Programs. Cristobal Marshall

2017 SADC People s Summit Regional Debates and Public Speaking Gala. Strengthening Youth Participation in Policy Dialogue Processes

Spring. ECTS 7.5 Prerequisites. Dr. Ioannis Karkalis Supreme Court Justice Director Director of the EPLO Academy for Transparency and Human Rights

Andrew L. Stoler 1 Executive Director Institute for International Business, Economics and Law // //

The Intergenerational Persistence of Attitudes toward Corruption

Mixed system: Proportional representation. Single majority system for 5 single-member constituencies (two cantons, three half-cantons).

Chapter 9 - Trade in Services

Sources of information on corruption in Ethiopia

1. Why has the official tolerance for corruption declined during the past decade, in so many countries and institutions around the world?

THE GENDER DIMENSION OF CORRUPTION

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEWS

Please do not cite or distribute. Dealing with Corruption in a Democracy - Phyllis Dininio

Transcription:

Entry #1123 Undergraduate 2199 Words Corruption: Winner Takes All Part A: Understanding Corruption Introduction Assessing the strength of an economy largely concerns its ability, given a finite set of resources, to maximise the cumulative welfare of its society. The mechanisms by which economies maximise welfare are formed through institutional policy. Institutions determine, amongst other things: the cost of economic transactions, the degree to which cooperation is conducive, and most pertinently, the extent to which the law is enforced (Ferrini, 2012). Hence, it is of great concern to policy makers and economic participants as to what extent institutions in the economy are corruptible. Corruption is understood to be the abuse of vested power for personal gain. Vested power describes power conferred upon an agent by a wider interest group. Institutional operatives possess varying degrees of vested power by virtue of election, appointment or otherwise. Van Duyne (2001: 2) offers more precisely that corruption occurs where a decision maker has the power to illegally deviate from the rules which regulate their decisions, in exchange for some gain. At this stage it becomes apparent that corruption exhibits features resembling those of a typical principal-agent conflict. Where corruption is possible, there exists a potential asymmetry between the actions of powerbearers and the resultant outcomes for their constituents. In this paper an analysis of corruption will be conducted. This analysis will commence by exploring existing literature on corruption, so as to justify corruption as a point of contention. Thereafter, a model will be developed from which the mechanics of corruption can be understood. Through this model, the fiscal and economic consequences of corruption will be examined. 1 of 10

Types of Corruption Contemporary works tend to focus on two major types of corruption. Grand and bureaucratic (Jain, 2001: 3-5). Grand corruption describes the manipulation of power by political elites so as to exploit public resources for their own interests. Where it is most pervasive, grand corruption leads to the normalisation of resource allocation in favour of areas where the gains from corruption are highest. Bureaucratic corruption concerns appointed officials and their dealings with the public. Often referred to as petty corruption, these incidents are usually of minimal societal consequence (Jain, 2001: 4). In these situations participants are either attempting to expedite bureaucratic processes or gain preferential access to services of which they are already entitled. Public and Private Sector Corruption While these designations all focus on holders of public office, by no means does that imply a mutual exclusivity between corruption and the private sector. Rather, in investigating the societal effects of corruption, it falls beyond the scope of this analysis to consider the private sector. Justification lies within 2 distinctions. The first concerns the fact that most private enterprises possess measures which discourage against largescale corruption, such as financial reporting standards along with comparatively finite resources. While a corrupted firm can run the risk of bankruptcy, incidents of public corruption seldom threaten the longevity of a government. The second aspect for consideration is that the public sector is financed by the collective contributions of society. As a firm has a duty towards the prudent allocation of shareholders capital, so too does a government have a duty to ensure the responsible deployment of society s resources. Moreover, while a firm s resources are typically predestined towards ends with purely financial gains, government expenditure is generally directed towards public goods intended to yield a societal benefit. From here it becomes sufficient that the focus on government arises out of a recognition of greater vulnerability to the damaging aspects of corruption. Motivations Underlying Corruption Continuing this investigation, it may also prove useful to consider reasons why institutional operatives engage in corruption. Cases of grand corruption usually feature an agent who possesses a monopoly over decision making power. This arrangement generally arises from situations where the agent is an ally political or otherwise of their theoretical supervisor (Jain 2001: 36). Aided by opaque measures of accountability, the monopolistic agent adopts 2 of 10

the role of sole enabler of progress. This power allows the agent to bargain for rents while competing interest groups lobby for progress. Jain (2001: 36) uses an example of the politically appointed head of the Lesotho Highlands Water Project, who manipulates their monopoly power to extract bribes from competing construction firms. When looking at bureaucratic corruption, the analysis of enabling factors requires an alternative approach. Nagano (2009) suggests that if it is true that economic agents are rational decision makers, then one might understand the logic underpinning acts of petty corruption. Most policies directed at altering behaviour carry some compliance benefit for both society and the individual (e.g. road safety and smoking legislation). This does not seem to be the case with anti-corruption measures, where there appears to be almost no individual benefit for compliance. Many cases of petty corruption, whilst allowing both parties the potential to gain, often present no obvious cost for the rest of society. This approach, by virtue of the imperfect information available to the corrupt parties, is particularly susceptible to societal externalities. In this situation one might also draw parallels to that of a prisoners dilemma. A corrupt bureaucratic official possesses a dominant strategy, which is personally inexpensive to enact, whilst simultaneously offering potential for reward. However, if every bureaucratic officer chose to pursue their dominant strategy, society would surely be worse-off. Part B: Corruption A Model Challenges in Measurement In an attempt to establish a model, it is worth noting that the illicit and secretive nature of corruption presents a considerable challenge to its empirical measurement. Without robust methods for measuring corruption, magnitudes cannot be quantified, theories cannot be tested and remedial policy cannot be assessed (Banerjee, Hanna and Mullainathan, 2012: 41). Where there is grand corruption, political players have the ability to manipulate their constituents by framing rent extractive policies as beneficial. These situations prove especially ambiguous when some in society genuinely do stand to benefit (Jain, 2001: 4). With petty corruption, most instances remain disguised due to the resource cost of investigation outweighing the value of the corruption. In attempting to measure corruption a common proxy usually manifests in the form of perception surveys. However, as Banerjee, Hanna and Mullainathan (2012: 44) note, the explanatory value of these rankings are at a loss when explaining the nature of the corruption affecting a particular country. The authors use 3 of 10

an example of the 2008 Transparency International Corruption Perceptions Index where Burkina Faso, Morocco and Thailand all score the same ranking. Buidling The Model The model supporting this analysis will hypothesise a corrupt individual s decision function and from there consider its bearing on the aggregate economy. The individual s gain function when contemplating corruption is a concept presented by Rose-Ackerman (1974: 3-4) where: G(X) = X J(X, p) R(X) Where: G = Net gains from corruption X = Gross gains from corruption (+; increases J and R) J = Penalty, if caught (-) p = Probability of detection (increases J) R = Moral cost of being corrupt (-) Where G is positive, the individual will choose to be corrupt. At this point it is appropriate to develop an additional tool which describes the marginal propensity for corruption (µ): Where for the individual (i): Y = Income without corruption µ i = Gi / Yi µ i 0 This effectively demonstrates how many times more lucrative corruption is for the individual. Note that the marginal propensity for corruption is only relevant where G(X) is positive. From here, society s marginal propensity for corruption can be derived as: µ s = (µi) / n µ s 0 Where n denotes the size of the corruptible population. With this knowledge, attention can be turned towards to general economy. The basic Keynesian model of a closed economy will be applied: Y = C(Y,T) + I + G (Here G is government) 4 of 10

From here the fiscal and economic effects of corruption can be assessed. At each stage of analysis, the model will be adjusted with the ultimate intention of motivating an economy represented by: Y = C(Y,T,µ) + I(µ) + G(µ) Fiscal Consequences Fiscal outcomes can be decomposed into the effects on government spending and taxation. Government expenditure provides a plausible conduit for assessing the effects of grand corruption. These cases often occur by way of intermittent special purpose projects such as infrastructure contracts or the sale of public assets. Given the inherent lack of precedence, the one-of-a-kind nature of these projects lends itself to an ambiguous price determination process (Rose-Ackerman and Truex, 2012: 24 25). As such, conventional anti-corruption frameworks prove insufficient when addressing the elements of these transactions which allow for the dispensation of rents (e.g. inflated costing). Banerjee, Hanna and Mullainathan (2012: 48 49) support this idea by highlighting the discrepancy between the reported expenditures on government projects in Uganda and China against the value of services beneficiaries claim to have received. In some cases, up to a 25% of the expenditure had gone missing. Dzhumashev (2013: 13) goes as far as to conclude that, by similar reasoning where corruption is ubiquitous, an increase in government spending generally leads to a decrease in GDP growth. Given these findings the model can be amended to reflect: Y = C(Y,T) + I + G(µ) Y = C(Y,T) + I + G 0 + Gc /µ Where: G 0 = Autonomous government expenditure G c = Corruptible government expenditure With respect to taxation, the underlying assumption is that economic participants comply with the belief that their payment represents their contribution towards society. However, when perceptions of public resource wastage increase, consumers willingness to pay taxes has been shown to decrease (Hadjipaschalis, 2014). Furthermore, Fitzsimons (2007: 7) shows that where corruption is prevalent, businesses take measures to withdraw their affairs from the formal economy in an effort to avoid the jurisdiction of rent seeking policies. It is 5 of 10

therefore apparent that corruption has a corrosive effect on the tax base. This is significant because in the face of a revenue shortfall government sacrifices future revenues by accruing higher debt levels (Ivanya, Moumouras and Rangazas, 2015: 30). The model now adopts the form: Y = C(Y,T,µ) + I + G(µ) Y = C 0 + c(y T / µ ) + I + G(µ) Economic Consequences Economically, focus will placed be on investment. Corruption generally increases the cost of doing business whether it be through bribery or the distortion of regular processes. As such, it is plausible to accept that countries with high levels of corruption exhibit disproportionately lower levels of both foreign and domestic private investment (Wickberg, 2013: 2). Moreover, when engaging in corruption is necessary for firms to operate, the perception of a stagnant competitive environment also causes private investment to decrease (KPMG, 2016: 9). KPMG (2016: 9) further conclude that on average every one point increase in a country s corruption perceptions index corresponds to an 11% decrease in foreign direct investment. Therefore, adjusting the model yields: Y = C(Y,T,µ) + I(µ) + G(µ) Y = C(Y,T,µ) + I 0 + Ic / µ + G(µ) Where: I 0 = Autonomous investment expenditure I c = Corruptible investment expenditure Assessing The Model Although increased corruption visibly decreases the overall welfare of society, it is evident more so that corruption disproportionately disadvantages the poor. This is given by the poor s relatively higher dependence on the effective employment of public resources (Wickberg, 2013: 3). In addition, corruption has been shown to inflate the prices of government services such as public healthcare (Gupta, Davoodi and Tiongson, 2000: 3). Rose-Ackerman and Truex (2012: 3) confirm this idea of declining welfare by examining the strongly negative relationship between a country s perceived level of corruption and its Human Development Index. Reverting focus back to the model, the mechanisms underlying the development of the 6 of 10

prototype seem to hold true when compared to the work of Rothstein and Holmberg (2014). This conclusion is illustrated in Figure 1 which asserts a resilient positive relationship between the quality of government (a proxy for corruption) and GDP per capita. Figure 1: Relationship between GDP per capita and Quality of Government Source: (Rothstein and Holmberg, 2014: 6) Conclusions Public sector corruption is necessary to study given the evidence that society s welfare depends on the strength of its institutions. The personalised subversion of institutional resources so characteristic of corruption, results in the decay of institutional strength. Where institutions are weak, policies, no matter how well-crafted, are generally predisposed towards failure (Rose-Ackerman and Truex, 2012: 2). Notwithstanding the institutional effects, the impetus in this analysis gained further urgency when the power asymmetry between institutional operatives and society was highlighted. The corrupt dealings of one agent can result in disproportionate and unintended welfare outcomes for their constituents. Corruption however continues to remain clandestine in its nature and quantification. It is clear that in the 7 of 10

absence of credible institutions, corruption is certain to remain opaque and similarly, where corruption is ubiquitous, institutions are bound to remain weak. There was also a relationship established between corruption and the strength of an economy. The model established showed that the magnitude of corruption has negative effects on government spending, taxation revenues and private investment. Hence, it can be concluded that where a government seeks a robust economy, it is of paramount importance that corruption is curtailed at every level. For where there is no corruption, there seems to be no impediment to the maximisation of societal welfare. 8 of 10

References Banerjee, A., Hanna, R. & Mullainathan, S. (2012) Corruption, s.l.: Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Dzhumashev, R. (2013) The Two-Way Relationship Between Government Spending and Corruption and its Effect on Economic Growth. Contemporary Economic Policy, 32(2), p. 403 419. Ferrini, L. (2012) The Importance of Institutions to Economic Development. [Online] Available at: http://www.e-ir.info/2012/09/19/the-importance-of-institutions-to-economicdevelopment/ [2017, 29 April]. Fitzsimons, V. (2007) Economic models of corruption. In: Palgrave, ed. Corruption and Development: the anti-corruption campaigns. London: Palgrave. Gupta, S., Davoodi, H. & Tiongson, E. (2000) Corruption and The Provision of Health Care and Education Services, London: International Monetary Fund. Hadjipaschalis, R. (2014) KPMG. [Online] Available at: https://www.sablog.kpmg.co.za/2014/02/effect-corruption-tax-morality/ [2017, 3 May]. Ivanya, M., Moumouras, A. & Peter, R. (2015) Corruption, Public Debt, and Economic Growth. [Online] Available at: https://msu.edu/~ivanynam/research/corr_debt/ivanyna_mourmouras_rangazas_corrupti on_public_debt_2015.pdf [Accessed 3 May 2017]. Jain, A. (2001) Corruption: A Review. Journal of Economic Surveys, 15(1), pp. 71-117. KPMG (2016) The impact of corruption. [Online] Available at: https://assets.kpmg.com/content/dam/kpmg/za/pdf/2017/03/corruption- TL.pdf [2017, 9 May]. Nagano, F. (2009) Corruption, Game Theory, and Rational Irrationality. [Online] Available at: https://blogs.worldbank.org/publicsphere/corruption-game-theory-andrational-irrationality [2017, 2 May]. Rose-Ackerman, S. (1974) The Economics of Corruption. Journal of Public Economics, July, Volume 4, pp. 187-203. Rose-Ackerman, S. & Truex, R. (2012)Corruption and Policy Reform, New Haven: Yale Law School. Rothstein, B. & Holmberg, S. (2014) Correlates of Quality Government. [Online] Available at: http://qog.pol.gu.se/digitalassets/1510/1510680_correlates-of-quality-ofgovernment.pdf 9 of 10

[2017, 3 May]. van Duyne, P. (2001) Will Caligula go transparant (sic.)? Corruption in acts & attitudes. Forum on Crime and Society, 1(2), pp. 73-98. Wickberg, S. (2013) Literature review on costs of corruption for the poor, s.l.: Transparency International. 10 of 10