The Great Hyperinflations in History: An Austrian School Perspective

Similar documents
Zimbabwe: A Story of Hyperinflation in the 21 st Century

RESTRICTED. COUNCIL Original: English/ 12 May 1993 French/ Spanish

As Joseph Stiglitz sees matters, the euro suffers from a fatal. Book Review. The Euro: How a Common Currency. Journal of FALL 2017

THE EPISTEMOLOGY OF THE AUSTRIAN SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS AND THE PROBLEM OF EMPIRICSM IN ECONOMIC THOUGHT

ECO 171S: Hayek and the Austrian Tradition Syllabus

International Trade Union Confederation Pan-European Regional Council (PERC) CONSTITUTION (as amended by 3 rd PERC General Assembly, 15 December 2015)

Overview of the Austrian School theories of capital and business cycles and implications for agent-based modeling

Topic Page: Hayek, Friedrich A. von (Friedrich August),

Economics 555 Potential Exam Questions

Cross-border Transactions of Individuals in 2010 BALANCE OF PAYMENTS DEPARTMENT

WILL CHINA S SLOWDOWN BRING HEADWINDS OR OPPORTUNITIES FOR EUROPE AND CENTRAL ASIA?

1. At the completion of this course, students are expected to: 2. Define and explain the doctrine of Physiocracy and Mercantilism

The economic outlook for Europe and Central Asia, including the impact of China

VISA POLICY OF THE REPUBLIC OF KAZAKHSTAN

LANGUAGE LEARNING MEASURES AND REQUIREMENTS FOR MIGRANTS: LATVIA

Will the US turn into a modern day Weimar Germany? Marshall Auerback

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 412 persons in December 2017, and 166 of these were convicted offenders.

The NPIS is responsible for forcibly returning those who are not entitled to stay in Norway.

International Summer Program

Why Monetary Freedom Matters Ron Paul

Gender pay gap in public services: an initial report

A Partial Solution. To the Fundamental Problem of Causal Inference

Hungarian-Ukrainian economic relations

HAS GROWTH PEAKED? 2018 growth forecasts revised upwards as broad-based recovery continues

World Refugee Survey, 2001

After the passing of its three

From Europe to the Euro Student Orientations 2014 Euro Challenge

4 Rebuilding a World Economy: The Post-war Era

Delays in the registration process may mean that the real figure is higher.

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) returned 444 persons in August 2018, and 154 of these were convicted offenders.

János Kornai s Contributions to Economic Analysis

Latin America in the New Global Order. Vittorio Corbo Governor Central Bank of Chile

UNHCR, United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees

SEPT 6, Fall of USSR and Yugoslavia Get out notebook, ESPN highlighters, and pencil

What factors have contributed to the significant differences in economic outcomes for former soviet states?

PAPER No. : Basic Microeconomics MODULE No. : 1, Introduction of Microeconomics

Contracting Parties to the Ramsar Convention

Human Action. Towards a Coordinationist Paradigm of Economics

Executive Summary. Figures provided by the U.S. Census Bureau 1 demonstrate that teen employment prospects are dismal:

THE NOWADAYS CRISIS IMPACT ON THE ECONOMIC PERFORMANCES OF EU COUNTRIES

A GAtewAy to A Bet ter Life Education aspirations around the World September 2013

4. Philip Cortney, The Economic Munich: The I.T.O. Charter, Inflation or Liberty, the 1929 Lesson (New York: Philosophical Library, 1949).

The Rise of Fascism and Communism. For the first time, war was waged on a global scale, leading to casualties and destruction on a

BULGARIAN TRADE WITH EU IN JANUARY 2017 (PRELIMINARY DATA)

BULGARIAN TRADE WITH EU IN THE PERIOD JANUARY - MARCH 2016 (PRELIMINARY DATA)

New York County Lawyers Association Continuing Legal Education Institute 14 Vesey Street, New York, N.Y (212)

From Europe to the Euro Student Orientations 2013 Euro Challenge

From Europe to the Euro

Political Economy Of Freedom: Essays In Honor Of Friedrich A. Von Hayek (The International Carl Menger Library) READ ONLINE

The present volume is an engaging and intriguing account. Book Review. How Global Currencies Work: Past, Present, and Future. Journal of SUMMER 2018

Global Consumer Confidence

Chapter 18 Development and Globalization

Prior to 1940, the Austrian School was known primarily for its contributions

Return of convicted offenders

From Europe to the Euro

ECON : Essentials of Economics. Macroeconomic Term Paper. War, what is it good for ₁

SEVERANCE PAY POLICIES AROUND THE WORLD

BULGARIAN TRADE WITH EU IN THE PERIOD JANUARY - JUNE 2014 (PRELIMINARY DATA)

Ludwig von Mises's Transformation of the. Austrian Theory of Value and Cost

PRICING BEHAVIOUR OF KAZAKH, RUSSIAN AND UKRAINIAN EXPORTERS IN THE INTERNATIONAL WHEAT MARKET

MONEY AS A GLOBAL PUBLIC GOOD

GLOBAL RISKS OF CONCERN TO BUSINESS WEF EXECUTIVE OPINION SURVEY RESULTS SEPTEMBER 2017

Schumpeter s Review of Frank A.

Policy Brief. Hyperinflations Are Rare, but a Breakup of the Euro Area Could Prompt One. Anders Åslund NUMBER PB12-22 NOVEMBER 2012

Carole Marsh/Gallopade International/Peachtree City, GA 2005 Paperback ISBN: Library Binding ISBN:

The recent financial crisis of generated a debate. Book Review. Monetary Regimes and Inflation: History, Economic, and Political

A2 Economics. Enlargement Countries and the Euro. tutor2u Supporting Teachers: Inspiring Students. Economics Revision Focus: 2004

Country Participation

UNITED NATIONS FINANCIAL PRESENTATION. UN Cash Position. 18 May 2007 (brought forward) Alicia Barcena Under Secretary-General for Management

Changes After Socialism*

a

Transition: Changes after Socialism (25 Years Transition from Socialism to a Market Economy)

From Europe to the Euro. Delegation of the European Union to the United States

Remittances in the Balance of Payments Framework: Problems and Forthcoming Improvements

Governing Body Geneva, March 2009

The present volume is an accomplished theoretical inquiry. Book Review. Journal of. Economics SUMMER Carmen Elena Dorobăț VOL. 20 N O.

PHILOSOPHY OF ECONOMICS & POLITICS

Translation from Norwegian

On June 2015, the council prolonged the duration of the sanction measures by six months until Jan. 31, 2016.

The Strategic Marketing Institute Working Paper

Feature Article. Policy Documentation Center

A REBALANCING ACT IN EMERGING EUROPE AND CENTRAL ASIA. April 17, 2015 Spring Meetings

As payments abroad grew faster, the deficit of cross-border transactions increased by 55% in 2008.

2018 BAVARIA S ECONOMY FACTS AND FIGURES

The Multidimensional Financial Inclusion MIFI 1

Lessons from Economies in Transition from Central Planning

Collective Bargaining in Europe

AMNESTY INTERNATIONAL REPORT 1997

Copyright Act - Subsidiary Legislation CHAPTER 311 COPYRIGHT ACT. SUBSIDIARY LEGlSLA non. List o/subsidiary Legislation

Trafficking in Persons

THE CZECH REPUBLIC AND THE EURO. Policy paper Europeum European Policy Forum May 2002

Comparison of the Roles of Neighboring Countries in the Foreign Trade of the USA, Germany and Turkey

Joshua Letta. Christopher Newport University

Total dimensions are the total world endowments of labor and capital.

EU DEVELOPMENT AID AND THE MILLENNIUM DEVELOPMENT GOALS

Health systems responses to the economic crisis in Europe

Chapter 11: Powers of Congress Section 1

Be afraid of the Chinese bearing gifts

Wartime Conferences T H E E A R L Y C O L D W A R

Letter prices in Europe. Up-to-date international letter price survey. March th edition

Transcription:

The Great Hyperinflations in History: An Austrian School Perspective Dimitrios N. Koumparoulis, Professor of Economic Theory UGSM-Monarch Business School Switzerland Dionysios K. Solomos, Professor of European Economic Policy UGSM-Monarch Business School Switzerland Abstract The paper attempts to approach the circumstances surrounding the great hyperinflations in world history and to summarize what the literature or documentation have revealed on the origin of hyperinflations and how they can be addressed. We focus on the basic principles of Austrian School in order to address our concerns on the matter of inflation and hyperinflation. Proponents of Austrian School state that prices and values exist in the minds of the individuals and considered to be subjective. Austrian economists argue that increases in supply of money, credit and shortage of goods are the sources behind inflation. Both money supply and expectations can lead to a hyperinflationary situation. Introduction According to Hanke (2008a, p. 2), hyperinflation is defined as a rate of inflation per month that exceeds 50 percent. Episodes of hyperinflations are rare and they do not take place when money has been commodity-based or when paper money has been convertible into a commodity (Hanke, 2008b).There have been 30 hyperinflations in history (Hanke, 2008a). The 32 nd hyperinflation was supposedly in 2008 in Zimbabwe. The first hyperinflation happened during the French revolution of 1789-96 (Hanke, 2008b). For Hanke (2008b, p. 187), the most well-known hyperinflation of the 20 th century was the great German hyperinflation of the 1920s, when the monthly inflation rate peaked approximately 30,000% in October 1923. Meanwhile, Hanke (2008b, p. 186) reported that the two most virulent hyperinflations recorded - Hungary (1945-46) and Yugoslavia (1992-94) - curiously remain little known. Hanke (2008b, p. 186) hypothesized that little is known about the two inflations probably because the peak monthly inflation rates were so high as to be incomprehensible. According to Hanke (2008b), the highest one-day inflation ever recorded was in Hungary in 43

July 10, 1946 when it was 348.46%. Under the rule of Slobodan Milosevic, Yugoslavia recorded the second highest monthly inflation at 313 million percent in January 1994 (Hanke, 2008b).The hyperinflation which has the reputation of producing the month with the highest inflation was in Hungary in July 1946 but Hanke (2008b) did not provide the inflation data. In 1988, Morales (1988) reported that the Bolivian hyperinflation of 1984-86 was the only case hyperinflation not associated with a world or civil war. However, informal sources, for example, like Boliviabella.com (2012) narrated that the Bolivian hyperinflation event was associated with political instability as the country s government confronted by widespread social unrest. The most recent hyperinflation event after 1988 was the Zimbabwe hyperinflation 2005-07. Based on Ploch (2010), it can be inferred that the Zimbabwe hyperinflation coincided with a volatile political situation resulting from violence and deep political divisions, thus, political volatility substituted to wars and revolutions in the case of the Bolivian hyperinflation of 1984-86. This work has been guided by two main objectives. Firstly, the work seeks to understand the circumstances surrounding the great hyperinflations in world history. The motive is to understand better how and why hyperinflations take place. Secondly, and just as important, this work seeks to summarize what the literature or documentation have revealed on the origin of hyperinflations and how they can be addressed. The paper attempts to investigate these concerns under the Austrian School principles. Based on Hanke (2008b) and Mises (2007) and arranged chronologically, the listing of hyperinflation events in history are as follows in Table 1. Table 1 1. United States Continental 1781 2. France 1789-96 3. United States Confederate 1865 4. Germany 1920-23 5. Poland 1921-24 6. Austria 1921-22 7. Soviet Union 1922-24 8. Hungary 1923-24 9. Greece 1942-45 10. Hungary 1945-46 11. Taiwan 1945-49 12. China 1947-49 13. Bolivia 1984-86 14. Nicaragua 1986-89 15. Peru 1988-90 16. Argentina 1989-90 17. Poland 1989-90 18. Brazil 1989-93 19. Yugoslavia 1990 20. Azerbaijan 1991-94 21. Congo 1991-94 22. Kyrgyzstan 1992 23. Ukraine 1992-94 24. Yugoslavia 1992-94 44

25. Armenia 1993-94 26. Georgia 1993-94 27. Turkmenistan 1993-1996 28. Belarus 1994 29. Kazakhstan 1994 30. Tajikistan 1995 31. Bulgaria 1997 32. Zimbabwe 2005-07 Austrian School Austrian school economics or the economics of the Austrian school is a perspective that emerged in Vienna in the1870s (Butler, 2010). Butler (2010) has a good exposition of Austrian economics and, unless stated otherwise, this work used Butler (2010) in describing the perspective. Butler (2010, p. 5) pointed out that the economics of the Austrian school is highly critical of modern mainstream economics. The economics of the Austrian school does not refer to the economics taught in Vienna but rather to a particular perspective in economics and to the economists who use the perspective. The origin of Austrian economics is attributed to the book, Principles of Economics, of Carl Menger. Menger believed that economists could develop economic principles that would hold true in every place and time; but that English economists were wrong in looking for linkages among the statistics of trade and commerce (Butler, 2010, p.6). In contrast, the Austrian school of economics opted to find the basic linkage in the millions of individuals making choices and, thus, the approach of the Austrian school to economics has been described as methodological individualism (Butler,2010, p.6). Butler (2010, p.7) asserted that the Austrian school of economics is not about objective, natural phenomena, but subjective, human ones. Hazlitt (2003, p. 30) narrated, for instance, that Menger insisted throughout his work that value is essentially subjective, and that therefore economics must be in the main a subjective science. Hazlitt (2003, p. 30) stressed that goods have no inherent value in themselves and they are valued because they help to satisfy some human want or need. Butler (2010) elaborated that Menger independently developed along with William Stanley Jevons and Leon Walras the use of marginal analysis in economics. Butler s (2010) view on marginal analysis in Austrian economics echoed the view of Hazlitt (2003). Unlike other expositions on marginal analysis, however, Butler s (2010, p. 7) exposition of marginal analysis is that people strive to acquire whatever that will satisfy their most urgent needs first and after that, they attend to their less and less urgent (or more and more marginal ) needs. In contrast, Hazlitt s (2003, p. 30) exposition of marginal analysis has a more conventional foundation: a consumer s desire may require a second, third, or fourth increment but the consumer s desire or need for a further unit of that good may be less 45

intense, and may finally become completely satisfied. Hazlitt (2003) emphasized that each increment of good will have a reduced value to consumers. Menger s seminal work that became known as "Austrian economics" was published in 1871. Bohm-Bawerk applied Menger s approach in the area of interest and capital and, together, they were known as the first wave of the Austrian school (Butler, 2010). The second wave of the Austrian economic school has been associated with the leadership of Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich Hayek who worked together on the theory of business cycles. To avoid the Nazis, Mises and Hayek left Austria in the 1930s for the United States of America (Butler, 2010). Mises concentrated his work on the pure science of science of choice and action, sharpening Menger s original principles and working out their implications (Butler, 2010, p. 8). On the other hand, Hayek went to Britain and then to America and concentrated his work on the role of information on how people make choices and how markets actually work (Butler, 2010, p. 8). According to Butler (2010), the third wave of Austrian school economists was mostly from the United States and Universities like New York, Auburn, and George Mason. Yet, at the same time, the third wave imbibed other intellectual traditions and that while many of them would not hesitate to call themselves Austrians, others would only admit to having been influenced, to a greater or lesser degree, by the Austrian School approach (Butler, 2010, p. 9). Basic Austrian Economic Perspective on Inflation Regardless of affiliation with any of the three waves of the Austrian economic school, Butler (2010, p. 11) held that economists of the Austrian school consider that all economic phenomena are inherently personal and unpredictable. Butler (2010, p. 13) emphasised that value is not a quality that resides in objects, and which can be measured because the same good has a different value to different people, depending on how much use they have for it. Further, people s wants and values change: a thirsty person may greatly value a drink, but do not have use for more once they have had their fill (Butler, 2010, p. 13). Thus, Austrian economics consider that usefulness, utility and value are subjective (Butler, 2010, p. 13). Nevertheless, prices help us maximize value and minimise cost (Butler, 2010, p. 14). Prices are the going rates of exchange between different goods and inform us that people in the market are prepared to sacrifice a good for another good (Butler, 2010, p. 14). Consistent with the discussion narrated, the Austrian school of economics considers that value does not exist in things, but in the minds of the individuals who value them (Butler, 2010, p. 11). Further, trade occurs and prices emerge precisely because people value things differently and markets steer goods to their most valued uses (Butler, 2010, p. 11). 46

However, government intervention, and policy mistakes such as inflation, disrupt this highly complex market process and invariably produce perverse results (Butler, 2010, p. 11). For Austrian school economists, money is a good (Butler, 2010, p. 16). If the supply of money increases then the value of money, just like the value of other goods, decrease (Butler, 2010). As a result, sellers demand more money for the goods they sell and the inflation process is initiated (Butler, 2010). According to Butler (2010, p. 16), inflation is good for debtors, who find themselves repaying loans in money that is not worth so much, and bad for savers. In the Austrian economic perspective, prices co-ordinate the activities of countless individuals throughout the world (Butler, 2010, p. 38). High prices indicate that something is scarce and high prices promote increase in production of things that are scarce (Butler, 2010). For economists of the Austrian school an increase in the supply of money sets off an avalanche of price changes which tears through markets, drawing resources first to one place, then another, creating real and destructive changes (Butler, 2010, p. 73-74). Butler (2010, p. 75) asserted that even if money effects could be spread evenly across all markets, its effects cannot be equal because some individuals would choose to spend the extra money, while others, perhaps more cautious. Butler (2010, p. 75) asserted that inflation causes a real change in the pattern of what is consumed, and therefore in what is produced. Hazlitt (1965, p.1) described inflation as always and everywhere, primarily caused by an increase by an increase in the supply of money and credit. In stronger terms, Hazlitt (1965, p. 1) even pointed out that, in fact, inflation is the increase in the supply of money and credit. Yet, at the same time, Hazlitt (1965, p. 2) recognized that inflation has been known as a substantial rise in prices caused by an undue expansion in paper money or bank credit. For Hazlitt (1965), however, defining inflation in terms of the latter will only lead to confusion. Hazlitt (1965) debunked claims that inflation result from shortages of goods. He said that inflation could happen even in abundance. Hazlitt (1965) argued that budget deficits do not necessarily lead to inflation as he pointed out that a government budget deficit will only cause inflation if it leads to an increase in money supply. Hazlitt (1965) also pointed that wage rises do not cause inflation but they would cause unemployment. Hazlitt (1965, p. 26) revealed that the perspective of cost-push inflation theorists took off from the perspective of Robert C. Tyson, chairman of the finance committee of the U.S. Steel Corporation in 1957 when Tyson indulged in mixing truth with error. For Butler (2010, p. 76), there is a difference between the conventional and Austrian economic thinking on inflation: most people think that inflation means rising prices but to economists of the Austrian school, Inflation is the very increase in the supply of money that has caused the price rises and the chaos that they create. Butler (2010) stressed that the Austrian economic school policy focus against inflation is to prevent the inflationary expansions from happening in the first place. Butler (2010) pointed out that there are several 47

ways through which inflation can be avoided and on this, three examples can be identified: prevent governments from arbitrarily printing money by pegging the quantity of notes and coins, prevent governments from issuing fiat money, and make government adopt a commodity like gold to serve as its currency (Butler, 2010). Butler (2010) recognized however that moving into a commodity currency could be difficult and controversial. For instance, there is only a small quantity of gold versus the billions of transactions that must be covered by gold and, thus, people think that moving to a gold standard is not a practical idea (Butler, 2010). A leading web publication that articulates the Austrian economic perspective on inflation in the United States is the Currentinflation.net. The website expresses a view consistent with Butler s (2010) articulation of the Austrian economist perspective on inflation. According to Currentinflation.net, buying gold is the answer to inflation because we can t buy a currency backed by gold currency (2011). During the great inflations of World War I and its aftermath, the website echoed the view of Austrian economists that European citizens had survived inflation by buying dollars or gold and although the actions may have been illegal, the actions actually worked. The website also echoed the view that for the Austrian school, economic factors are too complicated to predict with mathematical formulas and confirmed that, in the United States, Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich Hayek had been the two key figures of Austrian economics. Mises (2007, p. 44) which is a collection of lectures that Ludwig von Mises delivered in 1951 defined inflation as an increase in the quantity of money without a corresponding increase in the demand for money, i.e., for cash holdings. Mises (2007, p. 45) narrated: At the start of inflation, that is, at the beginning of an increase in the quantity of money without a corresponding increase in the demand for money, it causes a rise in prices. Then, if the people have learned something from theory or from history, they may anticipate still further price increases. In that case, they expect prices to rise and the purchasing power of each money piece to decline and they will trend to restrict their cash holdings, as compared with what they would have in the absence of such speculation as to the future purchasing power of money. This depends on the speculative reaction of the public. On the other hand, if people think prices will drop, there will be a tendency for them to increase their cash holdings in the expectation that the purchasing power of money will rise. In other words, Mises (2007) pointed out that inflation arise because money supply increased without a corresponding increase in the demand for money and can exacerbate further if expectations that prices will increase further are built into people s expectations. Mises (2007) narration can be described in this manner: inflation further worsens if there is an expectation that the value or purchasing power of money decrease. In other words, an expectation that the purchasing power of money will decrease will lead to a lower demand for money and a higher 48

demand for goods. Thus, inflation worsens. However, if people think prices will drop, there will be a tendency for them to increase their cash holdings in the expectation that the purchasing power of money will rise (Mises, 2007, p. 45). For Mises (2007), there are two periods involved in inflation. The first period may last many years while the second period last for only a very short time (Mises, 2007, p. 46). A reasonable interpretation of Mises (2007) herein discussed is that a hyperinflation is preceded by a relatively small inflation until all hell break loose and hyperinflation ensue. Mises (2007) solution to inflation was for nations to revert to a gold standard. Mises (2007, p. 52) asserted that a fiat money system cannot go on forever and must one day come to an end. Mises (2007, p. 52) also asserted that the gold standard under present conditions is the only standard which makes the determination of the purchasing power of money independent of the changing ideas of political parties, governments, and pressure groups. In returning to the gold standard, Mises (2007, p. 58) advocated a country must abolish laws against holding gold, re-establish the gold market and see what rate establishes itself. At the same, Mises (2007, p. 60) pointed out that a return to the gold standard is possible economically, but not politically. Mises (2007, p. 60) said that government is built on such tremendous expenditure that if the people are not actively opposed the government will always inflate. However, the advantage of the gold standard is that the purchasing power depends on conditions which are not subject to governments, political parties, and changing codes, creeds, and desires (Mises, 2007, p. 60) stressed that a gold standard prevents the government from increasing the amount of money. Concluding Remarks As for the root cause of hyperinflations, a basic insight that we can gain from the literature is that both money supply and expectations can lead to a hyperinflationary situation. Of course, monetary expansion, especially excessive or accelerating monetary expansion, is widely as the root of inflation and even inflation is usually defined in terms of an increase in money supply. Nevertheless, budget deficits lead to an inflationary situation when the deficit is financed by money creation or an obligation to print more money in the future to fund the interest rates of public debts. Budget deficits can contribute to the creation of the hyperinflation but as Kiguel and Liviatan (1992) pointed out, hyperinflation can be ended even if government budget deficits persist. However, ending the government budget deficits will also create a strong signal that run-away money creation will also stop. 49

References Boliviabella.com (2012). Recent history of Boliva: Part, 1900-1950 A.D. Retrieved March 15, 2012, from http://www.boliviabell.com/recent-history.html Butler, E. (2010). Austrian economics: A primer. United Kingdom: Adam Smith Research Trust. Hanke, S. (2008b). Hyperinflation: Mugabe versus Milosovic. Perspective, August, 186-188. Hazlitt, H. (1965). What you should know about inflation. London: D. Van Nostrand Company, Inc. Hazlitt, H. (2003). Understanding Austrian Economics. Ideas on Liberty, October, 30-33. Kiguel, M. and Liviatan, N. (1992, October). Stopping three big inflations. Policy Research Working Paper (WPS 999). Washington: The World Bank. Mises, L. (2007). The free market and its enemies: Pseudo-science, socialism and inflation. Lectures in 1951 of Ludwig von Mises. New York: Foundation for Economic Education. Morales, J.A. (1988). The end of the Bolivian hyperinflation. Documento de Trabajo No. 3/88. La Pax, Bolivia: Instituto de Investigaciones Socio Economicas. Ploch, L. (2010). Zimbabwe: Background. United States Congressional Research Service 7-5700. 50