Rich Man s War, Poor Man s Fight

Similar documents
19 ECONOMIC INEQUALITY. Chapt er. Key Concepts. Economic Inequality in the United States

The People, The Press and The War In The Gulf. A Special Times Mirror News Interest Index

How do the scale and outcome of a war affect

Part 1: Focus on Income. Inequality. EMBARGOED until 5/28/14. indicator definitions and Rankings

Political Cartoon Clinic

Poverty data should be a Louisiana wake-up call

An Equity Profile of the Southeast Florida Region. Summary. Foreword

Why Does Inequality Matter? T. M. Scanlon. Chapter 8: Unequal Outcomes. It is well known that there has been an enormous increase in inequality in the

Persistent Inequality

Working women have won enormous progress in breaking through long-standing educational and

Mapping migrants: Australians wide-ranging experiences of immigration

Immigration Reform, Economic Growth, and the Fiscal Challenge Douglas Holtz- Eakin l April 2013

Volume Title: The Korean War and United States Economic Activity, Volume URL:

World War II Home Front

ARTICLES. Poverty and prosperity among Britain s ethnic minorities. Richard Berthoud

Presentation Script English Version

EMBARGOED. Overcovered: Protesters, Ex-Generals WAR COVERAGE PRAISED, BUT PUBLIC HUNGRY FOR OTHER NEWS

Fallujah and its Aftermath

Has Globalization Helped or Hindered Economic Development? (EA)

Military Sociology: Past, Present, Future

The Racial Dimension of New York s Income Inequality

The Black-White Wage Gap Among Young Women in 1990 vs. 2011: The Role of Selection and Educational Attainment

Opting Out in 2012: Military Casualties, Vote Choice, and Voter Turnout in Obama s Bid for Reelection. Christopher Gelpi.

FIJI CIVIL SOCIETY INDEX REPORT A CIVIL SOCIETY IN TRANSITION

Karen Bell, Achieving Environmental Justice: A Cross-National Analysis, Bristol: Policy Press, ISBN: (cloth)

BY Aaron Smith FOR RELEASE JUNE 28, 2018 FOR MEDIA OR OTHER INQUIRIES:

All is Fair in War? Just War Theory and American Applications. Chris Sabolcik GSW Area II

In the second half of the century most of the killing took place in the developing world, especially in Asia.

Volume Title: Domestic Servants in the United States, Volume URL:

Community Well-Being and the Great Recession

Can free-trade policies help to reduce gender inequalities in employment and wages?

Constitutionalism and Rule of Law in the Republic of Korea

TREND REPORT: Like everything else in politics, the mood of the nation is highly polarized

Course: Government Course Title: Power and Politics: Power, Tragedy, and H onor Three Faces of W ar Year: Spring 2007

Population Vitality Overview

Visualizing. Rights C E SR. Making Human Rights Accountability More Graphic. Center for Economic and Social Rights. fact sheet no.

How Extensive Is the Brain Drain?

The Permissibility of Aiding and Abetting Unjust Wars

We know that the Latinx community still faces many challenges, in particular the unresolved immigration status of so many in our community.

Dietlind Stolle 2011 Marc Hooghe. Shifting Inequalities. Patterns of Exclusion and Inclusion in Emerging Forms of Political Participation.

A FORCE FOR FAIRNESS? WHAT COULD THE EUROPEAN UNION DO TO COMBAT ECONOMIC INEQUALITY?

POLICY Volume 5, Issue 8 October RETHINKING THE EFFECTS OF IMMIGRATION ON WAGES: New Data and Analysis from by Giovanni Peri, Ph.D.

A Not So Divided America Is the public as polarized as Congress, or are red and blue districts pretty much the same? Conducted by

Thomas Piketty Capital in the 21st Century

Lecture Outline: Chapter 10

Chapter 8: The Use of Force

CH 19. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

US Undocumented Population Drops Below 11 Million in 2014, with Continued Declines in the Mexican Undocumented Population

Northern Character: College-educated New Englanders, Honor, Nationalism, And Leadership In The Civil War Era

The Future of Inequality

Over the past three decades, the share of middle-skill jobs in the

Demographic Data. Comprehensive Plan

Poverty and Inequality

CRS Report for Congress

COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION. Brussels, 4 May /10 MIGR 43 SOC 311

Citizenship Just the Facts.Civics Learning Goals for the 4th Nine Weeks.

The Home Front. Chapter 7 Section 2 Pages

Unit 8. 5th Grade Social Studies Cold War Study Guide. Additional study material and review games are available at at

State of the Union: Unhappy with Bush

When Equal Is Not Always Fair: Senate Malapportionment and its Effect on Enacting Legislation

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

University of California Institute for Labor and Employment

RESEARCH BRIEF: The State of Black Workers before the Great Recession By Sylvia Allegretto and Steven Pitts 1

Chapter 6: Public Opinion and Political Action Chapter Summary. I. The American People ( ) Introduction

Emerging and Developing Economies Much More Optimistic than Rich Countries about the Future

OLDER INDUSTRIAL CITIES

Committee: General Assembly (GA) Chair Members: Araceli Nava Niño. Elías Eduardo Mejía Nava. Topic: Security Council Take of Action Improvement

Expert group meeting. New research on inequality and its impacts World Social Situation 2019

Summary. Flight with little baggage. The life situation of Dutch Somalis. Flight to the Netherlands

STATE OF WORKING FLORIDA

1100 Ethics July 2016

The Effect of North Carolina s New Electoral Reforms on Young People of Color

The widening income dispersion in Hong Kong :

Jus in Bello through the Lens of Individual Moral Responsibility: McMahan on Killing in War

Issue Brief: Immigration and Socioeconomic Status

Warm-up. List the causes of WWI. Describe how the US got involved.

Where are the Middle Class in OECD Countries? Nathaniel Johnson (CUNY and LIS) David Johnson (University of Michigan)

18 Pathways Spring 2015

Reconciling Educational Adequacy and Equity Arguments Through a Rawlsian Lens

Who Votes for America s Mayors?

US Policy in Afghanistan and Iraq: Lessons and Legacies

Gender, labour and a just transition towards environmentally sustainable economies and societies for all

2016 Arab Opinion Index: Executive Summary

Why growth matters: How India s growth acceleration has reduced poverty

Poverty and Inequality

I. LEVELS AND TRENDS IN INTERNATIONAL MIGRANT STOCK

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003

Tilburg University. The digital divide across all citizens of the world James, Jeffrey. Published in: Social Indicators Research

Six in 10 Support Kosovo Call-Up, Though Many Question Who's Winning

National and Urban Contexts. for the Integration of the Immigrant Second Generation. in the United States and Canada

INTRODUCTION THE MEANING OF PARTY

Flash Eurobarometer 455. European Youth

World History (Survey) Restructuring the Postwar World, 1945 Present

Poverty profile and social protection strategy for the mountainous regions of Western Nepal

STRENGTHENING RURAL CANADA: Fewer & Older: The Coming Population and Demographic Challenges in Rural Newfoundland & Labrador

INTRODUCTION ANALYSIS

International/Defense Issues: Civil Liberties, Terrorism, and War

ASK FORM 1 NATIONAL [N=500] AND CITIES ONLY: Q.2 All in all, are you satisfied or dissatisfied with the way things are going in this country today?

The Darfur Crisis: African and American Public Opinion

The problem of growing inequality in Canadian. Divisions and Disparities: Socio-Spatial Income Polarization in Greater Vancouver,

Transcription:

Butler University Digital Commons @ Butler University Scholarship and Professional Work - LAS College of Liberal Arts & Sciences 2011 Rich Man s War, Poor Man s Fight Harry van der Linden Butler University, hvanderl@butler.edu Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.butler.edu/facsch_papers Part of the Ethics and Political Philosophy Commons Recommended Citation van der Linden, H. 2011. Rich Man s War, Poor Man s Fight. Radical Philosophy Review, 14 (2), pp. 255-259. doi: 10.5840/ radphilrev201114231. Available from: http://digitalcommons.butler.edu/facsch_papers/233. This Book Review is brought to you for free and open access by the College of Liberal Arts & Sciences at Digital Commons @ Butler University. It has been accepted for inclusion in Scholarship and Professional Work - LAS by an authorized administrator of Digital Commons @ Butler University. For more information, please contact omacisaa@butler.edu.

Rich Man s War, Poor Man s Fight Harry van der Linden Under review Douglas L. Kriner and Francis X. Shen, The Casualty Gap: The Causes and Consequences of American Wartime Inequalities. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2010. Pp. 302. Cloth, $ 29.95. ISBN 978-0-19-539096-4. It is a rich man s war and a poor man s fight. This popular saying, going back to the Civil War when drafted men could buy their way out of military service for $300, is cited by Kriner and Shen to show that there is a long history of awareness that American wars tend to have an objectionable casualty (killed in action) gap: the soldiers who fight the wars come disproportionally from poor communities, and so combat deaths are disproportionally found in the lower socioeconomic communities rather than reflecting a common and shared sacrifice of all citizens (viii-ix). Recently, the issue has been voiced forcefully by Bob Herbert in his op-ed Blood Runs Red, not Blue (New York Times, August 18, 2005), who writes that for the most part, the only people sacrificing for [the Iraq] war are the troops and their families, and very few of them are coming from the privileged economic classes. Kriner and Shen continue: What is new in our book is not the claim that inequality is tied to wartime death but the evidence we present to support it (ix). Their empirical study is focused on World War II, the Korean War, the Vietnam War, and the Iraq War (of 2003). Kriner and Shen first show that there is a significant socioeconomic casualty gap with regard to the last three wars while this is not true of World War II. More specifically, in Korea, Vietnam, and Iraq, [communities with] the lowest three incomes deciles took on 35 percent, 36 percent, and 38 percent of the casualties, respectively, [while] the top three deciles by income suffered only 25 percent, 26 percent, and 23 percent of the casualties, respectively (29). A similar socioeconomic casualty gap is manifest when the measure of socioeconomic status is educational attainment instead of income. It is often said that there is 1

also a racial casualty gap, but Kriner and Shen argue that the data do not support this view after the Pentagon in 1967 reduced the number of blacks in combat positions in the Vietnam War in response to critics asserting such a gap. In fact, beyond this date, after controlling for socioeconomic conditions, a greater percentage of minorities in a community is related to lower casualty rates (40). Kriner and Shen rightfully stress that the very fact that communities at the high and low ends of the socioeconomic spectrum have different casualty rates does not necessarily imply that individuals from poor socioeconomic background have died disproportionally in recent American wars. The communities for which casualty data are available are counties or census designated places, and while it is highly unlikely, it is possible that casualties in a community with a low median income and level of educational attainment are predominantly from highincome, high-education backgrounds (41-42). We lack data on the level of individuals to conclude definitively that a casualty gap exists between individuals from socioeconomically advantaged and disadvantaged backgrounds (42). Still, the hypothesis is well-supported. In regard to the Iraq War, data are available that allow the determination of casualties of smaller census block groups (about one thousand residents). Block-group analysis shows that casualties within rich communities are disproportionally from blocks with income levels lower than those of the community at large, while casualties are also a bit more concentrated within the poorest blocks of poor communities (46). (The important implication is that the casualty gap percentages noted on the community level probably significantly understate the scope of the gap on the individual level.) Moreover, we have plausible and data-supported explanations for how the casualty gap between rich and poor communities has come about since World War II, and these explanations also account for the individual socioeconomic casualty gap. Accordingly, the burden of proof [is on] those who reject an individual-level casualty gap (58). Two mechanisms have led to an increasing casualty gap beginning with the Korean War. The first one is that the economic benefits of volunteering for military service are comparatively more attractive and compelling to those with fewer economic opportunities. Here it should be noted that even before the emergence of the all-volunteer army in 1973 more than 50 percent of the fighting forces in the Korean and Vietnam Wars were volunteers (63). The second mechanism is that with the Korean War the testing of skills of new recruits became effective in assigning occupational roles, with the result that those who had lower levels of educational attainment more often ended up in combat roles. To complete the picture, we must also take into account changes in the draft (74-80). A widespread draft in World War II and ineffective occupational assignment procedures at the time based on educational attainment 2

(68-69) explain the lack of a casualty gap in this war. A more limited and selective draft, offering, for example, easy student deferments, reduced its blunting impact on the casualty gap in the Korean and Vietnam Wars, while the absence of the draft in the Iraq War helps to explain why this war has the highest casualty gap. Kriner and Shen discuss next why the casualty gap matters. They note that the logic of the market as well as the economic and recognition opportunities provided by the military to the socioeconomically disadvantaged are arguments in favor of the status quo, while a long tradition of understanding fighting war as a public service with sacrifice to be borne by all goes against the casualty gap. On their account, Americans tend to be swayed by the traditional view because they become more opposed to war or lower their tolerance of high casualties in future wars once the casualty gap is brought to their attention. To support this claim, Kriner and Shen devised a survey in which they compared on a variety of questions respondents who were told that the casualties of the Iraq War were a shared sacrifice to respondents who were briefly informed about the casualty gap. The control group was not provided with this additional information. With regard to the question of whether the Iraq War was a mistake, approximately 56 % of the respondents of both the control group and the shared sacrifice group answered in the affirmative, while this rose to almost 62 % for the casualty gap group (97). Similarly, support for the draft went up from 18.6 % for the shared sacrifice group to 24.0% for the casualty gap group, while it was 20.8% for the control group (99). Moreover, with regard to the question of how many casualties would be acceptable in going to war with Iran to stop its nuclear program (and the respondents were provided casualty figures, among others, of around 400,000 in World War II, 54,000 in the Korean War, and 383 in the Gulf War), 37.4% of the shared sacrifice group said that 51-5,000 casualties were acceptable and, respectively, 30.9% and 34.8 % of the casualty gap group and control group held this opinion (102). The differences were smaller with regard to those who found more than 5,000 casualties acceptable; respectively, 15%, 14%, and 16.7% of the control, casualty gap, and shared sacrifice groups offered this answer. The remainder of the respondents found fewer than 50 casualties acceptable (and so, in effect, more or less opposed going to war). It is debatable whether these figures show that there is currently a deep public concern with the casualty gap once the facts are known. Kriner and Shen write that the 6 percentage point increase [in viewing the Iraq War as a mistake] is even more striking when we remember the modest nature of the inequality cue [provided to the respondents] and the large amount of information that most Americans already possessed on Iraq, with which this new cue had to compete (97). They speculate that the percentage increase would become even larger if 3

details of the casualty gap would be provided. But this cuts both ways in that further reflection on the casualty gap may lead to rationalizations. Moreover, the inequality cue suggests that the Iraq War is a mistake and this might have influenced the answers of the respondents, making the 6% far from impressive. With regard to the hypothetical war against Iran, what is, arguably, more striking and significant than the differences in casualty tolerance is that Kriner and Shen held polls in both September 2007 and March 2009 (of which the figures are provided above) and that the percentage of Americans of the control, shared sacrifice, and casualty groups who supported more than 50 casualties had increased in the range of 12 to 14% by the latter date (102). We may anticipate, then, that once the American propaganda machine is at full work, casualty gap concerns will have little bearing on preventing or restricting this war (or other future wars). The casualty gap has an impact on political behavior irrespective of people s awareness of this gap. Comparing communities at the opposite ends of the socioeconomic spectrum, Kriner and Shen argue that poor communities with higher casualty rates will likely have a higher proportion of citizens with personal links to the casualties of a given war; its politicians will more likely be opposed to the war (due to its human costs); and its local media will likely pay more attention to the casualties of the war (113-23). Thus one would expect to find greater opposition to the war among citizens of poor communities and more support of anti-war politicians. Kriner and Shen discuss in great detail how indeed these expectations are overall corroborated during the Vietnam War and currently during the Iraq War. They conclude: Consistent with a large literature in political science, we find that Americans do respond to combat casualties by lowering their support for military operations and for the political leaders waging them. However, they do not do so uniformly. Rather, this backlash is most intense among citizens who have experienced the costs of war most intimately through the lens of their local communities (182). Kriner and Shen add that because residents of socioeconomically disadvantaged communities possess fewer of the resources needed to engage in politics, the casualty gap decreases the political pressure that is brought to bear on military policymakers to change course. In other words, since affluent communities are more shielded from the human costs of war they are less likely to exercise their greater political influence in opposition to a given war even when the casualties overall rise significantly. This adds a new twist to the indictment that the typical American war is a rich man s war. Depending on their outcome, wars may have a positive or negative impact on the democratic participation and engagement of citizens, including their civic engagement, their trust in government, their interest in politics, and their willingness to vote. Kriner and Shen s final 4

research concerns how the casualty gap plays out in this regard. Most importantly, they show that the Vietnam War disproportionally led to reduced democratic participation and engagement within high-casualty communities. The negative impact was more limited and restricted to fewer dimensions of democratic participation and engagement in the case of the Korean War, while high-sacrifice communities in World War II may even have gained disproportionally with regard to the positive participatory effects of this war. The last chapter of The Casualty Gap offers some reflections on the future of the casualty gap. Kriner and Shen anticipate that because current military selection and occupational assignment mechanisms are unlikely to change, the casualty gap will remain with us (227). Still, they argue that the gap should be placed high on the agenda of policymakers because open engagement of the issue might reenergize the democratic brake on costly military policies that the casualty gap blunts (228). A clear problem with this expectation is that current American wars have much lower casualty rates and so the inequity of the casualty gap is nowadays presumably much less striking and compelling to the public at large than in earlier wars. The very fact that current military service is voluntary has a similar impact. More broadly, it is widely accepted within American society that the poor end up with jobs with greater casualty risks, jobs that also lead to a wide variety of quality of life gaps. In my view, it is ethically more urgent to focus attention on the collective failure of Americans to take responsibility for how their recent wars have had devastating consequences for civilian populations of other nations than to focus on their failure to take collective responsibility for the inequity of the distribution of their fallen soldiers. And, strategically, it might be more promising to try to increase the democratic brake on future military interventions by focusing attention on the economic costs of American wars. At the same time, I think that Kriner and Shen have strengthened the case for the inequity of the casualty gap by exposing its numerous dimensions and ramifications. They also rightfully note in their concluding reflections the need for an empirical study of what might turn out to become politically speaking a more influential gap, the wounded gap. The wounded/kill ratio in the Iraq War is 1 to 7.3 (through December 2008), while it was 1 to 1.7 in World War II, 1 to 1.9 in the Korean War, and 1 to 2.6 in the Vietnam War (229). Shrinking government budgets may add to the injustice done to poor communities, and those left wounded in military action at least can fight to have their voices heard. 5