If a party s share of the overall party vote entitles it to five seats, but it wins six electorates, the sixth seat is called an overhang seat.

Similar documents
REVIEW OF THE MMP VOTING SYSTEM PROPOSALS PAPER

THRESHOLDS. Underlying principles. What submitters on the party vote threshold said

DHSLCalc.xls What is it? How does it work? Describe in detail what I need to do

Civil and Political Rights

Enhancing MMP: How to improve New Zealand s

BCGEU surveyed its own members on electoral reform. They reported widespread disaffection with the current provincial electoral system.

NEW ZEALAND'S ELECTORAL SYSTEM

REPRESENTATION VS STABILITY: THE FIVE PER CENT THRESHOLD IN MMP

THE SOUTH AUSTRALIAN LEGISLATIVE COUNCIL: POSSIBLE CHANGES TO ITS ELECTORAL SYSTEM

kicking the tyres Choosing a voting system for New Zealand

ONE News Colmar Brunton Poll

What criteria should guide electoral system choice?

Post-election round-up: New Zealand voters attitudes to the current voting system

1 News Colmar Brunton Poll

1 NEWS Colmar Brunton Poll

Measuring the Compliance, Proportionality, and Broadness of a Seat Allocation Method

1 NEWS Colmar Brunton Poll

PRESENTATION SUMMARY

Arguments for and against electoral system change in Ireland

ONE News Colmar Brunton Poll

1 NEWS Colmar Brunton Poll

Online Appendix to Mechanical and Psychological. Effects of Electoral Reform.

Elections and referendums

Electoral Reform: Making Every Vote Count Equally

ONTARIO SUPERIOR COURT OF JUSTICE. JOAN RUSSOW and THE GREEN PARTY OF CANADA. - and -

Women s. Political Representation & Electoral Systems. Key Recommendations. Federal Context. September 2016

Electoral Reform: Key Federal Policy Recommendations. Researched and written by CFUW National Office & CFUW Leaside East York and Etobicoke JULY 2016

ANU College of Arts & Social Sciences

Elections and Electoral Systems

STV in Malta: A crisis?

ANALYSIS AND COMPARISON OF GREEK PARLIAMENTARY ELECTORAL SYSTEMS OF THE PERIOD

ON A SINGLE-BALLOT MIXED MEMBER PROPORTIONAL (SBMMP) ELECTORAL SYSTEM

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE?

Electoral Reform Questionnaire Field Dates: October 12-18, 2016

Electoral Systems and Evaluations of Democracy

The Case for Electoral Reform: A Mixed Member Proportional System for Canada. Brief by Stephen Phillips, Ph.D.

Which electoral procedures seem appropriate for a multi-level polity?

Fair Division in Theory and Practice

2010 Municipal Elections in Lebanon

Congruence in Political Parties

The 2011 Scottish Parliament election In-depth

DRAFT FOR CONSULTATION

(Bill No. 38) Electoral System Referendum Act

INFORMATION SHEETS: 2

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting

HOW DUAL MEMBER PROPORTIONAL COULD WORK IN BRITISH COLUMBIA Sean Graham February 1, 2018

SOME QUESTIONS ABOUT THE ELECTORAL SYSTEM FOR THE 2004 INDONESIAN GENERAL ELECTION ANSWERED

D Hondt system for allocation of parliamentary positions 22 March 2016

REFORMING THE ELECTORAL SYSTEM IN ALBERTA: THE CASE FOR DUAL- MEMBER MIXED PROPORTIONAL Sean Graham

Electoral Reform National Dialogue INFORMATION BOOKLET

New Zealand Centre for Public Law and contributors. Faculty of Law Victoria University of Wellington PO Box 600 Wellington New Zealand.

Electoral systems as conflict resolution measures

SUMMARY. Migration. Integration in the labour market

REPRESENTATIVE DEMOCRACY - HOW TO ACHIEVE IT

MMP vs. FPTP. National Party. Labour Party. Māori Party. ACT New Zealand. United Future. Simpl House 40 Mercer Street

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems

Math of Election APPORTIONMENT

As you may have heard, there has been some discussion about possibly changing Canada's electoral system. We want to ask people their views on this.

Submission to the Inquiry into and report on all aspects of the conduct of the 2016 Federal Election and matters related thereto

BILL C-24: AN ACT TO AMEND THE CANADA ELECTIONS ACT AND THE INCOME TAX ACT (POLITICAL FINANCING)

Liberal Revival Stalled Despite New Leader

F2PTP A VOTING SYSTEM FOR EQUALITY OF REPRESENTATION IN A MULTI-PARTY STATE FIRST TWO PAST THE POST. 1 Tuesday, 05 May 2015 David Allen

Letter prices in Europe. Up-to-date international letter price survey. March th edition

Chapter 4. Party Systems

Compare the vote Level 3

The UK and the European Union Insights from ICAEW Employment

Compare the vote Level 1

Local elections. Referendum on the voting system used to elect MPs to the House of Commons

EUROPEISKA KONVENTET SEKRETARIATET. Bryssel den 27 februari 2003 (28.2) (OR. en) CONV 585/03 CONTRIB 261 FÖLJENOT

Inquiry into the 2002 General Election

Vote-Buying and Selling

REFORMING THE ELECTORAL FORMULA IN PEI: THE CASE FOR DUAL-MEMBER MIXED PROPORTIONAL Sean Graham

Elections and Electoral Systems

INTERNATIONAL KEY FINDINGS

An introduction to Electoral. André Blais Université de Montréal

Scottish Parliamentary election

~n~ ~II~~I 3 1 A 3 F 6 - Date Printed: 01/06/2009. JTS Box Number: Tab Number: Document Title: Document Date: NOR ENG. Document Language:

Patrick J. Lingane February 7, 2008 A Letter to the Author Improvements to Spitzer s Chapter on Elections

Public Justice in Representation. A CPJ Position Paper on Electoral Reform and Representation

Electoral System Design Database Codebook

4 However, devolution would have better served the people of Wales if a better voting system had been used. At present:

Reading the local runes:

THE U.S. POLITICAL SYSTEM AND THE 2014 MIDTERM ELECTION. Hans Noel Georgetown University bit.ly/hansnoel

Electoral Reform Brief

DUAL-MEMBER MIXED PROPORTIONAL: A NEW ELECTORAL SYSTEM FOR CANADA. (Updated April 4, 2016) Sean Graham

The Belgian Electoral System: Open list system, political parties and individual candidates

Volatile and tripolar: The new Italian party system

THE CONSTITUTION OF KENYA (AMENDMENT) BILL, A Bill for. AN ACT of Parliament to amend the Constitution of Kenya

REFORM OF THE HUNGARIAN ELECTORAL SYSTEM

ELECTORAL REGULATION RESEARCH NETWORK/DEMOCRATIC AUDIT OF AUSTRALIA JOINT WORKING PAPER SERIES

GUIDE TO THE NEW ZEALAND PARLIAMENT

Impact of electoral systems on women s representation in politics

New Zealand s First MMP Election

Standing Orders Review 49 th Parliament Revised Submission to Standing Orders Committee

AirPlus International Travel Management Study 2015 Part 1 A comparison of global trends and costs in business travel management.

Political Participation under Democracy

ELECTING CANDIDATES WITH FAIR REPRESENTATION VOTING: RANKED CHOICE VOTING AND OTHER METHODS

Electoral. The MMP system

Sarah Lim ** The committee aims to report by September Australasian Parliamentary Review, Spring 2004, Vol. 19(1),

Settling In 2018 Main Indicators of Immigrant Integration

Transcription:

OVERHANGS How an overhang occurs Under MMP, a party is entitled to a number of seats based on its shares of the total nationwide party vote. If a party is entitled to 10 seats, but wins only seven electorates, it will be awarded three list seats, bringing it up to its required number. If a party s share of the overall party vote entitles it to five seats, but it wins six electorates, the sixth seat is called an overhang seat. When this happens, the party keeps all the electorates eats it has won but gets no list seats. The number of seats allocated under the Sainte-Laguë method increases by the number of overhang seats that have been won, thereby increasing the size of Parliament by the same number. Overhang seats occurred at the 2005, 2008 and 2011 general elections when the size of Parliament increased to 121, 122, and 121 members respectively. What submitters said The issue of what should happen when a party wins more electorate seats than it would be entitled to under its share of the party vote was raised in 1,415 submissions during the consultation phase. The majority were in favour of retaining the status quo (64%). The next preferred option was adopting a formula that would fix the size of the House at 120 members (25%). Smaller numbers favoured the introduction of balance seats (6%) with another small group suggested that a party forfeit its electorate wins to the second place getter if its electorate wins produced an overhang (5%). This issue was raised in 558 submissions on the Proposals Paper with 87% in support of a fixed number of seats and 13% supported the status quo. 1

Number of submissions Figure: Simple analysis of submissions on managing overhangs 1000 800 600 400 200 0 Consultation Paper Proposals Paper Retain the status quo Fix size of House at 120 Add balance seats Disqualify electorate win COMMISSION S RECOMMENDATION If the one electorate seat threshold is abolished, the provision for overhang seats should be abolished. Comments and themes from the full submissions what should happen when a party wins more electorate seats than it would be entitled to under its share of the party vote. Political parties All the political parties that commented on this issue support the status quo. They submitted that, while overhangs are undesirable because they distort proportionality, the current practice has the least impact on proportionality. Absorbing overhangs to ensure the size of the House remains fixed at 120 members would potentially result in greater disproportionality with major parties likely to have fewer seats than their party vote shares would entitle them. The introduction of balance seats would see a greatly increased House which is likely to be unpopular. The National Party raised the issue of the impact of the abolition of the one electorate seat threshold on the likelihood of overhangs occurring. Academics Professor Elizabeth McLeay commented this aspect of the present MMP system has been surprisingly uncontroversial, perhaps because the numbers of additional seats have been few and the rational for them clear. In recommending the status quo, she is supported by many other academics. Dr Stephen Church, however, proposed that overhangs be capped at 123 seats in total 2

and anything beyond that would need to be compensated for by the reduction in the number of quotients available for list seat allocation. Social and other commentators The Maxim Institute and Voters for Change recommended overhangs be removed. They submitted overhangs can make it more difficult for a government to form a majority because it inflates the total number of seats in the House. While overhangs protect proportionality, they are not essential to the operation of MMP and for the sake of clarity and legitimacy of electoral outcomes, they should not be allowed. What other submitters said Retaining the status quo An overhang creates a diverse Parliament where minority views are represented and should be allowed as long as they are not so large as to unreasonably represent a party s strength. The present level (of overhang) is acceptable, but should not get larger. The present system of overhang seats should remain. Seats won cannot be taken away. The distortion to proportionality is only temporarily. Allow the overhang. This seems like the fairest to all parties and the one that increases the size of Parliament the least. Giving other parties balance seats to maintain proportionality would mean too many MPs. There is already too much criticism (rightly or wrongly) about the size of Parliament - even if the increase is only on a temporary basis. A party with overhang seats must keep all the electorate seats it has won and the size of Parliament must increase for that term. It should keep its seats, as now. The current situation with the Māori Party hasn t been a real problem. The current overhang should be allowed to continue. While not ideal, increasing the number of MPs to retain proportionality or reducing the number of MPs for a party who creates an overhang will make the situation worse, not better. A fixed number of seats Keep the size of the House at a fixed number. 3

The number of seats should be fixed and no overhang allowed. In the event of an overhang, the electorate MPs still win their seats. After this occurs, the number of available list seats should decrease. This is to keep the number of overall seats in Parliament at 120. The option Allow overhang but compensate by decreasing the number of quotients available for list seat allocation seems the best choice as long as 120 is the absolute maximum number of MPs. Provide additional balance seats Allow the overhang, but provide additional balance seats to other parties. This provides better proportionality, which is after all, the principle behind MMP. The current system of not providing balance seats gives disproportionate power to parties which might be strong in particular electorates but do not have widespread support nationally. This is undemocratic. The overhang rule seems like a necessary evil, however if a party with an overhanging MP or two was going to be crucial to the formation of a government that would be iniquitous. Therefore in that situation the largest party should be allowed to bring into Parliament an equal number of MPs as the overhanging number of MPs. Disqualify electorate wins The party should shed the appropriate number of seats surrendering the most closely contested and working back toward those more easily won until the required number have been released. Surrendering seats in this way would ensure that the fewest possible voters in any electorate are disenfranchised. The disproportionality index Lowering the party vote threshold from 5% to 4% and at the same time abolishing the one electorate seat threshold could have the effect of increasing the frequency and size of overhangs. This could also affect the disproportionality rate in New Zealand s elections. Before recommending that overhangs be abolished, the Commission undertook some statistical modelling to see how disproportionate preceding election results would have been under a proposed 4% party vote threshold and no one electorate seat threshold. 4

Disproportionately is usually measured using an index developed by Professor Michael Gallagher (the Gallagher Index ). This index is widely regarded as the best measure of disproportionality. A perfectly proportional election would have a 0.0% rate therefore, the higher the rate, the greater degree of disproportionality. Generally speaking, a disproportionality rate of less than 3% can be regarded as an indication of an electoral system that is, on balance, reasonably fair. To put the results in the table below into perspective, the average disproportionality for the FPP elections in New Zealand from 1946-90 was 10.66%. By way of contrast, the following are the rates for a selection of proportional representation electoral systems are: Denmark: 1.74%; Finland: 2.86%; Germany: 0.67%; Iceland: 2.86%; Norway: 3.65%; Sweden: 1.67%; and Switzerland: 2.36%. 1 Table 1: Levels of disproportionality in the three MMP elections that had overhangs (Column A), as well as calculations of the disproportionality if the votes had been cast in those elections with the current thresholds but where overhangs are eliminated (Column B), a 4% party vote threshold in which overhangs are permitted (Column C,) and a 4% party threshold in which overhangs are not permitted (Column D). 2 Election Column A Column B Column C Column D Year A 5% threshold with overhangs A 5% threshold without overhangs A 4% party vote threshold with overhangs A 4% party vote threshold without overhangs 2005 1.13 1.13 2.14 2.12 2008 3.84 3.94 2.93 3.05 2011 2.38 2.32 2.38 2.32 Average 2.45 2.46 2.48 2.50 Column A shows the degree of disproportionality that actually occurred in the three MMP elections where overhangs occurred. The rules for these elections included two thresholds parties had to win either at least 5% of the party vote or at least one electorate seat in order to be eligible for a proportional share of all 120 seats in Parliament. 3 1 Arend Lijphart, 1994: Electoral Systems and Party Systems: A Study of Twenty-Seven Democracies, 1945-1990, Oxford: Oxford University Press 2 See attached pdf worksheets for these calculations. 3 It is noteworthy that the only two occasions when the LSQ statistics exceeded 3% were in 1996 and 2008, when in each of those two elections a party won more than 4% but less than 5% of the party votes and did not win an electorate, and thus did not qualify for any seats in Parliament. 5

Comparing columns A and B, it can be seen that had 119, 118, and 119 quotients actually been distributed in the 2005, 2008, and 2011 general elections respectively, then the average disproportionality for those three elections would have risen very slightly (ie by just 0.01%). Similarly, when columns C and D are compared, using data for the 2005, 2008, and 2011 general elections, but assuming a 4% party vote threshold and no one electorate seat threshold, the disproportionality index falls twice very slightly and rises once with an overall (ie an average) difference of only 0.12%. Government formation with and without overhangs While the majority of submitters favour the status quo, the point was made that if ever a Parliament is formed where the Government gets decided on the basis of overhang MPs, or the party with the greatest vote share is unable to form a government, it would create a potential legitimacy issue, even a crisis of confidence in the MMP electoral system. A few submitters made the point that if the one electorate seat threshold is abolished, this might increase the likelihood of frequent and possibly larger overhangs. For example, a re-calculation of the 2011 general election results without the one electorate seat threshold could have resulted in a six seat overhang. The data in the table below show the possible consequences for government formation under the proposed threshold changes without overhangs. Exactly the same governing arrangements that were negotiated in 1999, 2002, 2008 and 2011 would have been possible had the electoral system had a 4% party vote threshold, no electorate seat threshold and no provision for overhang seats. It is not possible to say what would have happened in 1996 and 2005 had different rules applied but it could have resulted in different governing relationships. Care needs to be exercised with the scenario presented in this table. Under different thresholds, it is likely both voters and parties would make different decisions. 6

Table 2: Showing Government composition and the number of governing party seats required and calculating the number of seats a governing party would need in a Parliament with a 4% threshold with and without overhangs Election Year Actual Government composition and numbers Government composition and numbers with a 4% threshold without overhangs Government composition and numbers with a 4% threshold with overhangs 1996 National, NZ First National, NZ First National, NZ First 61/120 59/120 59/121 1999 Labour, Alliance Labour, Alliance Labour, Alliance 2002 2005 2008 2011 59/120 59/120 60/121 Labour, Progressives, United Labour, Progressives, United 62/120 62/120 63/121 Labour, Progressives, NZ First, United Labour, Progressives, NZ First, United 61/121 60/120 64127 69/122 63/120 67/128 64/121 63/120 66/126 Labour, Progressives, United Labour, Progressives, NZ First, United 7