International trade and the income inequality gap between developed and developing countries.

Similar documents
ARTNeT Trade Economists Conference Trade in the Asian century - delivering on the promise of economic prosperity rd September 2014

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis

TRADE IN SERVICES AND INCOME INEQUALITY IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES

Income Inequality and Trade Protection

Brain Drain and Emigration: How Do They Affect Source Countries?

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES,

Chapter 4. Preview. Introduction. Resources, Comparative Advantage, and Income Distribution

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Regional Income Trends and Convergence

Trade Liberalization and Inequality: Re-examining Theory and Empirical Evidence

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

INCOME INEQUALITY AND DEVELOPMENT: OVERVIEW AND EFFECTS OF NORTH-SOUTH TRADE

International Trade and Inequality

Trade, Technology, and Institutions: How Do They Affect Wage Inequality? Evidence from Indian Manufacturing. Amit Sadhukhan 1.

Exploring the Impact of Democratic Capital on Prosperity

Globalization and Inequality in Different Economic Blocks

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin

International trade in the global economy. 60 hours II Semester. Luca Salvatici

Immigration and property prices: Evidence from England and Wales

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

Direction of trade and wage inequality

The Effect of Foreign Direct Investment, Foreign Aid and International Remittance on Economic Growth in South Asian Countries

Do Bilateral Investment Treaties Encourage FDI in the GCC Countries?

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis Nanak Kakwani

Asian Development Bank Institute. ADBI Working Paper Series INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND INEQUALITY. Shujiro Urata and Dionisius A.

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

Practice Questions for Exam #2

Convergence across EU Members and the Consequences for the Czech Republic

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Handout 1: Empirics of Economic Growth

Natural Resources & Income Inequality: The Role of Ethnic Divisions

Impact of Globalization on Income Inequality in Selected Asian Countries

Matthew A. Cole and Eric Neumayer. The pitfalls of convergence analysis : is the income gap really widening?

The Effect of Foreign Aid on the Economic Growth of Bangladesh

Poverty and Inequality

Globalization and Poverty Forthcoming, University of

1. Global Disparities Overview

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEWS

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

Wage inequality and skill premium

The wage gap between the public and the private sector among. Canadian-born and immigrant workers

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Quantitative Analysis of Migration and Development in South Asia

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Edexcel (A) Economics A-level

OPENNESS, ECONOMIC REFORMS, AND POVERTY: GLOBALIZATION IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES **

Test Bank for Economic Development. 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith

Full file at

Explaining the two-way causality between inequality and democratization through corruption and concentration of power

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Violent Conflict and Inequality

Globalization and Inequality. An International Comparison between Sweden and the US

Immigrant Legalization

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach

How does international trade affect household welfare?

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective

Reducing income inequality by economics growth in Georgia

The Correlates of Wealth Disparity Between the Global North & the Global South. Noelle Enguidanos

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA: ANALYSIS FOR ADVANCED ECONOMIES, EMERGING MARKETS &DEVELOPING ECONOMIES

Demographic Changes and Economic Growth: Empirical Evidence from Asia

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy

The Effect of International Trade on Wages of Skilled and Unskilled Workers: Evidence from Brazil

Poverty, Inequality and Trade Facilitation in Low and Middle Income Countries

China s (Uneven) Progress Against Poverty. Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen Development Research Group, World Bank

CERDI, Etudes et Documents, E

The Poor in the Indian Labour Force in the 1990s. Working Paper No. 128

Economic Groups by the Inequality in the World GDP Distribution

Democracy and government spending

Immigrant Children s School Performance and Immigration Costs: Evidence from Spain

LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES

POLICY OPTIONS AND CHALLENGES FOR DEVELOPING ASIA PERSPECTIVES FROM THE IMF AND ASIA APRIL 19-20, 2007 TOKYO

Evaluating Stolper-Samuelson: Trade Liberalization & Wage Inequality in India

Is Government Size Optimal in the Gulf Countries of the Middle East? An Answer

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N April Export Growth and Firm Survival

Economic Freedom and Economic Performance: The Case MENA Countries

The transition of corruption: From poverty to honesty

EFFECTS OF PROPERTY RIGHTS AND CORRUPTION ON GENDER DEVELOPMENT

Impacts of Economic Integration on Living Standards and Poverty Reduction of Rural Households

The Pull Factors of Female Immigration

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Macroeconomics, Questions 6-7

Workers Remittances. and International Risk-Sharing

EFFECTS OF REMITTANCE AND FDI ON THE ECONOMIC GROWTH OF BANGLADESH

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries

Cross-Country Intergenerational Status Mobility: Is There a Great Gatsby Curve?

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana

Relationship between Globalization and Wage Inequality

AQA Economics A-level

Trade Liberalization and Wage Inequality in India: A Mandated Wage Equation Approach

5A. Wage Structures in the Electronics Industry. Benjamin A. Campbell and Vincent M. Valvano

1. Free trade refers to a situation where a government does not attempt to influence through quotas

International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization

This report examines the factors behind the

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

CIE Economics A-level

Transcription:

ERASMUS UNIVERSITY ROTTERDAM ERASMUS SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS BACHELOR THESIS (IBEB) International trade and the income inequality gap between developed and developing countries. By Erudini Smits 355834 Supervisor: Prof.L.Hering Erasmus University of Rotterdam August 2014 Abstract The aim of this study is to identify what effects international trade, in the form of exports have on the income gap between the developed and developing countries. This paper analyses how the share of exports to developed countries in the form of total exports and exports of intermediate goods, are related to the country s Gross Domestic Product. The focus will be on analysing how trade will reduce the gap and will pay close attention to developing countries. Eventually this paper will show that international trade benefits all countries but it favours developed countries more, which in turn will cause the gap to increase. JEL Classification: F10, F63, F62 Keywords: International trade, Income Inequality, Developed countries, Developing countries pg. 1

Table of Contents 1. Introduction... 3 2. Literature Review... 6 2.1 Economic growth... 6 2.2 Export and Import... 7 2.3 Outsourcing... 7 3. Theoretical framework... 8 3.1 Convergence theory catch up effect... 8 3.2 Heckscher Ohlin model and the Stolper Samuelson theorem... 9 4. Hypotheses... 10 5. Data and Methodology... 12 5.1 Data... 12 5.2 Trends... 13 5.3 Methodology... 15 6. Statistical Results... 18 6.1 Descriptive Analysis... 18 6.2 Empirical Analysis... 18 7. Conclusion... 21 8. Limitation and suggestion... 22 References... 23 Appendix... 25 pg. 2

1. Introduction Economic inequality 1 has become increasingly important since there has been more pressure on increasing human welfare. Not only do academics focus on this topic but also international organizations, non-governmental organizations (NGOs), and political activists. One main aspect of economic inequality is income inequality. In general, this refers to the income gap between the rich and the poor. When analyzing income inequality, there are two main categories which may seem similar but in reality have very different meanings. The first one is the income inequality within a country which is usually measured with the Gini Index. The second one is the income inequality between countries which is measured as the difference in National Income. In the paper written by Bourguignon and Morrisson (2002), they state that the inequality between countries is a key factor in explaining world inequality 2. Therefore, this paper will only focus on between-country income inequality. Throughout this paper the sample countries will be split into two groups; developed and developing, and the income inequality is the gap in national income between these two groups. National Income will be measured in terms of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) or per capita GDP (GDPPC). The terms gap, inequality gap and income inequality gap will be used interchangeably, as they will all denote the same thing, which is the gap in GDP between developed and developing countries. Many studies have found that international trade and its openness correlates positively with GDP and GDP Growth, for example the paper written by Edwards (1992). Since countries experience different growth rates and since international trade impacts the growth rate, it is interesting to analyze whether international trade impacts the income inequality gap. Therefore, this paper intends to do exactly that: identify what impact international trade has on the income gap between the developed and developing countries. To be more specific, this study will analyse country data in order to answer the following research question; 1 Economic inequality: refers to financial disparity, meaning that societies or people have unequal amounts of financial and material resources (Dye, 2014). 2 World inequality: is a very broad term in academics which refers to the extent to which income and wealth is distributed in an uneven manner among the world s population. pg. 3

How does international trade impact the income inequality between developed and developing countries during the period 1990 to 2012? This paper will define the word impact as either a reduction or an increase in the income gap. As stated earlier the gap will be measured as the difference in GDP or GDPPC between the collection of developed countries 3 and collection of developing countries 4. The decision to select this time period was so that the data would represent the most recent years. The years before 1990 were excluded due to the unavailability of data for many countries. Furthermore, the sample consists of almost all countries in the world allowing it to represent a more realistic overview of the current situation. Although there has been a lot of interest in this topic and a large amount of literature already exists, this paper will still contribute to this subject in many ways. Firstly, it will shed light on the effects economic growth has on the gap. It will then take a closer look at how international trade is related to GDP. Once the relationship between international trade and GDP or GDPPC is established, this paper will focus on how developing countries can reduce the gap by exporting more towards developed countries. This paper is also unique as it will also take into consideration the increase in outsourcing of production. It will look at how outsourcing to developing countries may also be a factor that reduces the gap and is also considered a form of international trade. Figure 1 below represents the idea of how international trade will be linked to the income inequality gap. Figure 1 International trade Influences Per Capita GDP Influences The income inequality gap. To answer the research question this paper will conduct an Ordinary Least Square (OLS) regression and analyze trends and test statics. Three hypotheses will be formulated in aid to answer the research question. Eventually this paper will show that economic growth 3 Developed countries will sometimes be referred to as rich countries. 4 Developing countries will sometimes be referred to as poor countries. pg. 4

may not be a strong factor that contributes to the widening of the gap and that there is not enough evidence for the idea of convergence. It will also show that there is indeed a relationship between trade openness and GDP. This paper will show that developed countries will benefit more from trade compared to developing countries, which in turn may be one factor that increases the income gap since developed countries will gain a higher GDP through trade than developing countries. This paper will also conclude the fact that there is not enough evidence that will suggest that an increase in exports to developed countries would reduce the gap; neither would the gap be reduced if they outsource more to developing countries. The remainder of this paper consists of the following order: Section 2 reviews the existing literature and focuses on economic growth, imports, exports, and outsourcing. Section 3 consists of the theoretical framework, which will explain two main theories in detail. Section 4 describes the data and methodology, in this section an analysis of trends will also be conducted. The following section will then look at the statistic results, both with a descriptive and empirical analysis. The final section concludes and presents the limitations of this research and possible suggestions for further research. pg. 5

2. Literature Review This section will evaluate the existing literature, focusing on economic growth, trade and outsourcing. Section 2.1 presents the literature related to economic growth. Section 2.2 shows the relevant literature for trade openness, and finally section 2.3 looks at the literature regarding outsourcing. 2.1 Economic growth It is widely believed that trade openness creates a competitive environment which results in quality products leading to the economic growth (Aradhyula, Rahman, & Seenivasan, 2007). Ghose (2004) saw that some developing countries achieved significantly faster economic growth than the advanced countries, which showed that there was convergence. The second part of his paper showed that (i) trade liberalization had extremely varied effects on trade performance across countries, and (ii) the distribution of benefits and costs of trade liberalization across countries has been such as to reduce international inequality without affecting inter-country inequality. Dollar and Kraay (2004) came up with a series of important findings; (1) the post- 1980 globalizers are catching up to the rich countries while the rest of the developing world is falling further behind, (2) they find a strong positive effect of trade on growth, (3) increase in growth rate that accompanies expanded trade leads to proportionate increases in incomes of the poor, and concluded that globalization leads to faster growth and poverty reduction in poor countries. A study done by Abramovitz (2004) found that the rate at which convergence happened varied from period to period and that it was usually accompanied by dramatic shifts in countries productivity rankings. The paper explored the connections between convergence itself and the relative success of early leaders and latecomers. In historical trend studies done by O Rourke (2001) and Bourguignon and Morrisson (2002), it was concluded that globalization has been a force for between-country convergence among participating countries since the 1820s. Sala-i-Martin (2006) finds that overall global inequality has been falling since 1980, due to between-country convergence. pg. 6

2.2 Export and Import Zhang and Ondrich (2004) found that export and import have distinct effects on a country s income inequality. Their results showed that only exports had a positive correlation with income and concluded that higher export intensity countries, as opposed to high import intensity countries, have higher per capita income, ceteris paribus. Roser and Cuaresma (2011) focused on developed countries while Meschi and Vivarelli (2007) focused on developing countries, both studies looked at the validity of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem concerning the effects of international trade on the income inequality among countries. Aradhyula, Rahman and Seenivason (2007), used a balanced data panel that revealed that trade openness increases income and an unbalanced panel data set revealed that trade openness increases income inequality overall, but when this data set was split into two groups, they saw that trade increases inequality in developing countries but it reduces inequality in developed countries. 2.3 Outsourcing The rising integration of world markets has brought with it a disintegration of the production process, in which manufacturing or service activities done abroad are combined with those performed at home. Companies are now finding it profitable to outsource production processes (Feenstra, 1998). In his paper, he compares several different measures of foreign outsourcing, and argues that they have all increased since the 1970 s. Lee and Sim (2012) found out that outsourcing to developed countries and less developed countries have opposite and significant effects on relative wage meaning that outsourcing to developed countries affected the wage of skilled labor and outsourcing to less developed countries reduced the wage of unskilled labor. Feenstra and Hanson (1996) found out that outsourcing reduces the relative demand for unskilled labor in both developed countries and developing countries. This was due to the fact that the outsourced activities are unskilled labor-intensive relative to those done in the developed country but they are skilled labor-intensive relative to the less developed economy. Therefore moving the activity to another country raises the average skill-intensity pg. 7

of production in both locations. Feenstra and Hanson (2001) also stated that trade in intermediate inputs can have an impact on wages and employment that is much greater than for trade in final consumer goods. They argue that the trade in intermediate inputs is a potentially important explanation for an increase in the wage gap. 3. Theoretical framework 3.1 Convergence theory catch up effect The convergence theory, also known as the catch-up effect, refers to the proposition that less developed economies or regions (poorer economies per capita incomes) are expected to grow faster than developed economies. As a result, all economies are predicted to converge in terms of per capita income. 5 Developing countries have three main arguments supporting this theory. The first argument states that late-comers can benefit from the already existing technology and knowledge that was developed by the pioneer economies and therefore the late-comers will not have to make the initial costs and effort but have the advantage of exploiting and adopting these production methods. The second argument is that of a standard statement in the growth theory itself. The idea that developing countries have a greater potential to grow at a faster rate than developed countries due to diminishing returns to factor inputs, meaning that capital productivity is higher in less developed economies in comparison to capital-rich economies. The third argument states that due to structural change in employment from workers in the primary sector (example agriculture) to secondary or the tertiary sector means that the developing country will have a source of labor productivity. But this statement will reduce its strength as the country develops further (Ghose, 2004). Unfortunately, on the other hand none of these arguments are fully convincing. According to Abramovitz (2004) there is a need for social capabilities to benefit from catchup growth. Social capabilities refer to the ability for that country to absorb new technology, attract capital and participate in global markets. These prerequisites must already exist within the economy before catch-up growth can occur. In his paper he continues to say that 5 In relevant literature this is referred to as beta-convergence pg. 8

due to the lack of social capabilities there is still divergence in today s world (Abramovitz, 1986). Another argument is that the theory assumes that technology is freely traded and available to those developing countries that want to catch-up, but this may not be the case in reality. There is always a possibility for the pioneer economy to always expand the technology frontier so that there always remains a technological gap between the economies. It can also be that due to learning by doing there can be constant or may be even increasing returns to factor inputs (Ghose, 2004). 3.2 Heckscher Ohlin model and the Stolper Samuelson theorem The Hecksher-Ohlin model (H-O model) was built on David Ricardo s theory of comparative advantage. The H-O model in general says that a country exports those products that use factors of production that are available in abundance in that economy. This means that developing countries that are labor-abundant will mostly export products that are labor-intensive in production and that they will import products that are more skill and capital-intensive in their production (Meschi & Vivarelli, 2007). The Stolper-Samuelsom theorem is an immediate result of the H-O model and describes the relationship between relative prices of output and relative factor rewards. The theorem states that if there is a rise in the relative prices of the product then there will also be an increase in the return of the factor that was used most intensively in the production of that product and there will be a fall in the return to the other factors. This means that if high-skilled labor and low-skilled labor were considered as two separate factors of production then the distribution of income between these two factors will be altered by the intensification of international trade. This also means that if the prices of exported goods increase, then the wages in the export sector rise and conversely wages will fall in the import sector (Roser & Cuaresma, 2011). The validity of the H-O model has been questioned mainly after the introduction of the Leontief paradox. Feenstra (2004) mentioned that the H-O model was hopelessly inadequate as an explanation for historical and modern trade patterns (Feenstra, 2004). The pg. 9

model was also criticized of being a bad analysis for north-south 6 trade as the assumptions of the model are too unrealistic (Stewart, 1989). 4. Hypotheses After revising the existing literature and looking at the theory, three assumption can be made that will guide this paper towards answering the research question. Due to the fact that income inequality is considered to have negative effects on social welfare 7, this paper mainly looks at the possibility of reducing the gap. It must also be stated that throughout this paper, the assumption that greater wealth, which is in this case measured by GDP, would mean better standard of living (Nye, 2002). Therefore, due to the fact that developing countries are lagging behind in GDP, the focus of this paper would be to analyze how trade mainly influences the GDP of developing countries and whether there is a reduction in the income inequality gap. The convergence theory looked at the hypothesis that eventually all economies will converge in per capita income, if the economic growth rate of developing countries would be faster than the growth rate of the developed world. According to Dollar and Kraay (2004), there was a strong positive effect of trade and growth and that an increase in growth rate that accompanies expanded trade leads to a proportionate increase in income of the poor. Since economic growth and trade are assumed to be connected strongly this assumption will be able to focus on economic growth as a means to support a suitable answer to the research question. Hypothesis1 will look at the assumption that the convergence theory is true and that a faster economic growth rate in the developing countries would reduce the income inequality gap. Ho: Faster economic growth in developing countries does not reduce the international income inequality gap. Ha: Faster economic growth in developing countries reduces the international income inequality gap. 6 North-south trade is the trade between the developed and developing countries. 7 Negative effects of social welfare are gathered from articles written by (Wilkinson, 2011) and (Schnurer, 2014). pg. 10

International trade has been accused of having an impact on the income gap. The following assumption that trade is related to income distribution was inspired by the H-O model. According to Zhang and Ondrich (2004), higher export intensive countries have a higher per capita income. Therefore the logic behind hypothesis2 is that more exportation from developing countries to developed countries should increase the wages in the developing countries and likewise reduce the wages in the developed countries which in turn will mean a smaller international income inequality gap. Ho: More export from developing countries to developed countries will not reduce the international income inequality gap Ha: More export from developing countries to developed countries will reduce the international income inequality gap. It has become common for firms to start outsourcing more and more (Feenstra, 1998). This makes outsourcing an important decision for firms and therefore also an important perspective to look at in regards to how it relates to international trade and the income inequality gap. According to Feenstra and Hanson (2001) trade in intermediate goods can have an impact on wages that is much greater than for trade in final consumer goods. With that being said, the following assumption therefore considers the trade of intermediate goods to represent the movement of outsourcing. Lee and Sim (2012) found that outsourcing from developed and developing countries had opposite and significant effects on relative wage. Therefore the following prediction is made for hypothesis3, that outsourcing from developed to developing countries will indeed reduce the international income inequality gap. Ho: An increase in outsourcing from a developed to a developing country will not reduce the international income inequality gap. Ha: An increase in outsourcing from developed to developing countries will reduce the international income inequality gap. pg. 11

5. Data and Methodology 5.1 Data The data used in this paper was gathered from the World Bank database. The data consists of 221 countries measured over a time period from 1990 to 2012. The years before 1990 were excluded because there was relatively less data available for many countries especially for developing countries. This may causes some bias in the analysis regarding developing countries. The time period was also selected so that it would reveal recent data and since a lot of variables are gathered on a yearly basis, it was suitable to look at duration of 22 years. It must be noted that the data is an unbalanced panel data set due to the fact that not all countries have recorded information for all the years or the information was not available. Each country was classified as developed or developing for each year according to the World Bank classification standards 8. This paper classifies low-income economies and low-middle-income economies as developing countries and classifies upper-middle-income economies and high-income economies as developed countries. During the selected time period, it could be seen that at one point or during the entire time, 117 countries were classified as developed and 135 countries as developing. This also revealed that in total 41 countries switched between country classifications 9. The table 4 in the Appendix shows a list of all the countries and in which category they were classified. When testing hypothesis 2, a new variable will be added to the data set about bilateral trade. However, this new variable was only available for the year 1992 to 2012. For the third hypothesis, data on bilateral trade of only intermediate goods is obtained from the World Integrated Trade Solution (WITS) database, and the data was only gathered between the years 2003 to 2007. This time period was selected so that the 2008 crisis would be omitted, and data before 2003 was very limited. 8 Each year the World Bank has different standards of GNI that specifies in which category the economy belongs to, the World Bank classification table 3 in the appendix shows the exact amounts. 9 There have been 41 countries that switched from being developing to developed or vice versa within the time period 1990 and 2012 in the dataset. pg. 12

0 0 2.00e+134.00e+136.00e+138.00e+13 1000000 2000000 3000000 5.2 Trends Analyses of trends show that over the years, it can be seen that GDP has been increasing for both the developed and developing economies. In 2008 there was a dip in the upward slopping trend due to the financial crisis, but in general GDP has been increasing in its absolute value. The GDP gap can be said to also be increasing as the gap in 1990 is a lot smaller than the gap in 2012 (the difference between the developed economies and the developing economies). Therefore when looking at the absolute value it seems to be that developed countries have a steeper slope than the developing countries, making it seem as if they grow at a faster rate. (Figure 2a) The same can be said for the GDP per capita with the only difference being that there are two peeks, one in 2008 and the second in 2011. (Figure 2b) Total GDP per year GDP per capita for each year 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 year total_gdp_rich total_gdp total_gdp_poor 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 year total_gdppc_rich total_gdppc total_gdppc_poor Figure2a Figure 2b On the other hand GDP Growth rate which is the change in GDP has continuously been moving up and down. It can be seen that in the beginning of the 1990 s the GDP growth rate of the developing countries was lower than that of the developed economies but since roughly 2007 it has been the other way around, economic growth rate for the developing economies is higher than that of the developed economies. This brings the argument of convergence more interesting as it can be seen that economic growth is faster for developing countries than developed countries for the last few years. It can also be seen that due to the crisis there has been a large fall in economic growth for all the countries but it has affected the developed economies more than the developing. (Figure 3) pg. 13

-4-2 0 2 4 Average GDP growth rate per year for developed and developing countries 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 year meangdpgrowth_rich meangdpgrowth_poor Figure 3 When considering trade openness it can be seen at the average trade openness for the world has been increasing, with a small dip in 2008 due to the crisis but that in general it has an upward slowing curve (Figure 4 in appendix), similar conclusions can be said about the trend in exports (Figure 6a and Figure 6b in appendix). When analyzing total trade openness, it can be seen that there is an increasing trend until 2008. After the crisis there was a reduction, followed by a gradual recovery and then in 2011 again a fall. The most interesting observation is when total trade openness is analyzed separately for developed and developing countries. It can be seen that from 1990 till 2005 total trade openness for developing countries was at a higher rate than that of developed countries, and after 2005 they have been having a fall in trade openness. On the other hand total trade openness for developed countries has been in general increasing over the years and after 2005 they remain at a higher level than developing countries. (Figure 5) pg. 14

50 100 150 200 Total Trade Openness per year 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 year tot_tradeopenness_rich tot_tradeopenness tot_tradeopenness_poor Figure 5 5.3 Methodology First of all, the relevant variables used in the analysis will be defined. To measure the gap, changes in GDP per capita will be analyzed. The level of exports will be used to analyze international trade. This is done because a country that is more open to trade will export and import relatively more, and for simplicity this paper will only look at the volume of exports. Both hypothesis 2 and 3 focus on exports from developing countries as a factor that will reduce the gap, therefore variables that look at the share of exports and share of exports in intermediate goods will be used. The share of exports variable will calculate the proportion of exports that are sent to only developed countries and the share of exports in intermediate goods will calculate the proportion of exports in intermediate goods sent only to developed countries. The table 2 in the appendix lists the key variables and their description. To find the solution to hypothesis 1 a two sample z-test statistic for comparing two means 10 will be conducted. This will distinguish whether there is a higher GDP growth rate on average for developing countries and therefore prove that convergence may occure. In order to examine hypotheses 2 and 3, Ordinary Least Square (OLS) regressions will be used to regress GDP per capita (GDPPC) on the relevant variables for each hypothesis. All 10 Formula 1 in appendix shows the method used to calculate the z-test. pg. 15

variables will be used in natural logarithm form except for the control variable inflation, this is due to the fact that many countries may also face deflation. The time-order criterion for causal relationship implies that the independent variables must take place before the dependent variable. For this reason, lagged independent variables will be used in the regression, so it can explain what happen in period t based on knowledge of what happened in period t-1. For this paper to establish the impact trade has on the inequality gap it first has to establish the relationship trade has with GDP per capita. Models 1 will examine this relationship. Model 2 and 3 will do exactly the same as model 1 but will specify by only looking at developed countries first and then only look at developing countries. Ln(GDPPC) i,t = α + β 1 Ln(Export) i,t-1 + δ k X i,k,t-1 + y t + η i + ε i,t (1) Where i denotes countries and i = 1, 2, 3,, N and t denotes the years and t = 1990, 1991, 1992,, 2012. The dependent variable Ln(GDPPC) i,t is the natural logarithm of GDP per capita for country i in the year t. The summation, δ k X i,k,t-1 represents the control variable k for each country i in a time period of t-1. The list of control variables are explained in table 2 in the appendix. y t represents the year effect of year t, whereas η i is the country effect of country i. The error term,, accounts for the part of the effects that cannot be explained by the model. Once the relationship between international trade and GDP per capita have been established we can look at a more specific path of trade which might influence GDP. Hypothesis 2 will test whether exports from developing countries will increase the GDP and by doing so reduce the income gap. Model 4 will look at the relationship between GDP per capita and the share of exports to developed countries. Model 5 and 6 will specify the regression to developed countries and developing countries. These models will also incorporate the year and country fixed effects, plus the necessary error term. In addition to the control variables, the variable that represents trade in exports will also be included. Ln(GDPPC) i,t = α + β 2 (Share_Export) i,t-1 + δ k X i,k,t-1 + y t + η i + ε i,t (4) pg. 16

To understand international trade in another manner, hypothesis 3 focused on looking at outsourcing as a form on international trade. This was analyzed by looking at the trade in intermediate goods. Model 7 discovers the relationship between the share of export in intermediate goods to developed countries and the GDP per capita. This regression will only be conducted on developing countries during the years 2003 to 2007 due to the limited amount of data available. Model 7 will also include the trade variable plus the necessary control variables and fixed effects. Ln(GDPPC) i,t = α + β 3 (Share_INT) i,t-1 + δ k X i,k,t-1 + y t + η i + ε i,t (7) To check for the consistence of the results and for robustness a few extra regressions will be made. One change will look at an alternative dependent variable, another on a different method for representing international trade, and another would be the addition of the control variable education. The first robustness check will replace the dependent variable into the natural logarithm of GDP and not GDP per capita. This is assumed to have a similar result as the previous regressions as GDP is assumed to be positively correlated to international trade. For the second robustness check, the international trade variable will instead be measured as the natural logarithm of imports. Since the previous regressions looked at the trade in exports, the robustness check should roughly produce the same results, since one countries exports is another countries imports. The final robustness check will add the control variable for education. This variable although has a limited amount of observations, it is considered very important in many existing studies, for example the paper done by Bob Sutcliffe (2004) 11. Education is considered to drive up the number of skilled workers and increase a country s potentials in the long run. This variable will also allow the regression to be checked for omitted-variable bias (OVB) 12. The addition of this variable will be used to check whether adding another important control variable may change the results of the regression. 11 Bob Sutcliffe (2004), found that inequality continues to grow, but when adding other variables like life expectancy and education, then there is a reduction in inequality. 12 OBV occurs when a model is created which is incorrectly leaves out one or more important causal factors. The bias is then corrected by either underestimating or overestimating the effect on one of the other factors. pg. 17

6. Statistical Results 6.1 Descriptive Analysis Table 1 in the appendix, summarizes the descriptive statistics of three important variables with regard to developed and developing countries. The average GPDPC is much higher for developed countries, compared to developing countries. The large standard deviation of developed countries GDPPC indicates that there is large difference within this group. According to hypothesis 1, economic growth is higher for developing countries than for developed. When looking at the summary for this variable in Table 1, it can be seen that the mean for GDPPC growth is roughly the same, this means that both developed and developing countries have roughly been growing at the same rate. Using the information in table 1 we can generate the z-test statistic. After conducting the z-test on the null hypothesis of equal growth rate, it can be confirmed, as the z-test statistic is -0.00865, with a p-value of 0.49, and is therefore statistically insignificant even at 10%. Therefore, we can conclude that there is no difference between GDP growth of developed and developing countries. Therefore, GDPPC growth cannot be used as an explanation for the change in the inequality as proposed in hypothesis 1. 6.2 Empirical Analysis The results related to the effects of international trade on GDPPC are exhibited in Model (1), (2), and (3) in Table 5. In general, ln(export) has a positive effect on ln(gdppc), since the coefficient is positively significant at 1% level. This is consistent with the result of Zhang and Ondrich (2004), which found that higher export intensive countries have a higher per capita income. However, as exhibited in Model (2) and (3), the positive effect of trade is stronger for developed countries than for developing countries. This implies that developed countries benefit more from international trade than developing countries. Since the effect of trade on GDPPC is stronger for developed countries, this may cause the income inequality between developed and developing countries to enlarge further. From the added control variables, the coefficients for ln(population) are significantly negative, implying that GDPPC decreases as population increases. This is more severe in pg. 18

developing countries, as the coefficient for this group is approximately three times larger than the coefficient for developed countries in absolute value. The effect of consumption expenditures is not significant for the total sample and for developing countries, but it is significantly positive at 5% level for developed countries. This may be due to the fact that developed countries are close to their steady state, where consumption is high, while developing countries have to save more in order to accumulate more capital to get closer to their steady state. Moreover, Gross Capital Formation is only significantly positive in developed countries, this is consistent with the amount of accumulated capital in advanced economies over time. Finally, the inflation is slightly but significantly negative for the total sample, this is consistent with the observed negative relationship between inflation and GDP in the literature. When examining the effect of bilateral trade between developing and developed countries, the share of export to developed countries will be taken into account. The results for this is presented in Model (4) to (6) in Table 5. As observed, the coefficient of the share of export to developed countries, ln(share of export), is negative for all three models. However, only the coefficient for the total sample is significant. This result in general is surprising, because the larger the share of export goes to developed countries, the more negative it influences the GDPPC. The negative effect might be due to the high transaction costs and trade barriers, which are usually imposed by developed countries. When looking at developing and developed countries, the coefficient of the share of export to developed countries is not significant for developing countries nor developed countries. The effects of control variables remain similar as in Models (1) to (3). The significantly positive effect of trade, measured by export, on GDPPC is still larger for developed countries than developing countries. Therefore, there is not enough evidence to conclude that more export from developing countries to developed countries will reduce international income inequality. To examine the effect of outsourcing on the international income gap, this paper focuses on the share of intermediate goods that are exported from developing countries to developed countries. As presented in Model (7), the coefficient of the natural logarithm of the share of intermediate goods to developed countries is insignificant. This may be due to the fact that the export of intermediate goods, on average, is only a small fraction of a country s GDP. Its effect on GDPPC is therefore marginal (too small), compared to other pg. 19

control variables in the regression. Except ln(export), other control variables are not significant. This may be due to a statistical issue: the number of observations reduces significantly compared to previous models, as less data is available. The effect of trade is not only significantly positive at 1% level, but also is an increase compared to Model (3) and (6). To sum up, there is not enough evidence to conclude that an increase in outsourcing, in terms of the share of intermediate goods exporting from developing countries to developed countries, will reduce the international income inequality, as its effect on GDPPC is too small. On the other hand due to the rise in ln(export)=0.44 compared to model 3 and 6, it can be indirectly assumed that export of intermediate goods to developed countries will help trade in general and through that increase GDP. Each of the previous models will be tested in three ways for robustness. The results of the robustness test are presented in Table 6 (related to Model (1) to (3)), table 7 (related to Model (4) to (6)), and table 8 (related to Model (7)) Firstly, when replacing the dependent variable ln(gdppc) by the variable ln(gdp), the significance and the magnitude of the variables remain the same as the original models. Secondly, international trade will be measured by ln(import) instead. Even though more control variables have become significant, it comes to the same conclusions as in the case when using ln(export). Finally, when adding ln(education) to the control variables, as it is an important variable used in many literature, and to see whether the model is subjected to the omitted variable bias, it does not show any significance in any model. Also, it does not alter the results in this paper. Therefore, omitting the education variable is not a problem. This has proven that the methodology used in this paper is coherent and the results are robust/reliable. pg. 20

7. Conclusion The object of this paper was to shed light on the relationship between international trade and the inequality gap. The research question required that this paper look at the last few years and identify whether the inequality gap can be explained by international trade and whether the development of the economy matters. This paper defined the inequality gap as the difference in GDP per capita between countries that were classified as developed and developing. Hypothesis 1, assumed that economic growth in developing countries would be faster than developed countries and that therefore the gap would reduce. After analyzing the data it could be seen that GDP and the gap, both were increasing over time. But the GDP Growth was highly volatile to fluctuations for both the developed and developing countries. Even though it looked as if GDP Growth was faster in developing countries for a few years, it could be confirmed that GDP Growth cannot be said with significance that it was higher than for developed countries. Due to the fact that it was not significant, I cannot conclude that GDP growth is faster in developing countries, and therefore the null hypothesis 1 cannot be rejected. Hypothesis 2, assumed that if developing countries export more to developed countries then the inequality gap will reduce. The results showed that trade in exports did have a positive influence on the GDPPC. When looking at only developing countries I found that the share of exports to developed countries was negatively significant and that the total exports were positively significant. This allows me to conclude that there is not enough evidence for hypothesis 2 and therefore the null hypothesis 2 cannot be rejected. Hypothesis 3, assumed that since outsourcing has become more important to countries, if developed countries outsourced more to developing countries then the gap would reduce. It can be concluded that there is not enough evidence to reject the null hypothesis 3, and that outsourcing from developed countries may not help reduce the gap. On the other hand, it could be assumed that outsourcing does have an effect of trade on GDP indirectly and therefore may benefit the country. The argument that Feenstra and Hanson (1996) made can suggest that the inequality gap may not reduce as a result of outsourcing but that instead it raises the average skill-intensity of production in both pg. 21

locations. Either way because the share of intermediate goods is relatively a small part of total trade its effects may be insignificant to the inequality gap. Overall, this paper can conclude that there are many dimensions that have to be considered with regard to factors that influence the income gap. Due to the fact that exports benefited the developed country more than it did for developing countries, and in line with similar results found by Aradhyula, Rahman and Seenivason (2007), it can be said that when testing an unbalanced panel data set, trade openness increases income inequality overall. Therefore the impact that international trade would have on the income gap according to this study would suggest that there is an increase in the gap since developed countries are still benefiting more from trade than developing countries. 8. Limitation and suggestion This paper is limited in several ways. First of all, the problem of confounding between the dependent and independent factors was not considered. This means this paper did not look at any possible extraneous variables that might be directly or indirectly correlated to the dependent and independent variable. Another limitation that was encountered was the fact that the data set was unbalanced, and due to the lack of information available for each year and country the results and the data itself may be subjected to some degree of biasness. For further research, various aspects of this paper can be improved in order to obtain a more robust and broader view. One, suggestion that can be made is to include variables that show the effects of the country s geographical barriers, history (colonization) and perhaps trade policies (trade barriers). These are also factors that may have a significant influence on the gap. It might also be interesting to look at different ways to measure the income gap, for example by wage levels, consumption, consumer price index etc. To have a more solid conclusion about the causality of the gap with trade, a closer look at how northsouth trade and south-south trade influence the gap. Another suggestion would be to include outsourcing in the form of services, this would then give a more accurate view of the proportion of trade that is being outsourced. For example, many developing countries such as India have call centers and other services that are outsourced from firms in developed countries. It is also advised to may be analyze a longer period of time for outsourcing. pg. 22

References Abramovitz, M. (1986). Catch Up, Forging Ahead, and Falling Behind. The Journal of Economic History, Vol.46, No.2, 385-406. Aradhyula, S., Rahman, T., & Seenivasan, K. (2007). Impact of International Trade on Income and Income Inequality. Portland. Barro, R. J., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (1992). Convergence. The journal of Political Economy, 100, (2), 223-251. Bourguignon, F., & Morrisson, C. (2002). Inequality Among World Citizens: 1820-1992. The American Economic Review 92 (4), 727-744. Dollar, D., & Kraay, A. (2004). Trade, Growth, and Poverty. The Economic Journal, 114(493). Dye, F. (2014, May 18). WiseGeek. Opgehaald van What Is Economic Inequality?: http://www.wisegeek.com/what-is-economic-inequality.htm Edwards, S. (1992). Trade Orientation, Distortons and Growth in Developing Countries. Journal of Development Economics 39 (1), 31-57. Feenstra, R. C. (1998). Integration of Trade and Disintegration. Journal of Economic Perspectives- Volume 12 No.4, 31-50. Feenstra, R. C. (2004). Adavanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Feenstra, R. C., & Hanson, G. H. (2001). Global Production Sharing and Rising Inequality: A Survey on Trade and Wages. NBER Working Paper 8372. Ghose, A. K. (2001). Global economic inequality. Geneva: ILO publications. Ghose, A. K. (2004). Global inequality and international trade. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 229-252. Lee, H., & Sim, S. (2012). Global Outsourcing and Wage Inequality in Middle-Income Countries. Seoul: Department of Economics, Korea University,. Linder, S. (1961). An Essay on Trade and Transformation. Hoboken: NJ: John Wiley and Sons. Meschi, E., & Vivarelli, M. (2007). Globalization and Income Inequality. IZA Discussion Paper No. 2958. Morgan, R. E., & Katsikeas, C. S. (1997). Theories of international trade, foreign direct investment and firm internationalization: a critique. Wales: Cardiff Business School, University of Wales, UK. Nye, J. V. (2002). Standards of Living and Modern Economic Growth. Library Economics Liberty. O'Roueke, K. (2001). Globalization and Inequality: Historical Trends. NBER Working Papers 8339. Roser, M., & Cuaresma, J. C. (2011). Why is income inequality increasing. Satheesh Aradhyula, T. R. (2007). Impact of International Trade on Income and Income Inequality. American Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting, (p. 2). Portland. pg. 23

Sen, S. (2010). International Trade Theory and Policy: A Review of the Literature. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, Working Paper No. 635. Stewart, F. (1989). Recent Theories on international Trade: Some Implications for the Sounth. In H. Kierzkowski, Monopolistic Competetion and International Trade (pp. 84-108). Oxford: Clarendon Press. Wilkinson, R. (2011). Why inequality is bad for you and everyone else. Special to CNN. Zhang, S., Ondrich, J., & Richardson, J. (2004). The link between Trade and Income : Export Effect, Import Effect, or Both? New York: Department of Economics Sate University of New York at Fredonia. pg. 24

Appendix Formula 1 the z-test Here and are the means of the two samples, Δ is the hypothesized difference between the population means (in this case it is equal to 0 if testing for equal means), σ 1 and σ 2 are the standard deviations of the two populations, and n 1 and n 2 are the sizes of the two samples. Table 1 Variable Detail Total Developed Developing GDP_PC No. Of observations 4433 1850 2310 Mean 9760.344 19981.05 1186.096 Std. Dev. 16814.29 20130.36 964.128 Min 64.81015 1621.332 91.70108 Max 193892.3 193892.3 5192.769 GDP_PC growth No. Of observations 4369 1849 2309 Mean 2.016644 2.095081 2.096567 Std. Dev. 6.083057 4.082246 6.876959 Min -50.23583-16.58917-49.76177 Max 91.67289 33.89373 91.67289 Trade Openness No. Of observations 4137 1698 2253 Mean.8695893.9891565.7707151 Std. Dev..4994494.6194417.3647066 Min.1094877.1375305.1094877 Max 5.620622 5.620622 2.803611 pg. 25

0 5.00e+10 1.00e+11 1.50e+11 2.00e+11 2.50e+11 21 22 23 24 25.75.8 avg_tradeopenness.85.9.95 1 Figure 4 Average trade openness per year 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 year Figure 6a Figure 6b Average export from countries over time Average Log Exports by year 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 year exp_tot exp_rich exp_poor 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 year lnexp_tot lnexp_rich lnexp_poor Table 2 - Key Variables Variable Type Model Variable Description Dependent 1-7, 11-16, 20-26, 28 8-10, 17-19, 26 Independent 1-10, 14-19, 23-26, 28 11-13, 20-22, LnGDPPC LnGDP LnExp LnImp Natural Logarithm Gross Domestic Product per capita Natural Logarithm Gross Domestic Product Natural Logarithm of exports: total exports of goods and services measured in current US$ Natural Logarithm of imports: total imports of goods and services measured in current US$ pg. 26

27 4-6, 17-25 Share_Export Share of exports to developed countries as percentage of total exports 7, 26-28 Share_INT Share of exports in intermediate goods to developed countries as a percentage of total exports in intermediate goods Control (X) 1-28 LnFDI Natural Logarithm Foreign Direct Investment: net inflows of FDI measured as a percentage of GDP 1-28 LnGCF Natural Logarithm Gross Capital Formulation: calculated as a percentage of GDP 1-28 Lnpop Natural Logarithm of Population: Total Population 1-28 LnLE Natural Logarithm Life Expectancy: life expectancy at birth measured in total years 1-28 LnConsumption Natural Logarithm Consumption Expenditure: Final Consumption expenditure measured as a percentage of GDP 1-28 Inf Inflation: Annual percentage change of consumer prices 14-16, 23-25, 28 LnEdu Natural Logarithm Education: Percentage of population that enrolled in secondary school education Table 3 - World Bank classification Data for calendar year : Low income (L) Lower middle income (LM) Upper middle income (UM) High income (H) 1990 610 611-2,465 2,466-7,620 > 7,620 1991 635 636-2,555 2,556-7,910 > 7,910 1992 675 676-2,695 2,696-8,355 > 8,355 1993 695 696-2,785 2,786-8,625 > 8,625 1994 725 726-2,895 2,896-8,955 > 8,955 1995 765 766-3,035 3,036-9,385 > 9,385 1996 785 786-3,115 3,116-9,645 > 9,645 1997 785 786-3,125 3,126-9,655 > 9,655 1998 760 761-3,030 3,031-9,360 > 9,360 1999 755 756-2,995 2,996-9,265 > 9,265 2000 755 756-2,995 2,996-9,265 > 9,265 2001 745 746-2,975 2,976-9,205 > 9,205 2002 735 736-2,935 2,936-9,075 > 9,075 2003 765 766-3,035 3,036-9,385 > 9,385 pg. 27