The Political Economy of State-Owned Enterprises. Carlos Seiglie, Rutgers University, N.J. and Luis Locay, University of Miami. FL.

Similar documents
Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito

Migration, Intermediate Inputs and Real Wages

CHAPTER 18: ANTITRUST POLICY AND REGULATION

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana

Tax Competition and Migration: The Race-to-the-Bottom Hypothesis Revisited

Chapter 4: Specific Factors and

Taxation, Migration, and Pollution

Love of Variety and Immigration

INFANT INDUSTRY AND POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE PROTECTION

Thinkwell s Homeschool Microeconomics Course Lesson Plan: 31 weeks

Illegal Immigration, Immigration Quotas, and Employer Sanctions. Akira Shimada Faculty of Economics, Nagasaki University

Notes on exam in International Economics, 16 January, Answer the following five questions in a short and concise fashion: (5 points each)

Managing migration from the traditional to modern sector in developing countries

Immigration and Unemployment of Skilled and Unskilled Labor

Unemployment and the Immigration Surplus

CHAPTER 19 MARKET SYSTEMS AND NORMATIVE CLAIMS Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

Brain Drain and Emigration: How Do They Affect Source Countries?

Citation 經營と經濟, vol.90(4), pp.1-25; Issue Date Right.

The Political Economy of Trade Policy

July, Abstract. Keywords: Criminality, law enforcement, social system.

Labour Market Reform, Rural Migration and Income Inequality in China -- A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

ECONOMIC GROWTH* Chapt er. Key Concepts

Fertility, Income Distribution, and Growth

Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights in a. Product-cycle Model of Skills Accumulation

The Evolution of Development Thought: An Economist s Overview

Rural-urban Migration and Minimum Wage A Case Study in China

Thinkwell s Homeschool Economics Course Lesson Plan: 36 weeks

Illegal Immigration and Preferential Trade Liberalization. Subhayu Bandyopadhyay *

Introduction. Equilibrium in a Single Competitive Labor Market. (Pareto) Efficiency. Competitive Equilibrium Across Labor Markets.

Globalization, Child Labour, and Adult Unemployment

Chapter Ten Growth, Immigration, and Multinationals

POLITICAL POWER AND ENDOGENOUS POLICY FORMATION OUTLINE

Jens Hainmueller Massachusetts Institute of Technology Michael J. Hiscox Harvard University. First version: July 2008 This version: December 2009

Organized Interests, Legislators, and Bureaucratic Structure

The Impact of Decline in Oil Prices on the Middle Eastern Countries

Production Patterns of Multinational Enterprises: The Knowledge-Capital Model Revisited. Abstract

Migration, Tied Foreign Aid and the Welfare State

THE MACROECONOMIC IMPACT OF REMITTANCES IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES. Ralph CHAMI Middle East and Central Asia Department The International Monetary Fund

The Transfer of the Remittance Fee from the Migrant to the Household

Introduction to Labor Economics

IDE DISCUSSION PAPER No. 517

CH 19. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

The Poor Law, Migration, and Economic Growth

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different?

Wage Rigidity and Spatial Misallocation: Evidence from Italy and Germany

Impact of Education, Economic and Social Policies on Jobs

Chapter 12: Exploring Economic Equality. Understandings of Economic Equality

A condition for the reduction of urban unemployment in the Harris Todaro model

Professor Christina Romer. LECTURE 13 LABOR AND WAGES March 2, 2017

Chapter 5: Internationalization & Industrialization

AConstrainedChoiceProductivityandPoliticalActivity

1. Introduction. The Stock Adjustment Model of Migration: The Scottish Experience

POLI 12D: International Relations Sections 1, 6

Chapter 7. Urbanization and Rural-Urban Migration: Theory and Policy 7-1. Copyright 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

George Mason University

TAMPERE ECONOMIC WORKING PAPERS NET SERIES

Migration, Wages and Unemployment in Thailand *

A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM SKILL ACQUISITIONS MODEL OF DEVELOPMENT FOR LESOTHO

Economic aspects of Croatian emigration

Butter and Guns: Complementarity between Economic and Military Competition

Investing Like China

Chapter 6: Economic Systems. Economics: how people choose to use scarce resources in order to produce and buy the goods they want.

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Strategic Interaction, Trade Policy, and National Welfare - Bharati Basu

How Migration can change Income Inequality: The case of Israel

Economic Development and Transition

Is Sustainable Growth Possible Through Financial Assistance

Forced to Policy Extremes: Political Economy, Property Rights, and Not in My Backyard (NIMBY)

Political Power and Economic Policy. Theory, Analysis, and Empirical Applications

Immigration and voting on the size and the composition of public spending

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Macroeconomics, Questions 6-7

The China Syndrome. Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States. David H. Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon H.

Trans-boundary Pollution and International. Migration

Competitiveness: A Blessing or a Curse for Gender Equality? Yana van der Muelen Rodgers

Public Choice Part IV: Dictatorship

Market failures. If markets "work perfectly well", governments should just play their minimal role, which is to:

Chapter 10 Worker Mobility: Migration, Immigration, and Turnover

The Long Term Economic Impacts of Reducing Migration in the UK

Are Second-Best Tariffs Good Enough?

Brain Gain: Claims about Its Size and Impact on Welfare and Growth Are Greatly Exaggerated

11/7/2011. Section 1: Answering the Three Economic Questions. Section 2: The Free Market

Illegal Immigration. When a Mexican worker leaves Mexico and moves to the US he is emigrating from Mexico and immigrating to the US.

Toil and Tolerance: A Tale of Illegal Migration

Trade Liberalization and Pro-Poor Growth in South Africa. By James Thurlow

School of Economics Shandong University Jinan, China Pr JOSSELIN March 2010

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Honors General Exam Part 1: Microeconomics (33 points) Harvard University

Volume Author/Editor: Jagdish N. Bhagwati, editor. Volume URL:

Ideological party and regulation theory 1

International migration and human capital formation. Abstract. Faculté des Sciences Economiques, Rabat, Morocco and Conseils Eco, Toulouse, France

From the Grabbing Hand to the Helping Hand

Immigration and The Economic Crisis: Does recession make a Difference?

Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability by Timothy Besley and Andrea Prat (2006)

Corruption and Political Competition

EURASIAN JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE

Making Trade Globalization Inclusive. Joseph E. Stiglitz ASSA Meetings Philadelphia January 2018

International labor migration and social security: Analysis of the transition path

The Transition from Communism:

Is Government Size Optimal in the Gulf Countries of the Middle East? An Answer

ECONOMIC SYSTEMS AND DECISION MAKING. Understanding Economics - Chapter 2

Transcription:

The Political Economy of State-Owned Enterprises Carlos Seiglie, Rutgers University, N.J. and Luis Locay, University of Miami. FL. In this paper we wish to explain certain "stylized facts" of the Cuban economy, both past and present, as well as outline certain features which will be prevalent during a transition to a market economy with private property rights. We employ a "new political economy" or "public choice" framework to understand the effects that economic variables have on the political support for the regime. We begin by first developing the model. We then proceed to derive comparative statics results which we use to interpret recent events which have occurred in Cuba. We conclude by making some observations regarding a major obstacle which confronts transitional economies, namely the need to reduce employment to more efficient levels. I. The Model The politician, bureaucracy or dictator in a socialist regime is seen as choosing policies which maximize the political support they receive from possible coalitions. This level of support is denoted by S. Let support be derived from two policies, namely increasing employment, L, and providing some amount of other government services, e.g., education or health care which we denote by G. Assume for simplicity all industry is State-controlled, so the State is the sole recipient of profits or is liable for losses, [[pi]], from these enterprises. These, along with foreign borrowing or foreign aid, b, are the government's only sources of revenue to finance, G. Formally, the regime (dictator) seeks to maximize support, S, where subject to: where L f is full-employment or some other target level of employment; x denotes the level of output; p is the price; w, the wage rate and K and r are the amounts and cost of capital, respectively. Furthermore, we assume that [[partialdiff]]s/[[partialdiff]]l,[[partialdiff]]s/[[partialdiff]]g>0, namely that support for the regime is increasing in government transfers and employment. Note that, for simplicity, there is only one industry and that the government restricts competition by restricting imports so as to permit for [[pi]]>0. Our solution is arrived at by solving the following constrained optimization problem: The first-order conditions are:

Solving out for [[lambda]] we get: or In other words, a support maximizing regime will always employ more labor than is socially optimal (where the value of the marginal product is equal to the wage rate) and which maximizes profits. Figure 1 depicts the political equilibrium implied by equation (9). Note that profit maximization, and therefore efficiency, would require the employment of L* amount of workers, yet the regime employs L". The slope of the iso-support curve, So, is given by the left-hand side of equation (9) while that of the government's budget constraint by the right-hand term. Political equilibrium dictates that the marginal political benefits of increasing employment beyond the efficient point, [[partialdiff]]s/[[partialdiff]]l be equal to the cost, namely the reduction in political support which results from providing the marginal worker with a subsidy of (pfl - w). Note that this subsidy drains the government of revenues which it could use for other purposes. II. Some Comparative Statics First of all, note that as a result of employing more labor than is optimal the marginal productivity of capital is increased. If the planning ministry takes the cost of capital as established in the world market as the domestic price of capital it will tend to over-invest in capital as a result of its higher marginal productivity. In other words, there exists a bias for industries to be more capital-intensive. Whether they are depends upon the political incentive to maintain full employment. Second, a decrease in subsidies from a foreign country (e.g., Russia) can be viewed as a capital outflow resulting in a fall in the marginal productivity of labor and consequently, a fall in the political support for the regime (see Figure 2). Similarly, an increase in the price of one of its inputs (oil) which had previously been subsidized by the former Soviet Union has the same effect. Conversely, infusions of foreign capital has the opposite effect, i.e., increasing productivity, the state industry's net revenues and therefore increasing or in a dynamic context, maintaining support. Formally, we can derive a series of implications from the model by totally differentiating equations (6) and (7) along with the constraint that G = px-wl-rk + b. In matrix notation this yields:

Using Cramer's rule we can solve the above system for the desired comparative statics results: where [[Delta]] is the determinant of the matrix in (10), which is positive by the second-order conditions for a maximum. Although not necessary, we assume that [[partialdiff]] 2 S/[[partialdiff]]G[[partialdiff]]L>0, [[partialdiff]] 2 S/[[partialdiff]]G[[partialdiff]]L f >0 and [[partialdiff]] 2 S/[[partialdiff]]L[[partialdiff]]L f <0, i.e., that the marginal political support for the regime as it increases social expenditures is increasing in the level of employment and in the size of the work force, and decreasing in the level of unemployment (or underemployment). Similarly, we can derive comparative statics for the effects of the exogenous variable on the level of employment. We summarize other implications of the model: 1) A fall in the world price of its tradable goods (terms of trade) results in a movement away from its target of full employment, a decline in State provided services and political support for the regime. 2) Emigrations (a fall in L f ) increases the internal support of the regime (even if those that emigrate are strong supporters) by shifting the shape of the iso-support functions such that the new political equilibrium is one towards greater efficiency in production, government revenues and, therefore, support for the regime. 3) Trade sanctions (if they are effective) can be viewed as reducing prices, p, increasing transaction costs, or increasing the cost of some of the inputs required in production, either of which shifts down the government's budget constraint and reduces support for the current regime. A similar effect results from capital (lending) restrictions where the government's budget constraint shifts down as the marginal

productivity of labor declines, and therefore so does support. 4) Current interest in attracting private capital is aimed at offsetting the decline in capital from the former USSR and limiting decline in support (expands constraint). 5) The same is true of the recent policy of allowing the use of dollars to increase international reserves (expands constraint). 6) A dual system of private investors allowed to maximize profits and produce efficiently, e.g., in the tourist sector, is incompatible, as more productive workers will flow from State industries to private industries leading to a collapse in the "full-employment system" because of sectoral distortions. These are just some of the implications derivable from this framework which have relevance to the case of Cuba. It is important to point out that as the level of support for the regime declines as economic conditions deteriorate,e.g., as foreign loans (aid) declines or the level of production, x (sugar) falls, the government has an incentive to reverse the process by allowing foreign ownership of specific industries. For example, if we now denote the profits from the state-run industries by [[pi]]1 and those earned by foreigners [[pi]]2, and the government taxes these profits at the rate t, then the governments budget constraint given by equation (2) is replaced by We can see that this will result in both an increase in G and L accompanied by an increase (or a slowing down of the deterioration) in support for the regime. During a transition to a market economy there exists political pressures to continue to maintain a more than optimal number of workers employed in the state-owned industries and therefore the economy. This can be seen by analyzing Figure 3. The political equilibrium in this case is given by an employment level of Lo which is not socially optimal. The socially optimal level of employment at L* yields less political support for the regime, so therefore there will be pressure to enact labor laws governing the conditions of labor contracts. These laws (which are not so different from those outlined in the Constitution of 1940) will impose large deadweight losses on the economy and are doomed to exact large costs on the development of the Cuban economy if the pressure to enact them is not resisted. III. Concluding Remarks We make a final observation regarding the employment policy of a socialist regime in transition. The fact that these economies tend to employ more labor than is socially optimal leads to the marginal productivity of capital being high. Foreign investors may be attracted by this high return to capital prior to the transition towards a smaller work force. But as the transition occurs and unemployment (in the short run) increases, it reduces the marginal productivity of capital. While the economy adjusts to more efficient methods of production we should expect that the reduced returns to capital will temper foreign investment after the transition. [For Figures 1, 2, 3, please contact the authors.] Bibliography Becker, Gary S. "Public Policies, Pressure Groups and Dead-Weight Costs." Journal of Public Economics, December 1985, 329-47.

Brennan, G. and J. Buchanan. The Power to Tax. Cambridge University Press, 1980. Findlay, R. and J.D. Wilson. "The Political Economy of Leviathan," in A. Razin and E. Sadka, eds., Policy in Theory and Practice. New York: Macmillan, 1987. Findlay, Ronald. "The New Political Economy: Its Explanatory Power for LDCs," in Gerald Meier, Economic Development and Public Policy. San Francisco, 1992. Locay, L. and C. Seiglie. "Endogenous Political Structures," in George P. Montalván (ed.), Cuba In Transition, Volume 2: Papers and Proceedings of the Second Annual Meeting of the Association for the Study of the Cuban Economy. Miami, FL: Florida International University, 1993, pp. 241-254. Peltzman, Sam. "Toward a More General Theory of Regulation." Journal of Law and Economics, August 1976, 211-40. Seiglie, Carlos. "A Theory of the Politically Optimal Commodity Tax." Economic Inquiry, July 1990. Stigler, George. Chicago Studies in Political Economy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988.