Online Appendix. Capital Account Opening and Wage Inequality. Mauricio Larrain Columbia University. October 2014

Similar documents
Capital Account Opening and Wage Inequality

Gender effects of the crisis on labor market in six European countries

The Changing Relationship between Fertility and Economic Development: Evidence from 256 Sub-National European Regions Between 1996 to 2010

Fertility rate and employment rate: how do they interact to each other?

Appendix to Sectoral Economies

The Israeli Economy: Current Trends, Strength and Challenges

Commission on Growth and Development Cognitive Skills and Economic Development

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

The Effect of ICT Investment on the Relative Compensation of High-, Medium-, and Low-Skilled Workers: Industry versus Country Analysis

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications

WORLDWIDE DISTRIBUTION OF PRIVATE FINANCIAL ASSETS

Do Institutions have a Greater Effect on Female Entrepreneurs?

Migration and the European Job Market Rapporto Europa 2016

Employment Outlook 2017

Taiwan s Development Strategy for the Next Phase. Dr. San, Gee Vice Chairman Taiwan External Trade Development Council Taiwan

Upgrading workers skills and competencies: policy strategies

Curing Europe s Growing Pains: Which Reforms?

Is This Time Different? The Opportunities and Challenges of Artificial Intelligence

Can free-trade policies help to reduce gender inequalities in employment and wages?

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads

Dirk Pilat:

Inclusive global growth: a framework to think about the post-2015 agenda

Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries

Recent trends in the internationalisation of R&D in the enterprise sector. Thomas Hatzichronoglou

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018

Inclusion and Gender Equality in China

Corporatism and the Labour Income Share

The Transmission of Economic Status and Inequality: U.S. Mexico in Comparative Perspective

Gains from Trade. Is Comparative Advantage the Ideology of the Comparatively Advantaged?

Recent demographic trends

Volume 30, Issue 1. Corruption and financial sector performance: A cross-country analysis

The Foreign-born Population in the EU and its contribution to National Tax and Benefit Systems. Andrew Dabalen World Bank

The Global Economic Crisis Sectoral coverage

Regional and Sectoral Economic Studies

Context Indicator 17: Population density

What Creates Jobs in Global Supply Chains?

Global Trends in Location Selection Final results for 2005

Political Skill and the Democratic Politics of Investment Protection

LANDMARKS ON THE EVOLUTION OF E-COMMERCE IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Ignacio Molina and Iliana Olivié May 2011

STATISTICAL REFLECTIONS

EU Labour Markets from Boom to Recession: Are Foreign Workers More Excluded or Better Adapted?

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

SEPTEMBER TRADE UPDATE ASIA TAKES THE LEAD

Income and Population Growth

Wages in utilities in 2010

EU exports to Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

OECD ECONOMIC SURVEY OF LITHUANIA 2018 Promoting inclusive growth

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005

GALLERY 5: TURNING TABLES INTO GRAPHS

Exposure to Immigrants and Voting on Immigration Policy: Evidence from Switzerland

OECD expert meeting hosted by the Norwegian Ministry of Education and Research Oslo, Norway 2-3 June 2008 ICTs and Gender Pierre Montagnier

The High Cost of Low Educational Performance. Eric A. Hanushek Ludger Woessmann

Industrial & Labor Relations Review

Trade liberalization and gender inequality

Identification of the respondent: Fields marked with * are mandatory.

The Impact of Foreign Workers on the Labour Market of Cyprus

In 2012, million persons were employed in the EU

TRIPS OF BULGARIAN RESIDENTS ABROAD AND ARRIVALS OF VISITORS FROM ABROAD TO BULGARIA IN SEPTEMBER 2015

Labour mobility within the EU - The impact of enlargement and the functioning. of the transitional arrangements

OECD Health Data 2009 comparing health statistics across OECD countries

THE NOWADAYS CRISIS IMPACT ON THE ECONOMIC PERFORMANCES OF EU COUNTRIES

BUILDING RESILIENT REGIONS FOR STRONGER ECONOMIES OECD

Civil and Political Rights

How does education affect the economy?

Differences in National IQs behind the Eurozone Debt Crisis?

The WTO Trade Effect and Political Uncertainty: Evidence from Chinese Exports

New Approaches to Measuring the Impacts of STI Policy

The political economy of electricity market liberalization: a cross-country approach

Estimating the foreign-born population on a current basis. Georges Lemaitre and Cécile Thoreau

ISSUE BRIEF: U.S. Immigration Priorities in a Global Context

Inward Greenfield FDI and Patterns of Job Polarization

The Economic and Financial Crisis and Precarious Employment amongst Young People in the European Union

Does Manufacturing Co-Locate with Intermediate Services?: Analysing the World Input-Output Database

Size and Development of the Shadow Economy of 31 European and 5 other OECD Countries from 2003 to 2013: A Further Decline

IMMIGRATION IN THE EU

2014 BELGIAN FOREIGN TRADE

3.1. Importance of rural areas

European Union Passport

Gendered Employment Data for Global CGE Modeling

TRIPS OF BULGARIAN RESIDENTS ABROAD AND ARRIVALS OF VISITORS FROM ABROAD TO BULGARIA IN AUGUST 2015

Francis Green and Golo Henseke

TRIPS OF BULGARIAN RESIDENTS ABROAD AND ARRIVALS OF VISITORS FROM ABROAD TO BULGARIA IN AUGUST 2016

Working Party on Territorial Indicators

TRIPS OF BULGARIAN RESIDENTS ABROAD AND ARRIVALS OF VISITORS FROM ABROAD TO BULGARIA IN MAY 2017

TRIPS OF BULGARIAN RESIDENTS ABROAD AND ARRIVALS OF VISITORS FROM ABROAD TO BULGARIA IN MARCH 2016

GDP per capita was lowest in the Czech Republic and the Republic of Korea. For more details, see page 3.

Migration, Mobility and Integration in the European Labour Market. Lorenzo Corsini

The effect of a generous welfare state on immigration in OECD countries

TRIPS OF BULGARIAN RESIDENTS ABROAD AND ARRIVALS OF VISITORS FROM ABROAD TO BULGARIA IN FEBRUARY 2017

POPULATION AND MIGRATION

Transcription:

Online Appendix Capital Account Opening and Wage Inequality Mauricio Larrain Columbia University October 2014 A.1 Additional summary statistics Tables 1 and 2 in the main text report summary statistics for the Chinn and Ito (2006) capital account openness index and aggregate wage inequality for each country, respectively. In this section, I report the evolution of both variables across countries and time. Table A.1 reports the evolution of the capital account openness index. According to the table, there is substantial variation of capital market openness both across countries and across time. Eastern European countries opened very quickly towards the end of the sample. Some countries (e.g., Denmark and Italy) opened in the 1980s. Other countries opened in the 1990s (e.g., Portugal and Spain). [Include Table A.1 here] Table A.2 reports the evolution of wage inequality across countries and time. Wage inequality between 1975 and 2005 increased in more than half of the countries in the sample. It increased particularly in Eastern European countries, but decreased in Scandinavian countries. The table also reports the evolution of wage inequality separately for manufacturing and non-manufacturing industries. For a given year, wage inequality in manufacturing sectors is on average higher than in non-manufacturing sectors. The large increase in wage inequality in Eastern European countries is heavily influenced by the increase in inequality in manufacturing industries. [Include Table A.2 here] A.1

A.2 Reverse causality In order to rule out concerns about reverse causality, I analyze whether pre-existing wage inequality in sectors with high financial dependence and strong complementarity explains the timing of the openings. In order to obtain a precise date of opening, I define the opening year as the year in which the Chinn and Ito (2006) openness index of acountryincreasesbymorethanonestandarddeviationacrossallcountriesandyears. Next, I rank all industries according to the product of both sectoral indices. Sectors with high financial dependence and strong complementarity are defined as those for which the product of the two sectoral indices is above the median of the product across sectors. Then, for each country I calculate average wage inequality in sectors with high financial dependence and strong complementarity before the opening year. Finally, I regress the capital opening year on pre-existing wage inequality in the aforementioned sectors. The results are reported in Table A.3. In column (1), I analyze the impact of the level of wage inequality on the opening year. The e ect is not statistically significant. In column (2), I analyze the impact of the change in wage inequality. Again, the e ect is not significant. According to these results, the timing of capital account opening does not vary with the degree of pre-existing wage inequality in sectors with high dependence and strong complementarity. [Include Table A.3 here] A.3 CSC estimation: system GMM In Section 3 of the main text, I estimated the skilled labor share equation (5) using adi erencegmmestimator. Inthissection,Ishowthatmyresultsarerobustto estimating the equation with a system GMM estimator, which combines the regression in di erences and in levels. For convenience, I re-write the skilled labor share equation here: ShareSkilled ct = + log(inequality) ct + log(capintensity) ct + c + t + " ct. For the system GMM estimation, the instruments for the regression in di erences are the same as in the text. The moment conditions for the regression in di erences are: E[z ct j " ct ]=0forj 2,t 3, where z =[ShareSkilled, Inequality, CapIntensity]. A.2

The instruments for the regression in levels are the lagged di erences of the corresponding variables. These are appropriate instruments under the additional assumption of no correlation between the di erences of these variables and the country fixed e ects. This leads to the following additional moment conditions for the regression in levels: E[ z ct j " ct ]=0forj 2,t 3. Table A.4 reports the estimates of the skilled labor share equation for each industry. The coe cient of correlation between this alternative capital-skill complementarity index and the original index is 0.92. In Table A.5, I re-estimate the e ect of capital account opening on sectoral wage inequality, using the alternative complementarity measure. According to the results, the coe cient of the triple interaction term is significant and very similar in magnitude than the coe cient obtained using the original complementarity measure (see Table 8). Therefore, my results are robust to estimating the complementarity index with system GMM. [Include Tables A.4 and A.5 here] A.4 Compositional e ects The transmission mechanism that I highlight in this paper works at the firm level. An alternative story is that capital opening induces skill-intensive firms to expand. This would change the within-industry composition of firms towards more skill-intensive firms, increasing the relative demand for skilled labor. This compositional e ect could lead to higher wage inequality, even if firms do not exhibit capital-skill complementarity. As before, there would be a threat to identification only if this between-firm e ect is particularly strong in industries with high external dependence and strong complementarity. To disentangle the within-firm and between-firm channels, I would have to conduct the analysis at the firm level. Unfortunately, I do not have access to a cross-country firm-level dataset with wage inequality information. However, I do have access to afirm-leveldatasetforanemergingmarket,chile,whichcontainswageinformation for production (i.e., blue-collar) and non-production (i.e., white-collar) workers. The dataset, called ENIA, is an annual survey covering all manufacturing firms in Chile. 1 1 ENIA stands for Encuesta Nacional Industrial Anual. The data covers the period 1979-1998 and comes from Alvarez and Crespi (2007). A.3

Iconductafirm-levelestimationtoanalyzethee ectofopeningonwithin-firmoutcomes: log(x) jit = Openness t Z i + j + t + " jit, where x is either capital stock per unit of skilled labor or wage inequality of firm j in industry i in year t. 2 Z i denotes either external financial dependence or capital-skill complementarity of industry i. Thespecificationincludesasetoffirmfixede ects( j ) and year fixed e ects ( t ). Firm fixed e ects control for all time-invariant company characteristics. I cluster standard errors at the industry level. Table A.6 reports the results. In column (1), I exploit variation in external financial dependence across sectors and analyze the e ect on the capital stock. I find that capital opening increases within-firm capital stock particularly in externally dependent sectors. In column (2), I exploit cross-sectoral variation in complementarity and estimate the e ect on wage inequality. 3 According to the results, opening increases within-firm wage inequality particularly in sectors with strong complementarity. These findings support the within-firm channel. [Include Table A.6 here] Finally, I analyze whether opening the capital account leads skill-intensive firms to expand. To measure skill intensity, I use the lagged ratio of skilled to unskilled labor. I estimate the e ect on firm-level production: log(output) jit = Openness t SkillIntensity j,t 1 + j + t + " jit Column (3) of Table A.6 reports the results. The results show that skill-intensive firms do not expand more than non skill-intensive firms after capital opening. This finding provides evidence against the between-firm composition channel. A.5 E ect across demographic groups Capital opening a ects wage inequality di erentially across industries only if labor is imperfectly mobile across sectors. In the economy, there are some workers that are 2 I define wage inequality as the relative wage between non-production and production workers. 3 Since there is not su cient cross-sectional variation in the external dependence and complementarity indices within manufacturing, I only exploit variation in complementarity across sectors. A.4

more mobile than others. As a result, the di erential e ect on relative wages should vary across di erent types of workers. I focus on two demographic characteristics: age and sex. Since young workers have accumulated less sector-specific human capital than older workers, they are more mobile across sectors. Regarding sex, existing evidence shows that men tend to be more mobile than women. I divide each country-sector-year cell in the sample according to these demographic characteristics and re-estimate Equation (11) for each group. Column (1) of Table A.7 reports the results for young workers, which are defined as workers under the age of 50. Column (2) reports the results for older workers, those above 50. According to the results, the e ect is large and significant for older workers, but is not significant for young workers. Next, I divide the sample by sex. In column (3), I show the results for male workers and in column (4) for female workers. Although the e ect is significant for both groups, the magnitude of the e ect for women is more than twice the magnitude of the e ect for men. [Include Table A.7 here] A.6 Alternative samples In Table A.8, I re-estimate the sectoral regressions excluding the most developed countries from the sample. I rank all countries according to PPP-based GDP per capita in 1990 (the mid-year of the sample). In column (1), I drop the most developed country from the sample. In columns (2), (3), (4), I drop the two, three, and five most developed countries. According to the World Bank s WDI data, the countries with highest PPP-based GDP per capita in 1990 are (in order): Denmark, Belgium, Austria, Italy, and Japan. The magnitude of the triple interaction terms remains roughly constant across all four alternative samples and the e ect is always highly significant. This indicates that the results are driven by the less-developed, capital-scarce economies of the sample. [Include Table A.8 here] A.5

Table A.1: Capital Account Openness Index by Country and Time (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Average Average Average Average Cumulative Cum. Change 1970s 1980s 1990s 2000s Change (Annualized) Australia -0.106 1.042 2.191 1.132 1.239 0.041 Austria 1.132 1.132 2.059 2.456 1.323 0.044 Belgium 1.016 0.521 2.218 2.191 0.696 0.023 Czech Republic.. -0.106 1.808 2.562 0.285 Denmark -0.106 0.221 2.376 2.456 2.562 0.085 Finland 0.885 1.132 2.059 2.456 2.562 0.085 France -0.106-0.212 1.819 2.456 2.562 0.085 Greece -1.159-1.159 0.022 2.105 3.615 0.121 Hungary. -1.856-0.947 1.588 4.311 0.227 Ireland -0.524-0.106 1.555 2.456 3.258 0.109 Italy -1.856-0.456 1.819 2.456 4.311 0.144 Japan 1.185 2.297 2.323 2.456 1.323 0.044 Korea -0.738-0.738-0.528-0.106 1.053 0.035 Poland. -1.856-1.297-0.334 1.935 0.102 Portugal -1.159-0.949 1.422 2.456 3.615 0.121 Slovakia.. -1.159-0.275 2.033 0.226 Slovenia.. -0.370 1.397 3.086 0.343 Spain -0.528-0.106 1.290 2.456 3.615 0.121 Sweden 1.132 1.132 1.794 2.456 1.323 0.044 United Kingdom -0.363 2.297 2.456 2.456 3.258 0.109 Notes: the table reports the evolution of the capital account openness index for the 20 countries in the sample during the period 1975-2005. The openness index comes from Chinn and Ito (2006) index. Columns (1)-(4) report the average of the index over di erent decades; Column (5) reports the cumulative change of the index; Column (6) reports the annualized cumulative change. A.6

Table A.2: Aggregate Wage Inequality by Country and Time (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Average Average Average Average Cum. Change Cum. Change Cum. Change 1970s 1980s 1990s 2000s All Sectors Manuf. Non-manuf. Australia. 1.463 1.474 1.551 0.006-0.001 0.010 Austria. 1.650 1.557 1.488-0.005-0.004-0.007 Belgium. 1.478 1.528 1.499 0.001 0.006-0.000 Czech Republic.. 2.239 2.283 0.007 0.010 0.004 Denmark. 1.581 1.448 1.415-0.009-0.009-0.009 Finland 1.870 1.697 1.550 1.565-0.010-0.004-0.014 France. 1.882 1.865 1.767-0.013-0.014-0.017 Greece.. 1.570 1.527-0.001-0.007-0.009 Hungary.. 2.315 2.477 0.030 0.004 0.009 Ireland. 1.716 1.825 1.864 0.012 0.006 0.009 Italy 1.255 1.197 1.235 1.429 0.007-0.010-0.005 Japan 1.694 1.660 1.701 1.628-0.003-0.001-0.002 Korea 2.014 1.962 1.632 1.526-0.013-0.009-0.016 Poland.. 1.573 1.546 0.001 0.009 0.006 Portugal.. 2.243 2.392 0.023-0.010-0.009 Slovakia.. 1.796 1.776 0.004 0.013 0.003 Slovenia.. 2.102 2.134-0.010-0.034-0.013 Spain. 1.435 1.615 1.670 0.014 0.004 0.005 Sweden. 1.538 1.543 1.465-0.003-0.007-0.009 United Kingdom 1.836 1.861 1.834 1.950 0.001-0.002 0.004 Notes: thetablereportstheevolutionofaggregatewageinequalityforthe20countriesinthesampleduringtheperiod1975-2005.wageinequalityisdefined as the relative wage between workers with college and high-school education. Columns (1)-(4) report average wage inequality over di erent decades; Column (5) reports the annualized cumulative change over the entire sample period for all sectors; Column (6) reports the change for manufacturing sectors; Column (7) reports the change for non-manufacturing sectors. A.7

Table A.3: E ect of Pre-existing Wage Inequality on Timing of Capital Account Opening (1) (2) Pre-existing Inequality Level 0.0014 (0.0061) Pre-existing Inequality Change 0.0003 (0.0009) Observations 20 20 R-squared 0.199 0.070 Notes: the table reports the estimates of the e ect of pre-existing wage inequality in sectors with high financial dependence and strong complementarity on the year of capital account opening. Sectors with high financial dependence and strong complementarity are defined as those for which the product of the two sectoral indices is above the median of the product across sectors. The opening year is defined as the year in which the Chinn and Ito (2006) openness index of a country increases by more than one standard deviation of the index across all countries and years. Column (1) uses as independent variable the pre-existing level of wage inequality; Column (2) uses as independent variable the pre-existing change in wage inequality. ***, **, * denote statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%. A.8

Table A.4: Sectoral Index of Capital-skill Complementarity: Calculated Using System GMM (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Industry Industry Coe. StdDev. Coe. StdDev. Number of Name ISIC code Beta Beta Gamma Gamma Observations (CSC index) Manufacturing of wood 20 0.425*** 0.057 0.143*** 0.025 317 Manufacturing of coke, refined petroleum 23 0.87*** 0.081 0.022* 0.012 317 Manufacturing of chemicals 24 0.901*** 0.063 0.065** 0.03 317 Manufacturing of rubber, plastics 25 0.729*** 0.074 0.3*** 0.029 317 Manufacturing of other non-metallic mineral prod. 26 0.58*** 0.086 0.249*** 0.031 317 Manufacturing of machinery and equipment 29 0.782*** 0.059-0.106*** 0.017 317 Construction 45 1.542*** 0.097 0.08** 0.032 317 Wholesale trade and commission trade 51 1.725*** 0.066 0.171*** 0.03 317 Retail trade, except of motor vehicles 52 1.958*** 0.056-0.187*** 0.026 317 Hotels and restaurants 55 0.939*** 0.046 0.16*** 0.027 317 Post and telecommunications 64 0.977*** 0.066 0.345*** 0.031 317 Real estate activities 70 1.357*** 0.028-0.013 0.023 317 Education 80 0.692*** 0.033-0.077*** 0.011 317 Health and social work 85 0.638*** 0.054-0.096*** 0.019 317 Notes: the table reports the estimates of the skilled labor share equation for each of the 15 two-digit industries in the sample. The estimation is conducted using system GMM. Columns (2) and (3) report the coe cient and standard deviation of the elasticity of the share of wages paid to skilled labor with respect to relative wages; Columns (4) and (5) report the coe cient and standard deviation of the elasticity with respect to capital intensity. The coe cient of column (4) corresponds to the capital-skill complementarity index. Standard errors are clustered at the country level. ***, **, * denote statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%. A.9

Table A.5: E ect of Capital Account Opening on Sectoral Wage Inequality: Complementarity Index Calculated Using System GMM (1) (2) (3) (4) Capital Openness 0.007 0.006 (0.010) (0.010) Fin. Dep. -0.099*** (0.012) Comp. 0.074*** (0.027) Capital Openness * Fin. Dep. -0.033-0.014-0.033-0.014*** (0.019) (0.020) (0.020) (0.004) Capital Openness * Comp. 0.003 0.011 0.003 0.011 (0.021) (0.025) (0.022) (0.010) Capital Openness * Fin. Dep. * Comp. 0.201*** 0.120 0.201*** 0.120*** (0.060) (0.071) (0.062) (0.029) Fixed E ects Country Yes No No No Year Yes No No No Country-year No No Yes Yes Country-industry No Yes Yes Yes Industry-year No Yes No Yes Observations 6,480 6,480 6,480 6,480 R-squared 0.899 0.898 0.932 0.933 Notes: thetablereportstheestimatesofthee ectofcapitalaccountopeningonsectoralwageinequality.thecapitalskill complementarity index is calculated using system GMM. Column (1) includes country and year fixed e ects; Column (2) includes country-industry and industry-year fixed e ects; Column (3) includes country-year and countryindustry fixed e ects; Column (4) includes country-year, country-industry, and sector-year fixed e ects. Fin. Dep. stands for external financial dependence and Comp. for capital-skill complementarity. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the country level. ***, **, * denote statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%. A.10

Table A.6: E ect of Capital Account Opening on Sectoral Wage Inequality: Firm-level Evidence (1) (2) (3) Capital Wage Output Stock Inequality Capital Openness * Fin. Dep. 0.048* (0.028) Capital Openness * Comp. 0.119** (0.059) Capital Openness * Skill intensity(-1) 0.002 (0.002) Fixed E ects Firm Yes Yes Yes Year Yes Yes Yes Observations 14,217 13,321 11,692 R-squared 0.850 0.627 0.954 Notes: the table reports the estimates of the e ect of capital account opening on firm-level outcomes in Chile. The firm-level data comes from ENIA. Columns (1), (2), (3) estimate the e ect on the capital stock per unit of skilled labor, wage inequality, and production, respectively. Fin. Dep. stands for external financial dependence; Comp. stands for capital-skill complementarity; Skill intensity(-1) stands for lagged ratio of skilled to unskilled labor. All specifications include firm and year fixed e ects. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the firm level. ***, **, * denote statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%. A.11

Table A.7: E ect of Capital Account Opening on Sectoral Wage Inequality: Demographic Groups (1) (2) (3) (4) E ect by age E ect by sex Young Old Male Female Workers Workers Workers Workers Capital Openness * Fin. Dep. 0.020-0.038-0.040-0.151** (0.024) (0.036) (0.029) (0.070) Capital Openness * Comp. 0.099** -0.001 0.022-0.224** (0.036) (0.019) (0.035) (0.097) Capital Openness * Fin. Dep. * Comp. -0.059 0.219* 0.213* 0.612** (0.113) (0.118) (0.099) (0.245) Fixed E ects Country-year Yes Yes Yes Yes Country-industry Yes Yes Yes Yes Industry-year Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 5,210 5,223 5,234 5,223 R-squared 0.923 0.933 0.936 0.971 Notes: thetablereportstheestimatesofthee ectofcapitalaccountopeningonsectoralwageinequalityfordi erent demographic groups. Columns (1)-(2) divide the sample by age; Columns (3)-(4) by sex. Column (1) includes workers younger than 50; Column (2) workers older than 50. Column (3) includes male workers; Column (4) female workers. Fin. Dep. stands for external financial dependence and Comp. stands for capital-skill complementarity. All specifications include country-year, country-industry, and industry-year fixed e ects. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the country level. ***, **, * denote statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%. A.12

Table A.8: E ect of Capital Account Opening on Sectoral Wage Inequality: Alternative Samples (1) (2) (3) (4) Excluding Excluding Excluding Excluding most two most three most five most developed developed developed developed country countries countries countries Capital Openness * Fin. Dep. -0.026** -0.028** -0.028** 0.001 (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) (0.007) Capital Openness * Comp. 0.037** 0.044** 0.043** 0.023* (0.010) (0.010) (0.010) (0.013) Capital Openness * Fin. Dep.*Comp. 0.109*** 0.125*** 0.121*** 0.094*** (0.027) (0.027) (0.027) (0.023) Fixed e ects Country-year Yes Yes Yes Yes Country-industry Yes Yes Yes Yes Industry-year Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 6,090 5,700 5,310 3,615 R-squared 0.959 0.958 0.959 0.963 Notes: thetablereportstheestimatesofthee ectofcapitalaccountopeningonsectoralwageinequalityfordi erent sample of countries. Column (1) excludes the most developed country from the sample (highest PPP-based GDP per capita in 1990, the mid-year of the sample); Column (2) excludes the two most developed countries; Column (3) excludes the three most developed countries; Column (4) excludes the five most developed countries. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the country level. ***, **, * denote statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%. A.13