Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand

Similar documents
Trade, Diaspora and Migration to New Zealand

Trade and Migration to New Zealand

Trade Flows and Migration to New Zealand

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins

Bridging barriers. Pro-trade effects of immigration on Swedish exports. Axel Wijk Tegenrot

The Economic Relationship between Trade and Immigration in New Zealand

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS

The WTO Trade Effect and Political Uncertainty: Evidence from Chinese Exports

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach

Does the G7/G8 Promote Trade? Volker Nitsch Freie Universität Berlin

Commuting and Minimum wages in Decentralized Era Case Study from Java Island. Raden M Purnagunawan

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

Migration and Regional Trade Agreement: a (new) Gravity Estimation

Is the Great Gatsby Curve Robust?

Kosovo EU Trade Relations: A Dynamic Panel Poisson Approach

Emigration and source countries; Brain drain and brain gain; Remittances.

On the Determinants of Global Bilateral Migration Flows

Migration and trade flows: new evidence from Spanish regions

Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia. Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware. and

Immigration, Emigration and Trade in Sweden

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE TRADE CREATION EFFECT OF IMMIGRANTS: EVIDENCE FROM THE REMARKABLE CASE OF SPAIN. Giovanni Peri Francisco Requena

The Role of Internet Adoption on Trade within ASEAN Countries plus People s Republic of China

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Working Papers in Economics

Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins

The Flow Model of Exports: An Introduction

Does Vietnam s Entry into WTO Accelerate Its Trade Liberalization?

the notion that poverty causes terrorism. Certainly, economic theory suggests that it would be

Female Brain Drains and Women s Rights Gaps: A Gravity Model Analysis of Bilateral Migration Flows

5. Destination Consumption

A Gravitational Model of Crime Flows in Normal, Illinois:

School Quality and Returns to Education of U.S. Immigrants. Bernt Bratsberg. and. Dek Terrell* RRH: BRATSBERG & TERRELL:

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Measuring International Skilled Migration: New Estimates Controlling for Age of Entry

Analysis of China s Import from & Direct Investment in ASEAN Based on Gravity Models

Immigrant-Based Networks and the U.S. Bilateral Trade: Role of Immigrant Occupation

SIMPLE LINEAR REGRESSION OF CPS DATA

THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ECONOMIC INTEGRATION: EVIDENCE ON ASEAN-5 COUNTRIES 1

INDIA S TRADE WITH GULF COOPERATION COUNCIL (GCC) COUNTRIES: A PANEL GRAVITY MODEL ANALYSIS

Immigrants earning in Canada: Age at immigration and acculturation

Female Brain Drains and Women s Rights Gaps: Analysis of Bilateral Migration Flows 1

What drives trade in services? Lessons from the Nordics

Would a Russian WTO accession increase the country s export?

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

THE IMPACT OF MODE IV ON TRADE IN GOODS IN THE SADC REGION: THE CASE OF SOUTH AFRICA. Albert Makochekanwa. November 2009.

INSTITUTIONAL DETERMINANTS OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN MACEDONIA: EVIDENCE FROM PANEL DATA ABSTRACT

Labor supply and expenditures: econometric estimation from Chinese household data

An Analysis of Rural to Urban Labour Migration in India with Special Reference to Scheduled Castes and Schedules Tribes

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

Trading Goods or Human Capital

REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND TRADE IN AFRICA: AUGMENTED GRAVITY MODEL APPROACH

Internal and international remittances in India: Implications for Household Expenditure and Poverty

Immigration-Trade Nexus: the Case of the EU *1

International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework

The Impact of Conflict on Trade Evidence from Panel Data

An Assessment of the Europe Agreements Effects on Bilateral Trade, GDP, and Welfare

Tourism Growth in the Caribbean

The Differential Effect of Immigrants and Refugees on Trade with their Home Countries

REMITTANCES, POVERTY AND INEQUALITY

Do People Pay More Attention to Earthquakes in Western Countries?

The Impacts of Cultural Values on Bilateral International Tourism Flows

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

Labour Market Success of Immigrants to Australia: An analysis of an Index of Labour Market Success

Immigrant Employment and Earnings Growth in Canada and the U.S.: Evidence from Longitudinal data

Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts:

International Student Mobility and High-Skilled Migration: The Evidence

PROJECTION OF NET MIGRATION USING A GRAVITY MODEL 1. Laboratory of Populations 2

Migration and FDI Flows

Impact of Globalization on Income Inequality in Selected Asian Countries

The Evolutionary Effects of Democracy: In the long run, we are all trading?

Transferability of Skills, Income Growth and Labor Market Outcomes of Recent Immigrants in the United States. Karla Diaz Hadzisadikovic*

MODERN SERVICES EXPORT PERFORMANCES AMONG EMERGING AND DEVELOPED ASIAN ECONOMIES

ENHANCING TRADE THROUGH MIGRATION. A GRAVITY MODEL OF THE NETWORK EFFECT.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

Do State Borders Matter for U.S. Intranational Trade? The Role of History and Internal Migration

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

Poverty, Inequality and Trade Facilitation in Low and Middle Income Countries

Immigrant Children s School Performance and Immigration Costs: Evidence from Spain

Essays on International Trade. Oleksandr Lugovskyy

Tourist Arrivals in the APEC Region: Determinants and Inclusive Impacts By Emmanuel A. San Andres 1

Trade led Growth in Times of Crisis Asia Pacific Trade Economists Conference 2 3 November 2009, Bangkok. Session 11

Trade and the Spillovers of Transnational Terrorism

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

DO REGIONAL ASYMMETRIES MATTER FOR THE TRADE- MIGRATION LINK?

The Market Driven Trade Liberalization and East Asian Regional Integration. Lurong CHEN Graduate Institute of International Studies and UNU-CRIS

The Influence of Climate Variability on Internal Migration Flows in South Africa

Governance, Globalization, and Selection into Foreign Direct Investment

Political Skill and the Democratic Politics of Investment Protection

DETERMINANTS OF IMMIGRANTS EARNINGS IN THE ITALIAN LABOUR MARKET: THE ROLE OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND COUNTRY OF ORIGIN

Working Paper: The Effect of Electronic Voting Machines on Change in Support for Bush in the 2004 Florida Elections

ROMANIA-EU ACTUAL AND POTENTIAL TRADE

The Trade Creation Effect of Immigrants: Testing the Theory on the Remarkable Case of Spain

THE EFFECT OF REGIONAL TRADE AGREEMENTS ON THE GLOBAL ECONOMY AND SOCIETY

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict,

Third Country Effect of Migration: the Trade-Migration Nexus Revisited. Trade-Migration, Third-Country Effect, Quantile Regression, Imputation.

GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN

Transcription:

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand Murat Genç University of Otago, Dunedin, New Zealand Email address for correspondence: murat.genc@otago.ac.nz 30 April 2010 PRELIMINARY WORK IN PROGRESS NOT FOR QUOTATION

1. Introduction Tourism is an important sector in many countries as a source of foreign exchange earnings. In the case of New Zealand, for example, the contribution of international tourism in the year ended March 2009 is $9.3 billion (in New Zealand dollars), which amounts to 16.4 percent of New Zealand s total exports of goods. (Statistics New Zealand (2009).) Not surprisingly, agencies such as the UN World Tourism Organization (WTO) and the World Trade Organization have been treating tourism processes as an equivalent to actual goods exports. It is surprising that there is hardly any empirical study in the literature that applies the existing trade theories and econometric approaches to investigate the determinants of tourism flows. (Zhang and Jensen (2007) and Garín-Muňoz and Amaral (2000) are two exceptions. A most recent study is Keum (2010). Law, D., M. Genç, and J Bryant (2009) is another example, though their focus is not tourism flows.) This paper uses the most commonly used specification in empirical trade research, the gravity equation, to establish the determinants of tourism flows to New Zealand. It estimates a gravity model by using an unbalanced panel data set consisting of more than 190 countries that New Zealand has traded with between the years 1981 and 2006. The estimation technique employed is based on a panel Poisson model. The focus of this paper is the effect of migration on tourism flows. Following Gould (1994), it has been widely accepted that through their ability to speak languages, navigate legal systems, and draw on social and commercial networks in their origin countries, migrants can potentially reduce barriers to international trade. There are numerous studies in international trade literature that have examined the effects of migration on trade flows. Almost all of these studies have found a positive relationship between immigration and trade regardless of the different samples, specifications, and estimation methods used in them. This paper tests whether, all else equal, tourism flows from countries with larger stocks of migrants are larger. The gravity model used controls for standard determinants of trade that might be confounded with migration, such as the size of the economy or the distance to New Zealand. By applying panel data techniques, unobserved permanent characteristics of countries and global trends that might stimulate both migration and trade are also controlled for. 2. Modelling Approach and Methodology 2.1. The gravity model The basic idea behind the gravity model comes from the gravity theory in physics. Newton s law of universal gravitation states the gravitational attraction between two bodies is proportional to the product of their masses and inversely proportional to the square of the distance between them. In 1

trade models, the physical bodies are the exporting and importing countries, and their mass is their economic mass. In other words, the idea is that the bigger the sizes of the economies, the bigger the trade, and the greater the distance, the lower the trade. Thus, the basic gravity model can be written as EE i j mij = G, (1) D 2 ij where m ij is the level of trade (exports, imports, or total trade) between countries i and j, E i is the economic mass of country i, D ij is the distance between i and j, and G is the gravitational constant. This can be expressed in logarithmic form as ln m = ln G + ln( E E ) 2 ln D ij i j ij, (2) which can be viewed as ln m = β + β ln( E E ) + β ln D ij 0 1 i j 3 ij. (3) From an econometric point of view, this is a very simple specification where the parameter β 1 is the elasticity of trade with respect to the mass of the countries. In empirical trade models, the economic mass is typically proxied by the GDP (or some function of it) of the countries. It is also most common to extend the basic equation by including a number of factors that potentially facilitate or inhibit trade, such as cultural, geographical, and political characteristics. Such extended models are referred to as the augmented gravity models. 2.2. Issues in Estimation The standard approach to estimating the gravity model is to use the log-linear model in (3). Although this is very simple to implement, there are two potential econometric problems in doing the estimation. The first problem is due to the possibility of observing zero trade values. Because the proportion of observations with zero trade is often quite significant, the way these zeros are handled is important. There are various ways of overcoming this problem with various degrees of success such as discarding such observations, adding a constant factor to the volume of trade before taking its logarithm, and using a Tobit or Heckman type estimation method. The second problem is more fundamental, and is based on the fact that E(ln m) ln E(m) as implied by Jensen s inequality. As argued by Silva and 2

Tenreyro (2006), the standard practice of interpreting the coefficients in a log-linearized model estimated by OLS as elasticities can be highly misleading in the presence of heteroskedasticity. Accordingly, Silva and Tenreyro (2006) suggest estimating the gravity equation multiplicatively, without taking the logarithm of m, and allowing for heteroskedasticity. Their proposed method of estimation is a simple Poisson regression, equivalent to the Poisson pseudo-maximum likelihood estimator. As with the log-linearized model, this model also yields the elasticities if the independent variables are in logs. Furthermore, it also represents a natural way to deal with zero trade values and gives consistent estimators even when the variance function is misspecified. Both of these problems are avoided when the dependent variable, the volume of trade, is a count variable rather than a continuous variable. The data used in this paper are obtained as the number of visitors arriving to New Zealand. Therefore, the gravity model estimated in this paper is based on a panel Poisson model. 2.3. Econometric Specification Let t it denote the number of tourists arriving in New Zealand from country i in time t. Based on the multiplicative form of the gravity equation, the specification used in this paper is the following random effects Poisson model: Et ( α, x ) = exp( γ + x β) = α exp( x β) it i it i it i it (4) where γ = lnα. The vector x represents all the regressors: i i it x = (1,ln nzgdp,ln gdp,ln wgdp,ln mig, dmig,ln dist, dlan,ln rer ). (See Table 1 for the it t it t it it i i it definitions of the variables.) The conditional mean in (4) can be viewed either as one with effects that are additive before exponentiation or as one with multiplicative effects. Assuming that the random effects,, are gamma-distributed with a mean 1 and a variance of leads to an easy estimator to compute. 1 The resulting estimator is consistent under the assumption that the conditional mean is that given in (4) and that regressors are strongly exogenous. 1 See Cameron and Trivedi (1998) or (2005) for more details. 3

2.3.3. Data The data set is the same one used in Law, D., M. Genç, and J Bryant (2009). It contains data for a large panel of more than 190 countries on average for the years 1981 to 2006. Estimates of the foreign-born population in New Zealand come from Statistics New Zealand and are based on data from the 1981, 1986, 1991, 1996, 2001 and 2006 Censuses. To calculate exact values for the intercensal years it would be necessary to have data on deaths and international movements by place of birth, which are not available. Therefore, migrant numbers in inter-censal years have been interpolated. Data on short term visitor flows by country (the proxy for tourism exports) are also available from Statistics New Zealand and can be disaggregated by reason for visit. These data are annual. Data on language, and distance from New Zealand come from the Research Center in International Economics. 2 GDP data are obtained from either the IMF or the UN. 2.3.4. Variables Table 1 summarises the explanatory variables. Table 1 Explanatory variables used in the model Variable name Definition Log of the number of migrants in New Zealand from a given country Log of New Zealand s GDP (in 2006 $NZ) Log of foreign country s GDP (in 2006 $NZ) Log of world GDP (in 2006 $NZ) Log of the distance between the foreign country s capital and Wellington A dummy variable taking a value of one if English is not widely spoken in the foreign country. Log of the real exchange rate. Expressed so that an increase in this variable is associated with an appreciation of the New Zealand dollar. Dummy variable taking a value of one if there are no migrants from the country The dependant variable is the number of overseas short term visitors arriving in New Zealand from each country. 2 http://www.cepii.fr/anglaisgraph/bdd/distances.htm 4

3. Preliminary Results Results are presented in Table 2. It appears that migrants have a strong positive effect on tourism exports. Table 2 Tourism exports (holiday arrivals), 1981 to 2006 Variable Coefficient (s.e). 2341 (0.1282). 9409 (0.2852) 1.5153 (0.2557).6267 (0.3037) 5.4935 (1.2524) 1.6796 (0.7062). 5866 (0.2104) -.0403 (0.3647) Log Likelihood -919577.24 Observations 5025 Countries 205 Notes For definitions of the variables refer to Table 1. Cluster-robust standard errors are in parenthesis. Two stars (**) indicates that the coefficient is significantly different from zero at the 1% significance level, one star (*) indicates that it is significant at the 5% level, and a dagger ( ) indicates that it is significant at the 10% level. The estimated coefficients on Distance and the Non-English dummy are negative and statistically significant indicating that, all else equal, there will be fewer visitors from countries that are further away, and predominantly use a language other than English. The coefficient estimates on log variables are elasticities, so, the coefficient estimate on implies that a 1% increase in distance leads to a 5.5% decrease on the number of visitors. The coefficient estimate on implies that the number of visitors from a non-english speaking country are, on average, 81% lower. The coefficient estimates of the GDP variables are all statistically significant, and have the expected signs. Their coefficients are also interpreted as elasticities. 5

The variable is the main variable this study is concerned with. The coefficient estimate on is statistically significant at 7% significance level. Its magnitude implies that a 1% increase in immigrants from a country leads to a 0.23% increase in the number of visitors from that country, all else equal. 6

References Cameron, A. Colin and Pravin K. Trivedi (2005) Microeconometrcis: Methods and Applications. Cambridge, Cambridge Univeristy Press Cameron, A. Colin and Pravin K. Trivedi (1998) Regression Analysis of Count Data. Cambridge, Cambridge Univeristy Press Garín-Muňoz, Teresa and Teodosio P. Amaral (2000) An Econometric model for international tourism flows to Spain. Applied Economic Letters, 7: 525-529. Gould, David M. (1994) Immigrant links to the home country: empirical implications for US bilateral trade flows. Review of Economics and Statistics, 76(2): 302-316. Keum, Kiyong (2010) Tourism flows and trade theory: a panel data analysis with the gravity model. The Annals of Regional Science, 44(3); 541-557. Law, David, Murat Genç, and John Bryant (2009) Trade, diaspora and migration to New Zealand. NZIER working paper, 2009/04. Silva, J. M. C. Santos and Silvana Tenreyro (2006) The log of gravity. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(4): 641-658. Statistics New Zealand (2009). Tourism satellite account: 2009. Wellington: Statistics New Zealand Wagner, Don, Keith Head, and John Ries (2002) Immigration and the trade of provinces. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 49(5): 507-525. Zhang, Jie and Camilla Jensen (2007) Comparative Advantage: Explaining Tourism Flow. Annals of Tourism Research, 54(1): 223-243. 7