Classical Liberalism and International Economic Order: Studies in Theory and Intellectual History Razeen Sally London: Routledge, 1998, 186 pp.

Similar documents
4. Philip Cortney, The Economic Munich: The I.T.O. Charter, Inflation or Liberty, the 1929 Lesson (New York: Philosophical Library, 1949).

Book Review: The Street Porter and the Philosopher: Conversations on Analytical Egalitarianism

The Theory Of Money And Credit (Liberty Classics) By Ludwig von Mises READ ONLINE

Enlightenment of Hayek s Institutional Change Idea on Institutional Innovation

Course Title. Professor. Contact Information

THE FUTURE OF THE WTO

ECO 171S: Hayek and the Austrian Tradition Syllabus

SYLLABUS. Economics 555 History of Economic Thought. Office: Bryan Bldg. 458 Fall Procedural Matters

Using the Index of Economic Freedom

The financial crisis, accompanying recession, and. Qu a r t e r ly Jo u r n a l of. Jo h n P. Co c h r a n. Vol. 14 N o.

Morality and Foreign Policy

Prior to 1940, the Austrian School was known primarily for its contributions

James M. Buchanan The Limits of Market Efficiency

Why Do We Need Pluralism in Economics?

Economics 555 Potential Exam Questions

The present volume is an accomplished theoretical inquiry. Book Review. Journal of. Economics SUMMER Carmen Elena Dorobăț VOL. 20 N O.

SOCI 423: THEORIES OF SOCIAL DEVELOPMENT

Seminar on Mistery of Money Institute of Political Studies of the Catholic University of Portugal in Lisbon February 8 and 9, 2016 (tbc)

Classics of Political Economy POLS 1415 Spring 2013

California Subject Examinations for Teachers

John Rawls. Cambridge University Press John Rawls: An Introduction Percy B. Lehning Frontmatter More information

ECONOMICS AND COMPARATIVE POLITICS FORM IV

Nicholas Capaldi. Legendre-Soule Distinguished Chair in Business Ethics. Loyola University New Orleans. New Orleans, LA, USA

Trade theory and regional integration

A Tiger by the Tail. A 40-Years Running Commentary on Keynesianism by Hayek

Unit Three: Thinking Liberally - Diversity and Hegemony in IPE. Dr. Russell Williams

The Economics of Ignorance and Coordination

DEGREES IN HIGHER EDUCATION M.A.,

Lecture Overview. The Importance of Frédéric Bastiat ( ) A Lecture by Dr. David M. Hart and

As Joseph Stiglitz sees matters, the euro suffers from a fatal. Book Review. The Euro: How a Common Currency. Journal of FALL 2017

Book Review: American Constitutionalism: from Theory to Politics. by Stephen M. Griffin.

An Essay in Bobology 1. W.MAX CORDEN University of Melbourne, Melbourne, Australia

Original citation: (Caldwell, Bruce (2014) George Soros: Hayekian? Journal of Economic Methodology, 20 (4). pp

From classical political economy to behavioral economics Ivan Moscati

How Mythical Markets Mislead Analysis: An institutionalist critique of market universalism. Geoffrey M. Hodgson

Why Monetary Freedom Matters Ron Paul

NASH EQUILIBRIUM AS A MEAN FOR DETERMINATION OF RULES OF LAW (FOR SOVEREIGN ACTORS) Taron Simonyan 1

A review of Valeria Mosini s Reassessing the paradigm of economics: bringing positive economics back into the normative framework

Thomas Jefferson and Executive Power, and: Constitutionalism, Conflict, Consent: Jefferson on the Impeachment Power (review)

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Globalization and the Evolution of Trade - Pasquale M. Sgro

In the Aftermath of the Global Economic Crisis: Redesigning the WTO for the 21 st Century

As pointed out by Professor Kirzner (2001, pp. 137 and 140), Mises did

RULES OF ORIGIN CHAPTER 10 A. OVERVIEW OF RULES 1. BACKGROUND OF RULES. Chapter 10: Rules of Origin

Globalization & the Battle of Ideas. Economic Theory and Practice in the 20 th Century

American Government Chapter 6

Hayekian Statutory Interpretation: A Response to Professor Bhatia

The Rationale for Independent Monetary Policy

The struggle for healthcare at the state and national levels: Vermont as a catalyst for national change

Book review for Review of Austrian Economics, by Daniel B. Klein, George Mason

Revue Française des Affaires Sociales. The Euro crisis - what can Social Europe learn from this?

John Stuart Mill ( ) Branch: Political philosophy ; Approach: Utilitarianism Over his own body and mind, the individual is sovereign

POST COLD WAR U.S. POLICY TOWARD ASIA

CHAPTER 19 MARKET SYSTEMS AND NORMATIVE CLAIMS Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

Stiglitz then examines the standard model s welfare claims, reacquainting us in Chapter 3 with the now well-known Greenwald-Stiglitz

Choose one question from each section to answer in the time allotted.

Philosophy 221/Political Science 221 Philosophical Foundations of the American Revolution

Friedrich A. Hayek: A Centenary Appreciation

2. Scope and Importance of Economics. 2.0 Introduction: Teaching of Economics

Introduction: what s wrong with Keynesian economic theory?

Associate Professor Appleby writes:

Part 1. Understanding Human Rights

The University of Chicago Law Review

Settlement and Reconstruction

PROPOSAL. Program on the Practice of Democratic Citizenship

Name Date Hour. Mid-Term Exam Study Guide

Global Political Economy

A Correlation of. To the. Louisiana High School Civics Standards 2011

Communicating a Systematic Monetary Policy

Review of Roger E. Backhouse s The puzzle of modern economics: science or ideology? Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2010, 214 pp.

Chapter 9. Figure 9-1. Types of Rules of Origin

THE UNITED NATIONS AND THE EMERGING SYSTEM OF GOVERNANCE IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE

Correlation to the Texas Essential Knowledge and Skills (TEKS) United States Government

THE CONSTITUTIONALIZATION OF MONEY James M. Buchanan

S. Devrim Yilmaz. Kingston University Department of Economics 25 November 2014

Václav Klaus, Europe: the Shattering of Illusion. London, UK:: Bloomsbury Publishing Plc, pp. Hardcopy, ISBN

Human Action. Towards a Coordinationist Paradigm of Economics

Is Trade Liberalization s Star Fading or Simply Flickering?: European Union Trade Policy Adapting to an Uncertain Paradigm

Lecture 17. Sociology 621. The State and Accumulation: functionality & contradiction

Chapter 6:FEDERALISTS AND REPUBLICANS

The Dilemmas of Dissent and Political Response

L/UMIN Solidaritetens Pris Research Findings

Leadership and Economic Policy. Sandra J. Peart, Dean and Professor. Fall 2014

POLI 359 Public Policy Making

Economics and Reality. Harald Uhlig 2012

A Correlation of. To the Mississippi College- and Career- Readiness Standards Social Studies

GLOBALIZATION S CHALLENGES FOR THE DEVELOPED COUNTRIES

Examiners Report June GCE Government and Politics 6GP03 3D

Cambridge International Examinations Cambridge International Advanced Subsidiary and Advanced Level. Published

Economics is at its best when it does not worship technique for technique s sake, but instead uses

HIGH COMMISSIONER'S PROGRAMME 18 March 1996 REPORT ON INFORMAL TECHNICAL CONSULTATIONS ON OVERHEAD COSTS OF NGO PARTNERS

On the Irrelevance of Formal General Equilibrium Analysis

Robust Political Economy. Classical Liberalism and the Future of Public Policy

How Cantillon and Hume Propose the Same. Theory of First-Round Effects

New Directions for the Capability Approach: Deliberative Democracy and Republicanism

Introduction to Comparative Constitutionalism

Course Descriptions 1201 Politics: Contemporary Issues 1210 Political Ideas: Isms and Beliefs 1220 Political Analysis 1230 Law and Politics

Adam Smith and Government Intervention in the Economy Sima Siami-Namini Graduate Research Assistant and Ph.D. Student Texas Tech University

American Government: Teacher s Introduction and Guide for Classroom Integration

Monetary Theory and Central Banking By Allan H. Meltzer * Carnegie Mellon University and The American Enterprise Institute

Ideas about Australia The Hon. Dr. Geoff Gallop Lecture Australia in the World University of New South Wales 3 March 2015

Transcription:

148 Reviews Classical Liberalism and International Economic Order: Studies in Theory and Intellectual History Razeen Sally London: Routledge, 1998, 186 pp. Review by Jeffrey Tucker Publications Editor Ludwig von Mises Institute American political culture, since World War I, has cast the debate over international affairs and world trade into absurdly misleading categories. We are told that there are isolationists, who are protectionist in trade and reluctant to commit United States troops overseas, and there are internationalists, who favor the freedom of international trade and are ready to go to war and to fund international bureaucracies when it serves the (broadly defined) national interest to do so. Bound up with this truncated and confused debate are questions concerning international financial institutions such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank. Those who want to support these institutions from the United States federal budget are called internationalists, while those who do not are decried as isolationists (a term nearly always used derisively). The casual observer might conclude that the terms are somewhat useful as political categories, for it seems to be the case that the political forces favoring free trade (or some version of it) are also more likely to go to war and back the IMF, while those who agitate for industrial protection are also more skeptical of international military campaigns. In any case, this apparent division has grown more conspicuous since the end of the Cold War. It was the Clinton administration that negotiated and then argued for the passage of two major international trade treaties in the 1990s. President Clinton has been a strong supporter of IMF funding even as he pursued bombing campaigns in the Persian Gulf, Africa, and Serbia. At the same time, the political forces associated with Patrick Buchanan 1 have opposed military interventions since the end of the Cold War, but also pushed for higher and higher tariffs on imports. Whatever the practical reality, the division makes no theoretical sense, for a consistent position would either favor or oppose government intervention in trade, international economic management, and warfare. The consistent war

Markets & Morality 149 hawk might note, for example, that many international conflicts leading to war began as trade disputes rooted in protectionist policies. But even more important, the division between isolationists and internationalists leaves out a vibrant tradition of political economy, namely, that represented by the Catholic political tradition. Since the late-scholastic period, when Catholic theologians first came to see the social advantages of international trade, the Catholic political tradition has been internationalist in matters of economics and cultural exchange, while insisting on a stringent standard for evaluating the justice of wars, particularly those that do not involve vital national interests (the requirement that war be undertaken defensively, for example, would rule out most United States military activities since 1812). It is equally true that the Protestant political tradition, associated with the thought of Hugo Grotius, advocated international but unmanaged engagement in trade while seriously restricting the right of a state to go to war with another state. 2 But where is this alternative tradition represented in modern political economy? What Razeen Sally has done in his outstanding intellectual history, Classical Liberalism and International Economic Order, is to demonstrate that a vibrant tradition exists within modern political economy that embraces a libertarian concept of international policy, seen in strictures against war, an embrace of decentralized political institutions, and unsubsidized and unmanaged free trade as a moral and economic necessity. The result is an extremely valuable series of essays on the thought of David Hume, Adam Smith, Frank Knight, Jacob Viner, Wilhelm Röpke and the Ordoliberals, and Jan Tumlir. Sally draws on the thought of these individuals and schools (but not uncritically) in an attempt to break out of the narrowly restrictive categories that dominate most discussions of international affairs. He shows that it is not only possible but also deeply necessary to be internationalist on trade and isolationist in politics. The book chooses as its opening quotation an illuminating statement by Röpke: Internationalism, like charity, begins at home. To be sure, in one sense, Röpke s characterization applies to the entire classical liberal tradition, from the thinkers of the Scottish Enlightenment, to the French liberals, to the Austrian School, to the American Founders. However, Sally performs a useful task by restricting himself to the writings of modern thinkers who have made seminal contributions to understanding international trade and its relationship to politics. He has defined the crucial issues in a manner that appeals to academic economists, who are often too involved in the technical minutia of their discipline to put much serious thought into broad questions of international political economy.

150 Reviews At the heart of this classical liberal tradition is the assumption that international relations need not be organized by a central authority, or even by treaties among states, but that international relations achieve coordination and order through a spontaneous process of economic and cultural exchange. Sally sharply distinguishes this position from that of the neo-liberal institutionalists who, according to him, have a strong, and often seemingly unconditional, attachment to international organizations and elaborate mechanisms of intergovernmental negotiation and political coordination. They regard such mechanisms to be essential to the maintenance of a relatively open and stable international economic order. At the same time most of them are at least implicit defenders of interventionist governments, generous welfare states, and corporatist arrangements uniting governments and well-organized interest groups within nation-states all the hallmarks of a mixed economy, not a free-market economy. (7) Aside from being one of the few books available that sympathetically explores the classical liberal tradition, what is its unique contribution? Sally demonstrates that Frank Knight is much less a member of the Chicago School with its positivist methods and homoeconomicus assumptions than is generally thought. He argues that Knight was more conservative than he is generally assumed to have been, in the sense that Knight understood the evolving moral and cultural foundations of classical liberalism and favored economic methods based on realistic assumptions about human motivation. Sally also shows that the trade economist Jacob Viner, despite his periodic endorsements of international institutions, was skeptical that nations could formulate precise rules to govern trade, and criticized the credulity of people who put faith in the United Nations to enforce world peace. Nevertheless, Sally criticizes Viner for his unacceptable compromises with the prevailing Keyensian wisdom in the post-war intellectual climate. The most compelling section of the book, by far, concerns the work of Wilhelm Röpke, particularly with respect to his forgotten articles and books on international political economy. Röpke s three seminal works on international political economy are International Economic Disintegration (1942), Economic Order and International Law (1955), and International Order and Economic Integration (1959). I agree with Sally s judgment that these works have been unjustly neglected. Together they comprise a singular contribution in the history of classical liberalism, for Röpke argues against political unification on internationalist grounds, not on isolationist ones. He contends that the smaller the political unit, the closer government will be to the people, which means it

Markets & Morality 151 will be easier to keep it in check (thus, the less likely it will be to undertake large-scale experiments in macroeconomic planning). At the same time, smaller political units are more dependent on trade with their neighbors, thus enhancing the prospects for a secure peace. In the language of Catholic social teaching, he embraces solidarity through trade and subsidiarity through self-government. This was not just theory for Röpke, who could never resist the temptation to throw himself into contemporary political battles (for which we can be thankful). He opposed all post-war efforts to create a world government. In fact, he was even skeptical of European political union. As Sally notes, he adopted clear and controversial opinions in the thick of highly charged debates (133). Among his generation of classical liberal thinkers, he was nearly alone in his opposition to world economic management. Instead, he favored order from the bottom-up, which is based on small communities governing themselves in accord with their own cultural traditions. He vigorously opposed the World Bank and the IMF, correctly predicting that these institutions would only exacerbate the problems of international debt and world inflation. Remarkably, he even opposed the Marshall Plan on the ground that it represented forcible redistribution of property and would likely end in more centralized political systems (joining the journalist Henry Hazlitt, who astonished many by taking the same position). 3 At the outset, Sally predicts that he will be criticized for being too eager to use past thought as a searchlight on modern policy. However, it is not that Sally is too eager, but that he plainly gets matters wrong with regard to the World Trade Organization (WTO). The WTO is an institution that embodies the very ideal of the neo-liberal institutionalist structure that Sally s book stands against. It is designed to browbeat governments into ratcheting up regulations under the guise of harmonization and to support a bureaucracy conveying the impression that world trade depends on agreements among governments not on spontaneous cooperation among producers and consumers. Sally opines that Röpke would have maintained a favorable opinion of the WTO, which he mistakenly identifies with GATT (137, 195). Sally is correct to observe that Röpke was not seriously opposed to GATT but fails to present the political context. GATT was a fallback measure designed to support the international trading system in the wake of the political failure of the International Trade Organization (ITO), which the United States Senate shot down in 1948. The ITO, which classical liberals oppose, 4 was the actual predecessor of the WTO. The charters of these institutions include calls for a variety of planning measures; fiscal policy in the case of the ITO, and sustainable development in the case of the WTO. This is why Röpke argued so strenuously against the ITO (and Sally quotes him

152 Reviews to this effect on page 141). However, there is a difference between reluctantly supporting GATT as a second-best solution (authentic free trade being the firstchoice solution), and actively supporting it as essential to the international economic order. Neither GATT, the ITO, nor the WTO are necessary for a thriving international economy, and the classical liberal tradition Sally celebrates underscores that point. We can imagine, if Röpke were alive today, he would have strong words for both the anti-trade forces attacking the WTO, as well as the WTO itself, which presumes to be wise and powerful enough to manage the international economy. Nonetheless, Sally makes up for this minor problem by drawing attention to an interesting trade theorist who discerned both the merit of GATT s informal system of reciprocal negotiations, and the dangers of eliminating political competition through centralizing the state. His name is Jan Tumlir, a Czech economist, who immigrated to the United States in the 1940s. Tumlir never completed his magnum opus, due to his untimely death in 1985, but he did leave behind important essays on property rights, political decentralization, and international trade. He was a strong opponent of international government intervention and was among the first to see the danger of non-tariff barriers to trade. He saw protectionism and macroeconomic stabilization policies as the key culprit in bringing about the economic stagnation of the 1970s. He was an advocate of taking the political discretion out of international economic policy and amending the rules of international exchange to permit as much freedom for the movement of goods and services as possible. Tumlir emphasized that domestic constitutionalism was essential for restricting the tendency of politicians to rent-seek at the expense of world trading relations. The result of Sally s effort is an exciting intellectual history. His work begins the process of unraveling the present intellectual consensus of neo-liberal institutionalism, and its media counterpart of pigeonholing all foreign-policy perspectives as either internationalist or isolationist. He points the way toward a rethinking of the central issues of trade and foreign policy that place voluntary exchange, market relations, constitutional government, and human cultural contract among all people at the center of the debate. In Catholic terms, he has succeeded in showing that there is indeed a modern intellectual tradition that supports both subsidiarity (political decentralism) and solidarity (international cooperation through trade) without granting undue powers to the state either at the national or international levels. Classical Liberalism and International Economic Order will aid students and scholars seeking to bolster such a tradition within religious circles today.

Markets & Morality 153 Notes 1. Patrick J. Buchanan, A Republic, Not an Empire (Washington, D.C.: Regnery, 1999). 2. Vreeland Hamilton, Hugo Grotius: The Father of the Modern Science of International Law (New York: Rothman, 1986). 3. Sally might have taken more notice of Röpke s advocacy of the gold standard, which may have helped explain why he was opposed to flexible exchange rates. For under the gold standard, there is a single monetary standard to use in world trade, even though it differs in name and unit of measurement. 4. Philip Cortney, The Economic Munich: The I.T.O. Charter, Inflation or Liberty, the 1929 Lesson (New York: Philosophical Library, 1949). The Hayek-Keynes Debate Lessons for Current Business Cycle Research John P. Cochran and Fred R. Glahe Lewiston-Queenston-Lampeter: The Edwin Mellon Press, 1999, 221 pp. Review by Leonard W. Martin Professor of Economics, Emeritus Cleveland State University Professors John P. Cochran and Fred R. Glahe undertake the formidable task of comparing and contrasting Hayek s and Keynes s approach to tradecycle theory. In addition, they include a thorough discussion of the relative differences between the classical and the neoclassical approaches to the business cycle. There is a general introduction followed by a brief exposition of the Wicksell connection and of objections by Hayek and Keynes to classical monetary theory and quantity equation, chiefly over the methodology of separating monetary and value theory. The subsequent chapters provide a Hayekian interpretation of the methodology and foundations of trade-cycle theory; the role of capital theory in trade-cycle theory; the self-reversing nature of a monetary change; crisis, unemployment, and policy implications; use of equilibrium in trade-cycle theory; and lessons for contemporary theorists from the Hayek-Keynes debate. One advantage of this organization is that the authors were able to present Hayek s theory in detail. However, the principal disadvantage of this format is that a fair