Red flags of institutionalised grand corruption in EU-regulated Polish public procurement 2

Similar documents
Mihály Fazekas* - István János Tóth**

Three indicators of institutionalised grand corruption using administrative data

Using Big Data in public procurement to detect corruption&collusion risks. Mihály Fazekas

Uncovering high-level corruption: Crossnational objective corruption risk indicators using public procurement data

Using Big Data in public procurement to detect corruption&collusion risks

ANNEX A FULL DESCRIPTION OF THE MEASUREMENT MODEL. Our approach builds on prior work with similar datasets making use of a range of

Second-generation indicators of High-Level Corruption using Government Contracting Data: Examples from Eastern Europe

From corruption to state capture: A new analytical framework with empirical applications from Hungary

Red tape, bribery and government favouritism: evidence from Europe

From Corruption to State Capture: A New Analytical Framework with Empirical Applications from Hungary

Networks and grand corruption in Hungary. Exploratory analysis

Anatomy of grand corruption: A composite corruption risk index based on objective data

THE ECONOMIC EFFECT OF CORRUPTION IN ITALY: A REGIONAL PANEL ANALYSIS (M. LISCIANDRA & E. MILLEMACI) APPENDIX A: CORRUPTION CRIMES AND GROWTH RATES

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Anatomy of grand corruption: A composite corruption risk index based on objective data

The 2017 TRACE Matrix Bribery Risk Matrix

PUBLIC PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS ACT

Curriculum Vitae. Date of birth and birthplace: November , Budapest, Hungary. IE CERS HAS (Institute of Economics Hungarian Academy of Sciences)

The Anticorruption Frontline

Statistical Analysis of Corruption Perception Index across countries

Corruption as an obstacle to women s political representation: Evidence from local councils in 18 European countries

GENDER DIFFERENCES IN THE EQI DATA

Summary of the Results of the 2015 Integrity Survey of the State Audit Office of Hungary

The evolution of the EU anticorruption

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

Official name: Larnaca Sewerage and Drainage Board National ID: Postal address: P.O. Box Town: Larnaca Postal code: 6306

OFFICE OF ANTICORRUPTION AND INTEGRITY ANTICORRUPTION SEMINAR FOR CONSULTANTS, CONTRACTORS, AND SUPPLIERS

Public Procurement and Corruption in Serbia. BORISAV KNEZEVIC M.A. SENIOR ADVISER 8th December 2010, Serbian Chamber of Commerce

CAREERS, CONNECTIONS AND CORRUPTION RISKS IN EUROPE

CORRUPTION AND GOVERNMENT. Lessons for Portugal Susan Rose-Ackerman

INTERNATIONAL TRADE ALERT

The impact of corruption upon economic growth in the U.E. countries

Russian Federation. OECD average. Portugal. United States. Estonia. New Zealand. Slovak Republic. Latvia. Poland

DEFINING AND MEASURING CORRUPTION AND ITS IMPACT

PRESS RELEASE Prague, June 30th, 2004

The transition of corruption: From poverty to honesty

Short-term International Migration Trends in England and Wales from 2004 to 2009

Conference of the States Parties to the United Nations Convention against Corruption

Happiness and economic freedom: Are they related?

Governance and the City:

Guidelines for Performance Auditing

European Single Procurement Document ESPD (Scotland) Version 1.6

PARKING SYSTEM FOR PRAGUE AIRPORT

Law No. 02/L-44 ON THE PROCEDURE FOR THE AWARD OF CONCESSIONS

UNCITRAL Perspective on Curbing Corruption

Cartels, corruption and the importance of inter-agency cooperation in the fight against unfair practices in public procurement

8. Perceptions of Business Environment and Crime Trends

Corruption: Costs and Mitigation Strategies

CSI Brexit 3: National Identity and Support for Leave versus Remain

Do Bilateral Investment Treaties Encourage FDI in the GCC Countries?

Thinking Like a Social Scientist: Management. By Saul Estrin Professor of Management

ECB - T105 roofing for the new ECB premises (D-Frankfurt-on-Main) 2009/S Contract notice

Unit 4: Corruption through Data

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

Critiques on Mining and Local Corruption in Africa

Bachelorproject 2 The Complexity of Compliance: Why do member states fail to comply with EU directives?

A Vote Equation and the 2004 Election

STRATEGY FOR HUNGARY

The Correlates of Wealth Disparity Between the Global North & the Global South. Noelle Enguidanos

Supplemental Results Appendix

Crime and Corruption: An International Empirical Study

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

**This manuscript has been accepted for publication at Regional Studies

Forms of Civic Engagement and Corruption

Is inequality an unavoidable by-product of skill-biased technical change? No, not necessarily!

NATIONAL INTEGRITY SYSTEM ASSESSMENT ROMANIA. Atlantic Ocean. North Sea. Mediterranean Sea. Baltic Sea.

Social, Ethics and Sustainability Committee Charter 2018

PERFORMANCE CONTRACTS 2014/15 FINANCIAL YEAR 11 TH CYCLE GUIDELINES CORRUPTION ERADICATION INDICATOR REPORTING TEMPLATE

GOVERNANCE RETURNS TO EDUCATION: DO EXPECTED YEARS OF SCHOOLING PREDICT QUALITY OF GOVERNANCE?

REPUBLIC OF SERBIA Negotiating Group for the Chapter 5-Public Procurement. Bilateral Screening: Chapter 5 PRESENTATION OF THE REPUBLIC OF SERBIA

Working Papers in Economics

Making good law: research and law reform

Understanding the Governance Context Analytical Tools and their Utilization. December 10 Francesca Recanatini, WBI

Good Governance for the Quality of Life

Regional Anti-Corruption Action Plan for Armenia, Azerbaijan, Georgia, the Kyrgyz Republic, the Russian Federation, Tajikistan and Ukraine.

KNOW THY DATA AND HOW TO ANALYSE THEM! STATISTICAL AD- VICE AND RECOMMENDATIONS

on Interstate 19 in Southern Arizona

IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY

Impact of Human Rights Abuses on Economic Outlook

Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies

The Economic and Social Review, Vol. 42, No. 1, Spring, 2011, pp. 1 26

A French perspective on the quantification of antitrust harm. Frederic Jenny

Emigration and source countries; Brain drain and brain gain; Remittances.

Reforming the Judiciary: Learning from the Experience of Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe

Tsukuba Economics Working Papers No Did the Presence of Immigrants Affect the Vote Outcome in the Brexit Referendum? by Mizuho Asai.

Procurement Procedure for Supply of Interim Staff for IT and General Administration Ref. EBA/2012/018/OPS/IT/RT

S.I. 7 of 2014 PUBLIC PROCUREMENT ACT. (Act No. 33 of 2008) PUBLIC PROCUREMENT REGULATIONS, 2014 ARRANGEMENTS OF REGULATIONS PART 1 - PRELIMINARY

Supplementary information for the article:

The effect of foreign aid on corruption: A quantile regression approach

Handle with care: Is foreign aid less effective in fragile states?

Judicial Integrity Initiative Launch: Judicial Systems and Corruption 9 December 2015: London, UK

Experiments in Election Reform: Voter Perceptions of Campaigns Under Preferential and Plurality Voting

INTERNAL INSTRUCTIONS GOVERNING CONTRACTS WITH LANTIK S.A. THAT ARE NOT SUBJECT TO STANDARDISED REGULATIONS C O N T E N T S:

Public-Private Partnership No. 14 of

Firm Competitiveness and Detection of Bribery

Evaluation of the Good Governance for Medicines programme ( ) Brief summary of findings

ANNEX IV Procurement by grant Beneficiaries in the context of European Community external actions

Big Government, Small Government and Corruption: an European Perspective. Alina Mungiu-Pippidi Hertie School of Governance

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

Open call for tender for the choice of a "Coordinating expert"

Transcription:

Mihály Fazekas 1 Red flags of institutionalised grand corruption in EU-regulated Polish public procurement 2 26/2/2016 1 University of Cambridge, Government Transparency Institute, mfazekas@govtransparency.eu 2 This policy brief was written and published with the support of Open Society Foundations, the "Technological innovation for policy research for think tanks" program

The indicator development approach follows closely the composite indicator building methodology developed by the authors making use of a wide range of public procurement red flags (Charron, Dahlström, Fazekas, & Lapuente, 2015; Fazekas, Chvalkovská, Skuhrovec, Tóth, & King, 2014; Fazekas, Tóth, & King, 2016; Fazekas & Kocsis, 2015). The measurement approach exploits the fact that for institutionalised grand corruption to work, procurement contracts have to be awarded recurrently to companies belonging to the corrupt network. This can only be achieved if legally prescribed rules of competition and openness are circumvented. By implication, it is possible to identify the input side of the corruption process, that is techniques used for limiting competition (e.g. leaving too little time for bidders to submit their bids), and also the output side of corruption, that is signs of limited competition: single bid received. By measuring the degree of unfair restriction of competition in public procurement, a proxy indicator of corruption can be obtained. This indicator, which we call the corruption risk index (CRI), represents the probability of corrupt contract award and delivery in public procurement falling between 0 and 1. Based on qualitative interviews of corruption in the public procurement process in Hungary as well as a review of the literature (OECD, 2007; Pricewaterhouse Coopers, 2013; World Bank, 2009), we identified a broad list of potential components of the CRI, that is red flags indicating corruption risks in public procurement. Of this broader list, only those entered the final CRI which turned out to be significant and substantial predictors of single bidding in line with our proposed model of corrupt rent extraction (more on the regression models used below). We ended- up having 6 components 3 for the Polish national CRI (Table 1). Each of these is discussed briefly here, for more details see (Fazekas, Tóth, & King, 2013). 1. One of the most straightforward red flag of corruption is single bid submitted. Since we are only examining competitive markets, the apparent lack of competition allows for awarding above market price contracts and extracting corrupt rents. 2. A simple way to fix tenders is to avoid the publication of the call for tenders in the official public procurement journal as this would make it harder for competitors to prepare a bid. This is only considered in non-open procedures as in open procedures publication is mandatory. 3. While open competition is relatively hard to avoid in some tendering procedure types such as open tender, others such as invitation tenders are by default much less competitive; hence using less open and transparent procedure types can indicate the deliberate limitation of competition, hence corruption risks. 4. Different types of evaluation criteria are prone to fiddling to different degrees, subjective, hard-to-quantify criteria often accompany rigged assessment procedures as it creates room for discretion and limits accountability mechanisms. 5. If the submission period, i.e. the number of days between advertising a tender and the submission deadline, is too short for preparing an adequate bid, it can serve corrupt purposes; whereby the issuer informally tells the well-connected company about the opportunity well ahead. 6. If the time used for deciding on the submitted bids is excessively short or lengthened by legal challenge, it can also signal corruption risks. Snap decisions may reflect 3 An additional component can be potentially added to the CRI: share of the winner in the issuer's market (this requires more extensive. It requires further work which is in progress,

premediated assessment, while legal challenge and the corresponding long decision period suggests outright violation of laws. For continuous variables above such as the length of submission period, thresholds had to be identified in order to reflect the non-linear character of corruption. This is because most values of continuous variables can be considered as reflections of diverse market practices, while some domains of outlier values are more associated with corruption. Thresholds were identified using regression analysis, in particular analysing residual distributions (for more on this see (Fazekas et al., 2013). We restricted the sample to experienced issuers of tenders on competitive markets in order to minimize the chances that we are measuring honest errors or inexperience rather than corrupt practices. Thus we only examine tenders in markets with at least 10 contracts awarded throughout 2009-2014, where markets are defined by product type (CPV 4 level 3) and location (NUTS 5 level 1) within each country. Table 1. Summary of elementary corruption risk indicators ( red flags in bold) Proc. phase Indicator name Indicator values submission assessment outcome Call for tenders publication (non-open procedures) Procedure type Length of submission period Weight of non-price evaluation criteria Length of decision period Single bidder contract (valid/received) 0=call for tender published in official journal 1=NO call for tender published in official journal 0=open 1=non-open (restricted, negotiated, tender without competition, competitive dialogue) Number of days between the publication of call for tenders and the submission deadline Sum of weights for evaluation criteria which are NOT related to prices number of days between submission deadline and announcing contract award 0=more than 1 bid received 1=1 bid received In addition to the identification of thresholds in continuous variables, regression analysis was used to ensure red flags measure corruption, and to make the indicator comparable across different sectors and countries (where different corruption techniques might be used). In this analysis, we consider red flags as indicating corruption only if they predict single bidder contracts. We also control for a number of likely confounders in these regressions. These 4 CPV=Common Procurement Vocabulary. For more info see: http://simap.europa.eu/codes-andnomenclatures/codes-cpv/codes-cpv_en.htm 5 NUTS=Nomenclature of territorial units for statistics. For more info see: http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal/nuts_nomenclature/introduction

controls are: (1) institutional endowments measured by type of issuer (e.g. municipal, national), (2) product market and technological specificities measured by CPV division of products procured, (3) contract size (log contract value in EUR), and (4) regulatory changes as proxied by year of contract award. Regression results indicate that there is considerable market access restriction, hence likely institutionalised grand corruption, going on in Poland during the 2009-2014 period, by and large following the same techniques and tricks. These results on their own demonstrate that corruption is widespread in public procurement. Arriving at robust regression models with considerable explanatory power in Poland while using the same regression set-up and variables as in other EU countries point at the feasibility of cross-country comparisons too. The logic of our analysis is the following: if not publishing the call for tenders in the official journal for open procedures is associated with a higher probability of a single bidder contract award, it is likely that avoiding the transparent and easily accessible publication of a new tender is typically used for limiting competition. This would imply that call for tenders not published in the official journal becomes part of CRI. Taking another example, if we found that leaving only 5 or fewer days for bidders to submit their bids is associated with a higher probability of a single bidder contract compared to periods longer than 20 calendar days (a more or less arbitrary benchmark category), this would indicate that extremely short submission periods are often used for limiting competition. Then this would provide sufficient grounds to include the 5 or fewer days category of the decision period variable in CRI. Following this logic, in addition to the outcome variable in these regressions (single bidder) only those variables and variable categories are included in CRI which are in line with a rent extraction logic and proven to be significant and powerful predictors. Once the list of elementary corruption risk indicators is determined with the help of the above regressions, each of the variables and their categories receive a component weight. As we lack the detailed knowledge of which elementary corruption technique is a necessary or sufficient condition for corruption to occur, we assign equal weight to each variable and the sizes of regression coefficients are only used to determine the weights of categories within variables. For example, if there are four significant categories of a variable, then they would get weights 1, 0.75, 0.5, and 0.25 reflecting category ranking according to coefficient size. The component weights are normed so that the observed CRI falls between 0 and 1. The full definition of components and their weights can be found in Appendix A. The strength of this composite indicator approach is that while individual strategies of corruption may change as the environment changes, they are likely to be replaced by other techniques. Therefore, the composite indicator is a far more robust proxy of corruption over time than a single variable approach. In an international comparative perspective, a further strength of CRI is that it balances national specificities with international comparability. On the one hand, it provides a comparative indicator in as much as the logic of indicator building and the underlying indicators are the same in each country. On the other hand, component weights and variable category thresholds (e.g. the definition of accelerated procedure in terms of submission period length differs by country and year) reflect the different national contexts. The same overall scale of country level CRIs (0-1) allows for using the three indices as one scale both for joint analysis and comparative work.

Validity of corruption indicators While the validity of both corruption risk measures predominantly stem from their direct fit with the definition of high-level corruption, their association with widely used survey-based macrolevel corruption indicators as well as with mico-level objective indicators of corruption risks underpin their validity. Below, we report validity tests using the full European sample of TED data which support not only validity for Poland, but also for the whole continent. Both corruption risk indicators (2009-2013 averages per NUTS region) correlate as expected with the regional European Quality of Institutions index (EQI), population corruption perceptions and self-reported bribery of the same regional representative survey of 2013 (Charron, Dijkstra, & Lapuente, 2010) (Table 2). Table 2. Bivariate Pearson correlation between objective measures of regional corruption and survey-based indicators Variable % single bidder Regional CRI N % single bidder 0.69* 185 Regional CRI 0.69* 185 EQI (2013) -0.61* -0.54* 185 Corruption perception 0.55* 0.47* 185 Reported bribery 0.53* 0.59* 185 Source: TED and (Charron, Dahlström, Fazekas, & Lapuente, 2015) Note: * = significant at the 5% level On the level of countries, one simple indication that the corruption indices are valid is their association with widely acknowledged and used corruption indices such as the World Bank s Control of Corruption indicator. (Figure 1: top panel for CRI, bottom panel for the share of single bidder contracts). While validity tests are confirmatory in both cases, the association is much stronger for the single bidder indicator than for CRI.

Figure 1. Bivariate relationship between WGI-Control of Corruption (2012) and CRI and share of single bidder contracts (both are period averages for 2009-2013) Source: TED In addition to macro-level evidence of validity, two micro-level objective risk indicators are inspected for further exploring validity: procurement suppliers country of origin and contract prices. It is expected that higher corruption risk contracts are won by companies registered in tax havens as their secrecy allows for hiding illicit money flows (Shaxson & Christensen, 2014). In line with our expectations there is a marked and significant difference with regards to both indicators (Figure 2).

Figure 2. Average corruption risks of public procurement suppliers registered abroad, EU26, 2009-2013, Ncontract=14 909 0,35 0,32 0,30 0,29 0,26 0,29 0,25 0,20 0,15 0,10 0,05 0,00 % single bidder regional CRI tax haven NO tax haven Source: TED We also expect corruption to drive prices up. A simplistic, albeit widely used, indicator of price in the absence of reliable unit prices is the ratio of actual contract value to initially estimated contract value (Coviello & Mariniello, 2014). As expected both the single bidder indicator and CRI are associated with a higher price ratio. Single bidder contracts are associated with 7% higher contract value, while contracts with 1 CRI higher are associated with 9% higher contract value (Table 3). Table 3. Linear regression explaining relative contract value, EU26, 2009-2013 dependent variable relative contract value (contract price/estimated price) independent variables single bidder contract 0.071 CRI 0.090 sign. 0.000 0.000 each regression contains constant controls: sector of contracting entity, type of contracting entity, year of contract award, country of contract award, main product market of procured goods and services, and contract value N 164,711 164,711 R 2 0.088 0.086 Source: TED

References Charron, N., Dahlström, C., Fazekas, M., & Lapuente, V. (2015). Meritocratic recruitment and high-level corruption risks in Europe (No. in press). Gothenburg. Charron, N., Dijkstra, L., & Lapuente, V. (2010). Mapping Quality of Government in the European Union: A Study of National and Sub-National Variation (No. 2010:22). Gothenburg. Coviello, D., & Mariniello, M. (2014). Publicity requirements in public procurement: Evidence from a regression discontinuity design. Journal of Public Economics, 109, 76 100. Fazekas, M., Chvalkovská, J., Skuhrovec, J., Tóth, I. J., & King, L. P. (2014). Are EU funds a corruption risk? The impact of EU funds on grand corruption in Central and Eastern Europe. In A. Mungiu-Pippidi (Ed.), The Anticorruption Frontline. The ANTICORRP Project, vol. 2. (pp. 68 89). Berlin: Barbara Budrich Publishers. Fazekas, M., Tóth, I. J., & King, L. P. (2013). Anatomy of grand corruption: A composite corruption risk index based on objective data (No. CRC-WP/2013:02). CRC- WP/2013:02, Budapest: Corruption Research Centre. OECD. (2007). Integrity in Public Procurement. Good Practice from A to Z. Paris: OECD. Pricewaterhouse Coopers. (2013). Identifying and reducing corruption in public procurement in the EU. Brussels: PricewaterhouseCoopers and Ecorys. Shaxson, N., & Christensen, J. (2014). The Finance Curse. How Oversized Financial Centres Attack Democracy and Corrupt Economies. Chesham, UK: Tax Justice Network. World Bank. (2009). Fraud and Corruption. Awareness Handbook. Washington DC: World Bank.

Appendix A weights of CRI components Table A1. Component weights of CRI reflecting variable and category impact on corruption outcomes, normed to have an overall sum of 1 Variable component weight single received/valid bid 0.167 no call for tender 0.167 procedure type 1=accelerated negotiated 0.125 2=accelerated restricted 0.000 3=award without publication 0.167 4=competitive dialogue 0.000 5=negotiated with competition 0.042 6= negotiated without competition 0.083 ref. cat. 7=open 0.000 8=restricted 0.042 missing procedure type 0.000 weight of non-price evaluation criteria 1: 0 <= non-price criteria weight <= 5 0.055 2: 5 < non-price criteria weight <= 20 0.167 3: 20 < non-price criteria weight <= 40 0.110 4: 40 < non-price criteria weight <= 67 0.000 5: 67 < non-price criteria weight <= 100 0.000 missing non-price criteria weight 0.000 short submission period 3: length of submission period: 0-25 days 0.083 2: length of submission period: 26-42 days 0.000 1: length of submission period: 43-1000 days 0.167 4: missing data 0.000 5: there is or no call for tender 0.000 length of decision period 1: length of decision period: 0-18 days 0,167 2: length of decision period: 19-29 days 0.083 3: length of decision period: 30-63 days 0.042 4: length of decision period: 64-10000 days 0.000 5: missing length of decision period 0.125 6: there is or no call for tender 0.000