BEING IN GOVERNMENT: A POINT TO

Similar documents
PARTY TYPES AND ELECTORAL STABILITY IN CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPEAN STATES. Sergiu GHERGHINA & George JIGLAU

Impact of the EU Enlargement on the Agricultural Income. Components in the Member States

Personalized Parties at Power: Case Study of the Czech Republic

Nationalisation of Party Systems in the Baltic States and in Central Europe: A Comparative Perspective

91/93 93/ FBV PBV 19.7 WBV FWBV 0.93

Measuring Presidential Power in Post-Communist Countries: Rectification of Mistakes 1

CU Scholar. University of Colorado, Boulder. Daniel Kotsides University of Colorado Boulder. Spring 2013

POLITICAL PARTICIPATION OF WOMEN IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC

Europeanization in the making. Perceptions on the Economic Effects of European Integration in Romania

Cover Page. The handle holds various files of this Leiden University dissertation.

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents

NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Department of Politics. V COMPARATIVE POLITICS Spring Michael Laver Tel:

NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Department of Politics V COMPARATIVE POLITICS Spring Michael Laver. Tel:

Res Publica 29. Literature Review

Supplementary information for the article:

Hungary. Basic facts The development of the quality of democracy in Hungary. The overall quality of democracy

Forecasting the 2012 U.S. Presidential Election: Should we Have Known Obama Would Win All Along?

Political Groups of the European Parliament and Social Structure 1

Religious Voting and Class Voting in. 24 European Countries. A Comparative Study

CALTECH/MIT VOTING TECHNOLOGY PROJECT A

Electoral Systems and Evaluations of Democracy

Can Civic Education Make a Difference for Democracy? Hungary and Poland Compared

EUROBAROMETER 71 PUBLIC OPINION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION SPRING

NATIONAL INTEGRITY SYSTEM ASSESSMENT ROMANIA. Atlantic Ocean. North Sea. Mediterranean Sea. Baltic Sea.

European Union Expansion and the Euro: Croatia, Iceland and Turkey

Voting for Parties or for Candidates: Do Electoral Institutions Make a Difference?

The role of Social Cultural and Political Factors in explaining Perceived Responsiveness of Representatives in Local Government.

Economics of Voting in Post-communist Countries *

ATTACKS ON JUSTICE CZECH REPUBLIC

Political knowledge and the political attitudes of youth in EU and Slovakia

The Party of European Socialists: Stability without success

Introduction of the euro in the new Member States. Analytical Report

ECPR Workshop about European Aspects of Post-Communist Party Development (Mannheim, March 26-31, 1999)

The evolution of turnout in European elections from 1979 to 2009

Econometric Estimation of a Gravity Model for the External Trade of Romania

Appendix. Communism, Federalism and Ethnic Minorities: Explaining Party Competition Patterns in Eastern Europe World Politics. October 2014.

European International Virtual Congress of Researchers. EIVCR May 2015

BUSINESS CYCLE SYNCHRONIZATION AND ITS LINKS TO TRADE INTEGRATION IN NEW EU MEMBER STATES

Explaining Variance in Party System Stability in Lithuania and Latvia

Economic Growth, Foreign Investments and Economic Freedom: A Case of Transition Economy Kaja Lutsoja

The Changing Relationship between Fertility and Economic Development: Evidence from 256 Sub-National European Regions Between 1996 to 2010

Three aspects of political sophistication - which one can be blamed for generating bias?

Supporting Information for Inclusion and Public. Policy: Evidence from Sweden s Introduction of. Noncitizen Suffrage

Quantitative evidence of post-crisis structural macroeconomic changes

The Macro Polity Updated

Keywords: Voter Policy Emphasis; Electoral Manifesto, Party Position Shift, Comparative Manifesto Project

EXPLAINING THE EFFECTIVE NUMBER OF PARTIES PARADOX IN POST-COMMUNIST EUROPE: PRESIDENTS MATTER. Matthew C. Falvey

Class, Religion, and Generations: Cleavage Voting and the Mediating Role of Party Identification in the Czech Republic,

Flash Eurobarometer 364 ELECTORAL RIGHTS REPORT

Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries

EUROPEAN UNION CITIZENSHIP

No Elections for Big Parties

REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY

Party Polarization, Revisited: Explaining the Gender Gap in Political Party Preference

Data Protection in the European Union. Data controllers perceptions. Analytical Report

Introduction: Political Dynamics in Post-Communist Romania

Kim Lane Scheppele, Princeton University

"OH SAY, WHOM WOULD YOU VOTE FOR?" SOME REMARKS ON HUNGARIAN ELECTORAL SYSTEM

Of the 73 MEPs elected on 22 May in Great Britain and Northern Ireland 30 (41 percent) are women.

The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis

LEARNING THE ECONOMIC VOTE AT LOCAL ELECTIONS: CASE OF LITHUANIA,

Kybernetika. František Turnovec Fair majorities in proportional voting. Terms of use: Persistent URL:

Financial Crisis. How Firms in Eastern and Central Europe Fared through the Global Financial Crisis: Evidence from

Poznan July The vulnerability of the European Elite System under a prolonged crisis

Electoral Reforms in Romania Towards a Majoritarian Electoral System? 1

THE EVALUATION OF OUTPUT CONVERGENCE IN SEVERAL CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES

PUBLIC OPINION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

The Transition Generation s entrance to parenthood: Patterns across 27 post-socialist countries

Thinking Like a Social Scientist: Management. By Saul Estrin Professor of Management

Late modern religiosity in Slovakia: Trends and patterns

The Legitimacy of Democracy and Trust in the Political Institutions in the Czech Republic *

PROSPECTS FOR CONSTITUTIONALISM IN POST-COMMUNIST COUNTRIES

A Global Perspective on Socioeconomic Differences in Learning Outcomes

Analyzing the Legislative Productivity of Congress During the Obama Administration

The Components of Elections: District-Time Effects, District Heterogeneity, and Volatility

Who Speaks for the Poor? The Implications of Electoral Geography for the Political Representation of Low-Income Citizens

General Certificate of Education Advanced Level Examination January 2011

GCE. Government and Politics. Student Course Companion. Revised GCE. AS 1: The Government and Politics of Northern Ireland

Experiments in Election Reform: Voter Perceptions of Campaigns Under Preferential and Plurality Voting

Sciences Po Grenoble working paper n.15

Working Papers in Economics

The political economy of electricity market liberalization: a cross-country approach

Labour market of the new Central and Eastern European member states of the EU in the first decade of membership 125

OSCE Round Table, How do Politics and Economic Growth Benefit from More Involvement of Women?, Chisinau,

The effects of party membership decline

Tzu-chiao Su Chinese Culture University, Taiwan

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One

CDDRL WORKING PAPERS. Europeanization without Decommunization: A Case of Elite conversion. Number 64 June Alina Mungiu-Pippidi

The Effects of Political and Demographic Variables on Christian Coalition Scores

Chapter 7 Political Parties: Essential to Democracy

The Electoral Success of Communist-Successor Parties in the Czech Republic and Romania

Powersharing, Protection, and Peace. Scott Gates, Benjamin A. T. Graham, Yonatan Lupu Håvard Strand, Kaare W. Strøm. September 17, 2015

Practice Questions for Exam #2

Election of Kurdistan Parliament: Kurdish Competition with Consequences on Baghdad

Online Appendix to Mechanical and Psychological. Effects of Electoral Reform.

Volatile and tripolar: The new Italian party system

Party System Institutionalization: Bringing the System Back In. Steven B. Wolinetz Memorial University of Newfoundland

Ohio State University

A Trend in Expected Electoral Participation in Seven European Postcommunist

Media and Political Persuasion: Evidence from Russia

Transcription:

BEING IN GOVERNMENT: A POINT TO INSTABILITY? IONUT CIOBANU STUDENT, FACULTY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE, CHRISTIAN DIMITRIE CANTEMIR UNIVERSITY, BUCHAREST Ionutciobanu2000@yahoo.com A short draft- first version Paper prepared for ECPR Joint Sessions of Workshops Uppsala, April 13-18, 2004 1

Introduction In a seminal work, Lipset and Rokkan assumed a party system take many years to solidify and his road is slow with many stops. This statement is fitting very well for post-communist countries. Previous studies have established the importance of political parties in order to party system stabilization. The starting way of political parties from Eastern Europe, the organization type, the changes of these structures, represents so many opportunities for researchers who are interested about these countries. I m just a seeker, so I cannot stay away from this. As Jan Zielonka has wrote ( in connection with Russia) in Eastern Europe the institutional design is in flux and chaos and political parties are not excepted from this situation. Is this context provisional or a long-term process toward stability? This short paper starting with Kreuzer and Pettai ( 2003:80) assumption : stop treating parties instability as an residual category but an ordinary one. That means instability will be treat in this research like being the soul of party systems. I will stop now with these sophisms. This work is focus on the electoral change of parties,( governmental parties but also non governmental) in four Eastern countries: Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Hungary and Romania. One of the goals is to be clear, concise and brief ( sorry for redundancy). I chose the sample with no clear reasons but proximity, maybe some kind of familiarity and sure for short time. In such Eastern countries, the electorate is open ( Mair 1996:9), the psychological identification between parties and voters are weak, and more than that electorate is strongly oriented to a punishment vote for parties who lead the government. What s happen with parties who are punished by electorate and therefore lost the power? This question produced the hypothesis which I ll follow in research: The governmental parties become more fluctuant than parties who never was in power. That presume for government parties a higher electoral volatility and elasticity than for non-governmental parties which I expect to be more stable. So my goal is to find an empirical connection between government position of a party with the evolution in manner of electoral change after the party lost elections and therefore the power. 2

This research ignoring the type of parties, the position in left right spectrum, membership also the leadership, the general context and particularities of each party system. I could say this is a static research, a quantitative one concentrate only on the electoral volatility and elasticity of the parties. Is one of the many boundaries of this paper. Concepts Electoral change produced in time a substantial work by various scholars. Lipset and Rokkan are maybe the parents of this concept, linked by them to the industrial revolution cleavages. Rose and Urwin ( 1970), Bartolini and Mair ( 1990) are also scholars who stressed the same subject in various ways but close with the macro-level indicators in order of measuring system stability. Another group of researchers, Dalton and Wattenberg ( 2000) has been focused on micro-level of stability: partisan affiliation (Drummond 2002). The most used measure to capture the electoral change is electoral volatility, a concept well known in political research ( developed by Pedersen, Bartolini and Mair, Birch etc.), concerning changes over succesive elections in party support and therefore is dealing with voters behavior. In this study, the two indicators of parties electoral change are: - electoral volatility which is calculated as the sum of all electoral differences, for a party system or for a single party, divided by 2; - electoral elasticity, for a single party or for all parties, which is calculated as being the absolute difference between a party s best and worst electoral outcame for all elections; Elasticity and volatility give us information about party system change. But what is the difference between them? I cannot say better than Drummond: to use an analogy, if we consider a single party to be a swinging pendulum, the variety of that pendulum, both its speed and direction, could represent electoral volatility, while the distance between the highest points on either side of the pendulum represent the elasticity of the party support. Nice words. But what happens if a party s vote share not decrease in some consecutive elections? Example: First election Second election Third election 10% of votes 13% of votes 15% of votes In this case it s useless to calculate volatility because the party s votes share increase each time so the real solution is to avoid to calculate volatility( technical it s 3

impossible). Unfortunately in this study the electoral volatility will be the same with elasticity party support in some cases only for statistical reasons. The third and the last key concept is being in government. What is the meaning of being in government? I chose again the most simple definition in order to eliminate such parties who not hold executive position but give assistance to the cabinet ( Romanian ethnic party UDMR is a good example): - a party it s member of a government if this party hold at least one executive position in the cabinet. This statement produced two categories of parties: governmental parties and non-governmental parties. With these operational categories of parties I ll test my hypothesis. The variables and expected relations The period which I decided to be analysed is the last three elections for each country from my sample for the lower chamber ( in case of Romania and Czech Republic). The argument for such a choice is the different situations between countries. First elections in independent Czech Republic, the electoral system change in Bulgaria made me very careful with selection in order to have almost the same conditions in each country. The parties which I have chosen are those parties who won seats in Parliament in at least two consecutive elections. Just such parties are in position to gain executive powers. Because not all the countries are using the same electoral system, Hungary is using a mixed system, the others different kind of RP, I decided to consider relevant percentage of votes not seats. In Hungary case I used percentage for list votes. The source of electoral results is Project on Political Transformation and the Electoral Process in Post-Communist Europe, University of Essex. The independent variable is a dummy variable: - 1 for governmental parties: - 0 for governmental parties; The dependent variable is the net difference between two consecutive elections for parties who just have lost the executive power, and the total volatility or elasticity for non-governmental parties. The analyses method is simple regression. Will be calculated the total mean of electoral volatility for governmental and nongovernmental parties. The same calculation I ll apply for elasticity party support, to compare the results. I expect for governmental parties a higher electoral change. Also expect the follows relations in order to verify my hypothesis: TVNGP < TVGP; TENGP< TEGP; 4

Where: TVNGP is total electoral volatility for non-governmental parties; TVGP is total electoral volatility for governmental parties; TENGP is total elasticity for non-governmental parties; TRGP is total elasticity for governmental parties; Analyses To keep my initial promise, to be clear and brief I will list below all parties which I selected for analyses with variable code (for independent variable) and the net difference of votes after these parties ( or never gained the power) lost the power ( for dependent variable). Party s name country code difference PSD-Social Democratic Romania 1-6.2% Party CDR- Romanian Democratic Romania 1-18.2% Convention PD- Democratic Party Romania 1-5.9% UDMR-Magyar Democratic Union of Romania PUNR-Party of Romanian National Unity MSZP- Hungarian Socialist Party FIDESZ- Federation of Young Democrats SZDZS- Alliance of Free Democrats FKgP-Independent Small Holders Party SDS-Union of Democratic Forces BSP-Bulgarian Socialist Party CSSD- Czech Social Democratic Party Romania 1 + 0.2% Romania 1-3.4% Hungary 1-0.1% Hungary 1 +11.7% Hungary 1-12.8% Hungary 1-4.7% Bulgaria 1 +28.3 Bulgaria 1-21.43% Czech Republic 1-2.11% 5

ODS-Civic Democratic Party Czech Republic 1-2.12% KDU-CSL-Coalition of Christian Union and Czech People s Party ODA-Civic Democratic Alliance Czech Republic 1 1 +8.8% -5.23% These are all governmental parties and is easy to observe that the majority of them are negative influenced of being in government, ten parties lost votes after they lost the power. The most sensitive parties are in Bulgaria where SDS ( Union of Democratic Forces) and BSP ( Bulgarian Socialist Party) lost or won together 49.46% of votes share. The Bulgarian party system was in 2001 scene of a huge surprise when a complete new party won the elections. Two most freeze parties are in Czech Republic where CSSD (Czech Social Democratic Party) and his opponent ODS (Civic Democratic Party) lost just 4.23% of votes. For non-governmental parties, unfortunately just three, the situation is: Party s name Country Code Change PRM- Greater Romania 0 +15.6% Romania Party DSP-Movement Bulgaria 0 +2.1% For Freedom and Rights KSCM-Communist Party of Bohemia and Moravia Czech Republic 0 +8.2% The Hungarian party system simply surprising with no non-governmental party. Maybe the reason is electoral system who push the voters to give votes for already well established parties. Concerning governing formulas in Hungary are the most familiar in Eastern Europe ( Toole 2000). In percentage of all non-governmental parties is clear an increase of votes share for all parties. The higher level of increase belongs to PRM ( Greater Romania Party) a nationalist party which is the second party in Romania after last elections. The next step is to observe the indicators for electoral change, electoral volatility end elasticity party support. In their studies Rose and Urwin (1970) found a stable trend of electoral volatility in post-second World War years, with just 1% change in an electoral term. Bartolini and Mair ( 1990) found an average 8.5% for volatility in western democracies. After this period, I mean after the 70 s the general electoral volatility increase in all 6

regions, more in previous most stable countries, the Scandinavian countries. These not expected changes in Scandinavian area give us a warning for future positions concerning freezing party system. A party system is hotter then he looks. But these changes in volatility are not significant in comparison with Eastern Europe countries. The elasticity for party support is in the same period is 7.9%. As electoral volatility, elasticity increased with 1.3% in twenty-five years. I think this difference not relevant. So electoral volatility and elasticity both are in low levels in western democracies. Let s compare now these findings with our findings concerning electoral volatility and elasticity. Descriptive Statistics N Minimum Maximum Mean Std. Deviation TEVGP 15.50 34.08 11.0647 10.5550 Valid N (listwise) 15 Descriptive Statistics N Minimum Maximum Mean Std. Deviation TEVNGP 3 2.23 15.60 8.6767 6.6977 Valid N (listwise) 3 Like statistics show us the volatility is between 0.50% and 34.08% for governmental parties, who means a great fluctuation. The mean is 11.06 % which is not much higher than average from western countries ( 8.5%) but remember these parties are the most institutionalized in their countries so the average is not very relevant. More relevant is here the minimum and maximum, the difference between them. For non-governmental parties the scores are like we expected, smaller than for governmental parties with a mean close to western level 8.67%. Poor number of such parties don t make me optimist for statistical relevance. 7

Descriptive Statistics N Minimum Maximum Mean Std. Deviation TEGP 15.80 34.09 12.5020 11.0883 Valid N (listwise) 15 Descriptive Statistics N Minimum Maximum Mean Std. Deviation TENGP 3 2.11 15.60 8.6367 6.7556 Valid N (listwise) 3 We have the same situation for elasticity party support : a not very higher elasticity for governmental parties than western elasticity support. More than that, for nongovernmental parties the mean (8.63%) is lower than western index which is in the end of period 9.2%. In this point of research we have the next relations confirmed: TEVNGP- 8.67% < TEVGP- 11.06% TENGP -8.63% < TEGP - 12.50% That means the hypothesis is valid and the research is finished? For first level of analyses can be in this way. But for a strong evidence in defence of hypothesis we need a statistical confirmation so I ll try to capture this evidence using for the next step of research the simple regression. 8

Regression Model Summary Model R R Square Adjusted R Square Std. Error of the Estimate 1,348,121,066 11.5400 a Predictors: (Constant), BG ANOVA Model Sum of Squares df Mean Square F Sig. 1 Regressio n 294,089 1 294,089 2,208,157 Residual 2130,763 16 133,173 Total 2424,852 17 a Predictors: (Constant), BG b Dependent Variable: DIFF Coefficients Unstandar dized Coefficien ts Standardi zed Coefficien ts t Sig. Model B Std. Error Beta 1(Constant) 8,633 6,663 1,296,213 BG -10,846 7,299 -,348-1,486,157 a Dependent Variable: DIFF As we see, the value of standardized coefficient beta is -,348 which means there exist a relationship in expected way between variables. But if we check the value of adjusted R square we find,066 in other words just 6% from cases are explained by the variance of independent variable. Another evidence against the relevance of the statistical results is the number of residual : 16. Unfortunately the research failed to produce strong statistical evidence. The hypothesis is confirmed only on inferior level position in government has an impact against electoral change of a party in expected sense- because the expected relations are confirmed, but not as strong as we believed, and more important we failed in building a statistical evidence using this kind of variables. 9

Conclusion If the study of new party systems from Eastern Europe have something to teach us about stabilization maybe is the next idea : these party systems are simply more complex in different new ways to be capture with a static, quantitative model. These systems are in permanent move in different ways, from different reasons, faster or slowly but moving. An approach to party systems in Eastern Europe should be more comprehensive, because as Mair argue, here ( or there) almost everything is different : the general context with no civil society, patterns of competition, the electorate, therefore the methods and concepts have to be different. This research failed in order to produce a statistical evidence for hypothesis but I hope we can stressed a few findings in final: - electoral volatility and elasticity for party support are both higher than the same values for western countries; - governmental parties are more open to electoral change than nongovernmental parties; - ethnic parties are not affected by being or not being in government ( Magyar Democratic Union of Romania and Movement for Freedom and Rights in Bulgaria are two parties with low electoral change); - in coalition cases, the second large party pay the price of the cabinet ( Alliance of Free Democrats in Hungary, Party of Romanian National Unity and Civic Democratic Alliance in Czech Republic paid the bill for first coalition party s). In brief this research looks like a party system from an Eastern country: a half in shadows a half in light. 10

Notes on individual countries for ambiguous parties ( after Sarah Birch idea) Romania: The Democratic National Salvation Front ( FDSN) is considered to be continuous with Romanian Party of Social Democracy in 1996 an continuous with Social Democratic Party in 2000. The National Salvation Front ( FSN) continuous with Social Democratic Union in 1996 and with Democratic Party in 2000. Bulgaria: Bulgarian Socialist Party is considered to be continuous with For Bulgaria in 2001. Movement for Freedom and Rights (DSP) is continuous with Alliance for National Salvation in 1997. 11

References Bartolini, Stefano and Peter Mair (1990) Identity, Competition, and Electoral Availability: The Stabilization of European Electorates 1885-1985, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Birch, Sarah (2001) Electoral Systems and Party Stability in Post-Communist Europe paper prepared for presentation at the 97 th annual meeting of the American Science Association, 2001. Drummond, Andrew (2002) Electoral Volatility and Party Decline in Western Democracies:1970-1995 paper presented at the annual meetings of the Midwest Political Science Association, 2002. Kreuzer, Marcus and Vello Pettai (2003) Patterns of Political Instability: Affiliation and Voters in Post-Communist Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania in Studies in Comparative International Development 38:76-98. Lipset, Seymour and Stein Rokkan eds.(1967) Party Systems and Voter Alignments: Cross-National Perspective. NewYork : Free Press. Mair, Peter (1996) What is Different About Post-Communist Party Systems? in Studies in Public Policy, 259. Pedersen, Mogens (1979) The Dynamics of European Party Systems: Changing Patterns of Electoral Volatility European Journal of Political Research 7:1:1-26. Rose, Richard and Derek Urwin (1976) Persistance and Change in Western Party Systems since 1945 Political Studies 18:287-319. Tool e, James (2000) Government Formation and Party System Stabilization in East Central Europe Party Politics 4:441-461. Zielonka, Jan (1994) Institutional Uncertainty in Post-Communist Democracies Journal of Democracy 5:2:87-104. 12