Differential population dynamics, inequality and political violence in India

Similar documents
Education Inequality and Violent Conflict: Evidence and Policy Considerations

Population Pressure, Natural Resources and Conflict: Insights from Sub-National Studies of India and Indonesia

Perspective on Forced Migration in India: An Insight into Classed Vulnerability

Horizontal Inequalities:

Does horizontal education inequality lead to violent conflict?

Horizontal Educational Inequalities and Civil Conflict: The Nexus of Ethnicity, Inequality, and Violent Conflict

Group Inequality and Conflict: Some Insights for Peacebuilding

Extended Abstract. Richard Cincotta 1 The Stimson Center, Washington, DC

Case Study on Youth Issues: Philippines

Urban Youth Bulges and Social Disorder

Female Migration for Non-Marital Purposes: Understanding Social and Demographic Correlates of Barriers

A Clash of Generations? Youth Bulges and Political Violence

Religious Demography of Emerging Economies

Population at Risk in Asia- Pacific

International Institute for Population Sciences, Mumbai (INDIA)

Internal migration and current use of modern contraception methods among currently married women age group between (15-49) years in India

Online Supplement to Female Participation and Civil War Relapse

On Adverse Sex Ratios in Some Indian States: A Note

Rural to Urban Migration and Household Living Conditions in Bangladesh

Japan s average level of current well-being: Comparative strengths and weaknesses

Irregular Migration in Sub-Saharan Africa: Causes and Consequences of Young Adult Migration from Southern Ethiopia to South Africa.

The Demography of the Labor Force in Emerging Markets

RECENT CHANGING PATTERNS OF MIGRATION AND SPATIAL PATTERNS OF URBANIZATION IN WEST BENGAL: A DEMOGRAPHIC ANALYSIS

Violent Conflict and Inequality

Spain s average level of current well-being: Comparative strengths and weaknesses

HORIZONTAL INEQUALITIES AS A CAUSE OF CONFLICT A Review of CRISE Findings 1

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict,

Chile s average level of current well-being: Comparative strengths and weaknesses

How s Life in Belgium?

Migrant Child Workers: Main Characteristics

Inequality in Housing and Basic Amenities in India

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset.

How s Life in Sweden?

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003

THE EMPLOYABILITY AND WELFARE OF FEMALE LABOR MIGRANTS IN INDONESIAN CITIES

How s Life in Mexico?

How s Life in Canada?

How s Life in Austria?

Education Inequalities and Conflict Database

Sri Lanka. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

Demographic Change, Natural Resources and Violent Conflict: The Case of India

Dimensions of rural urban migration

Household Vulnerability and Population Mobility in Southwestern Ethiopia

Does Migration Improves Indian Women s Health and Knowledge of AIDS

How s Life in the United States?

Causes of War. Håvard Hegre and Håvard Mokleiv Nygård. Syllabus. January 10, 2012

Internal Migration and Education. Toward Consistent Data Collection Practices for Comparative Research

School of Politics & International Relations Working Paper Series: WP04/2018

How s Life in New Zealand?

Data base on child labour in India: an assessment with respect to nature of data, period and uses

CHAPTER 3 SOCIO-ECONOMIC CONDITIONS OF MINORITIES OF INDIA

How s Life in the United Kingdom?

CONTENTS INTRODUCTION ORIGIN AND REGIONAL SETTING DISTRIBUTION AND GROWTH OF POPULATION SOCIAL COMPOSITION OF POPULATION 46 53

The Cultural Origin of Saving Behaviour. Joan Costa Font, LSE Paola Giuliano, UCLA Berkay Ozcan*, LSE

How s Life in Ireland?

Korea s average level of current well-being: Comparative strengths and weaknesses

Internal Instability and Technology: Do Text Messages and Social Media Increase Levels of Internal Conflict?

PREDICTORS OF CONTRACEPTIVE USE AMONG MIGRANT AND NON- MIGRANT COUPLES IN NIGERIA

Migration and the Urban Informal Sector in Colombia. Carmen Elisa Flórez

How s Life in Australia?

DETERMINANTS OF INTERNAL MIGRATION IN PAKISTAN

How s Life in the Netherlands?

Determinants of Return Migration to Mexico Among Mexicans in the United States

Living in the Shadows or Government Dependents: Immigrants and Welfare in the United States

Movers and stayers. Household context and emigration from Western Sweden to America in the 1890s

How s Life in Turkey?

How s Life in Hungary?

The Role of Migration and Income Diversification in Protecting Households from Food Insecurity in Southwest Ethiopia

(606) Migration in Developing Countries Internal migration in Indonesia: Mobility behaviour in the 1993 Indonesian Family Life Survey

How s Life in Norway?

Emigrating Israeli Families Identification Using Official Israeli Databases

Heather Randell & Leah VanWey Department of Sociology and Population Studies and Training Center Brown University

How s Life in Greece?

The Determinants of Low-Intensity Intergroup Violence: The Case of Northern Ireland. Online Appendix

How (wo)men rebel: Exploring the effect of gender equality on nonviolent and armed conflict onset

How s Life in Germany?

Lecture 22: Causes of Urbanization

ADDITIONAL RESULTS FOR REBELS WITHOUT A TERRITORY. AN ANALYSIS OF NON- TERRITORIAL CONFLICTS IN THE WORLD,

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

How s Life in Portugal?

How s Life in France?

Caught in the Crossfire: Land Reform, Death Squad Violence, and Elections in El Salvador

Poverty profile and social protection strategy for the mountainous regions of Western Nepal

Structural pressures and political instability

How s Life in Switzerland?

Female vs Male Migrants in Batam City Manufacture: Better Equality or Still Gender Bias?

Italy s average level of current well-being: Comparative strengths and weaknesses

MAGNET Migration and Governance Network An initiative of the Swiss Development Cooperation

How s Life in the Czech Republic?

WORKFORCE ATTRACTION AS A DIMENSION OF REGIONAL COMPETITIVENESS

Supplemental Appendices

Rural Migration and Social Dislocation: Using GIS data on social interaction sites to measure differences in rural-rural migrations

How s Life in the Slovak Republic?

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1

Reproducing and reshaping ethnic residential segregation in Stockholm: the role of selective migration moves

How s Life in Iceland?

Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies

Estimates by Age and Sex, Canada, Provinces and Territories. Methodology

The Economic and Social Outcomes of Children of Migrants in New Zealand

Population & Migration

Transcription:

Differential population dynamics, inequality and political violence in India Erika Forsberg (Uppsala University), Ragnhild Nordås (PRIO & ) Gudrun Østby (PRIO), Vegard Skirbekk (IIASA), Marcin Stonawski (IIASA), Monica Duffy Toft (Harvard Kennedy School) & Henrik Urdal 1 (PRIO & Harvard Kennedy School) Paper prepared for the Annual Meeting of the Population Association of America (PAA) March 31-April 2, 2011, Washington, DC Session 181: Population, Conflict, and Religion Saturday, April 2, 12:30 PM - 2:20 PM Draft paper all results are preliminary Abstract Certain forms of demographic change have been claimed to render states more susceptible to political violence. This project addresses the interaction of two such processes, age structure transitions leading to large youth bulges, and differential population growth between religious and ethnic groups. While previous works have indicated that both youth bulges and differential growth rates affect low-intensity conflict risks, this study asks whether cycles of violence follow peaks in age structure transitions within religious and ethnic groups as suggested by Samuel P Huntington. An analysis of cross-regional, time-series violence data for Indian states (1989-2009) serves as the empirical illustration, testing whether differential demographic dynamics may contribute to explain trends in violence. It is further addressed how the impacts of demography on conflict may be conditioned by levels of vertical and horizontal (i.e. inter-group) inequalities, by migration, and by levels of education. The study uses Indian census and survey data, including newly developed inequality measures based on individual-level survey data, and age- and genderspecific educational attainment data for religious groups. It further employs new georeferenced conflict events data from the Uppsala Conflict Data Program (UCDP). 1 Correspondence: henriku@prio.no 1

1.0 Introduction This paper addresses two major political demography literatures, namely the significance for political conflict and violence of age structure transitions ( youth bulges ) and of differential growth between religious and ethnic groups. It further addresses internal and external migration as a specific form of differential growth, and also considers the impact of differential education trends and of systematic differences in living conditions ( horizontal inequalities ) between religious groups. These perspectives have previously been kept distinct theoretically and have been tested separately. Future iterations of this paper will better integrate these perspectives and ask whether the impact of age structure transitions and differential growth on violence is aggravated by systematic grievances such as low education, and systematic group inequalities in education levels and household assets. The current version includes some very preliminary analysis. 2.0 Theoretical perspectives 2.1 Differential population growth In states where numbers of people matter, conventional wisdom has it that the prospect of a majority being overtaken by a minority is fraught, at a minimum, with tension, and one which might eventually lead to conflict and violence (Levy and Krebs 2001, Toft 2002, and Strand and Urdal 2005). The logic could work in two ways. Either declining majorities fearful of being overtaken might launch a preventive war either by passing legislation designed to prevent a rising minority from acquiring influence commensurate with its increasing numbers or by outright assault or a rising minority might make redistributive demands, ranging from increased access to offices, contracts, wealth, or even outright independence. Consider contemporary Israel. Its post-1967 occupation of Gaza and the West Bank of the Jordan River put this young parliamentary democracy in nominal control of millions of Palestinian Arabs, whose birthrates in the past forty years have far outstripped those of Israelis as a whole. Only successive waves of Jewish immigration have kept Jews in the majority within Israel. But those waves of immigration have now ebbed, while birthrates among Israeli and Palestinian Arabs remain high. At anything like current comparative birthrates, the proportion of Jews in Israel will drop from 82 percent of the population today to 77 percent by 2020. Demographic shifts are thus a major issue encompassing both identity and security issues within Israeli politics. At root, then is the relative shifts in population proportions of identity groups within a multinational state such as India, and more specifically, the two largest groups. Could a shift in populations make conflict more likely? Is peace more or less likely when group populations are distributed asymmetrically or evenly? The basic hypothesis explored here is then that differential population growth among identity groups within a state leads to pressure to change the current political order, which leads to an increase in conflict, and possibly violence. Or, fundamental shifts in group balances among contenders produce conflict and violence. 2

H1: Shifts in the numerical strength of religious groups on the state level are associated with higher levels of violence H2: The effect on violence of shifts in the numerical strength of religious groups is greater the greater parity of the largets groups We further investigate migration as a specific form of demographic shifts. In a recent study, Fearon and Laitin (2011) estimate that as many as one-third of ethnic civil wars can be labeled sons-of-the-soil conflicts. The term sons of the soil were initially coined by Weiner (1978) to categorize conflicts between the original inhabitants of an area and more recent settlers. The label suggests that those who are native to a given territory see themselves as prioritized in terms of access to the resources of that territory. The typical case, as depicted by Fearon and Laitin, is a large country with an overpopulated lowland plains area, inhabited by the country s dominant ethnic group. These plains are surrounded by peripheral hill areas populated by ethnic minorities, sometimes tribal. To counteract the population pressure in the lowlands, people move (or are promoted to move as part of a government resettlement policy) to the hill areas. Although such migration has marginal impact on mitigating the population pressure in the plains, it may have significant effects for sparsely populated peripheral areas (Tirtosudarmo, 2001). Thus, when migrants come to an area, the original population may both perceive a significant risk that the demographic and/or political balance changes to its disadvantage and increasing competition over resources, e.g. cultivable land or attractive employment opportunities. Migration, especially if large-scale, may thus create anti-foreigner sentiments among the native population. Partly depending on the reaction (or inaction) of the state government, the situation can turn into violent insurgencies or communal conflicts (Fearon and Laitin, 2011). As noted by e.g. Goldstone (2001), migration per se is not necessarily linked to an increased risk of conflict. For example, within-country population movements such as processes of urbanization are commonplace violent conflict, however, is not. Migration of certain types, and migration under certain conditions, may on the other hand be connected to conflict. We expect that the type of migration discussed here i.e., when the migrants come to an area inhabited by indigenous groups who view the territory as their traditional homeland are more likely to see violent conflict, partly because such processes are likely to affect the local power balance, or the distribution between different ethnic or religious groups. Several of the ongoing insurgencies in India fit the description of a typical sons-ofthe-soil conflict. In particular some of the armed conflicts in the northeast corner are clearly driven by the indigenous people s fear of being outnumbered by settler communities. Based on the above discussion we thus expect that areas with larger number of immigrants are more likely to experience violent events. H3: Areas with larger number of immigrants are associated with an increased probability of violent conflict events. 3

The sons-of-the-soil dynamics outlined by Fearon and Laitin (2011) emanate primarily from within-country migration from lowlands to hill areas. However, violent conflict may also arise as a result of international migration. International migration, especially if largescale, also has the potential of creating significant demographic changes and lead to a perceived loss of power among the autochthonous population. That state government sponsor or encourage migration to tribal areas are not limited to domestic resettlement processes. The government may, for example, choose to bring in cheap labor from abroad to exploit the local resources. In addition, the native population may perceive that the government is encouraging people to migrate as a deliberate strategy of diluting the local population. This may lead to resentment towards the government, and has the potential of turning into violent armed conflict. The anti-foreigner agitation of some of the rebel groups in Northeast India has focused on the presence of illegal immigrants, which by definition come from other countries. For instance, both All Tripura Tribal Force (ATTF) and National Liberation Front of Tripura (NLFT) sprung from an anti-immigrant agenda. Although the anti-foreigner agitation is especially pronounced in Assam and Tripura, fear of mass-migration and agitation over foreign nationals and infiltrators have been seen in the other states of Northeast India as well, in particular in Meghalaya and Manipur (Abbi, 1984: 273, Singh, 1987: 25, 141). Recently in Meghalaya, the local Khasi communities have become increasingly hostile towards the region s Nepali migrant workers. Hence, we suggest that areas with large numbers of immigrants from abroad are linked to higher risks of conflict events. H4: Areas with larger number of foreign immigrants are associated with an increased probability of violent conflict events. 2.2 Horizontal inequality Civil wars, as well as other forms of political violence, often seem to have an ethnic or religious dimension in terms of well-defined identity groups fighting each other. However, there is mixed empirical evidence regarding the link between group identity and violent conflict (see, e.g., Fearon and Laitin, 2003; Reynal-Querol, 2002). The critical question, then, becomes: Why do certain multiethnic countries (or subnational areas for that sake) experience civil conflict, while others do not? To answer this question one needs to go beyond the sheer cultural differences between groups and explore what contextual factors may contribute to an increased risk of inter-group conflict. Woodward (1995) holds that so-called ethnic conflicts are in fact driven by underlying economic inequalities, which in turn politicize ethnic identities. This line of reasoning is captured by the concept of horizontal inequalities (HIs), or systematic inequalities between identity groups. (see e.g. Stewart, 2008). The focus on groups distinguishes the concept of horizontal inequalities from that of vertical inequalities, which pertains to inequalities between individuals. According to the horizontal inequality argument, members of disadvantaged groups are likely to feel frustration and antagonism, especially when their relative deprivation is the result of actual exploitation and discrimination. It is not only resentment by the disadvantaged groups that may cause political instability. The relatively privileged can also attack the 4

unprivileged, fearing that they may demand more resources and political power or because of the loss of a privileged position. In either case, a society characterized by high horizontal inequalities has a higher risk of political violence, which has been demonstrated in many qualitative case studies (see e.g. Stewart, 2008). The horizontal inequality argument has also received support in recent statistical studies (e.g. Cederman, Gleditsch & Weidmann, forthcoming; Deiwiks, Cederman & Gleditsch, 2010; Østby, 2008; Østby, Nordås & Rød, 2009; Østby et al., 2011). Most of these studies, however, tend to focus exclusively on civil war and ignore other forms of political violence. As pointed out by Fjelde & Østby (2010), however, the scope of the inequalityconflict argument does not clearly restrict itself to cases where the state is a participant in the violence. Mobilization and militarization around collective demands for redistribution or in defense of the status quo distribution should be expected to lead societal groups to fight against each other. In fact, we should expect lower organizational barrier for inter-group violence than for creating and sustaining an armed challenge against the state. Within the broader literature on causes and dynamics of conflict in the developing world, attention to non-state (or communal ) conflict has increasingly been focused on explaining the Hindu Muslim riots in particular areas of India (Brown & Langer, 2010). A range of explanations have been proposed from those that focus on the instrumental role of riot entrepreneurs (Brass, 1997) and electoral competition (Wilkinson, 2004) to those that focus on the robustness of civil society (Varshney, 2002). To the best of our knowledge, none of these accounts explicitly consider a possible role of horizontal inequalities. 2 On the other hand, there is growing evidence from in-debt case studies of communal conflicts in other countries which support the proposition that horizontal inequalities may provoke non-state conflict (see e.g. Mancini, 2008 on Indonesia; Ukiwo on Nigeria). It is not unlikely that similar dynamics could play out as regards inter-group conflict in India. Indeed, since certain forms of non-state violence is by definition inter-ethnic, or inter-religious (such as e.g. Hindu-Muslim), we assume that horizontal inequality may be particularly related to this form of violence (see e.g. Tadjoeddin and Murshed, 2007). The many conflicts in India have also been affected by one-sided violence against civilians, which has been carried out both by the government of India and by a wide range of rebel groups across the country. 3 However, the debate about horizontal inequalities has also been quite mute among those who study the determinants of state repression ore one-sided violence more broadly (Østby & de Soysa, 2008). Why should horizontal inequalities increase the level of such violence? The mechanisms underlying this relationship can be conceptualized in two ways: On the one hand, horizontal inequalities may increase the level of dissent from below due to heightened grievances by relatively deprived groups, which in turn can lead to repression. On the other hand, horizontal inequalities may increase the level of dissent from above. We assume that leaders will take more seriously potential threats from disadvantaged ethnic groups because the shared identity of such groups may overcome the collective action problems whereby people are unable to cooperate because of mutual suspicions (Olson, 1965), and hence be more likely to form a rebellion. 2 This is possibly due to the lack of systematic data on inter-religious inequalities in India. 3 See the UCDP database: http://www.ucdp.uu.se 5

H5: States with severe socio-economic inequalities between religious groups are more likely to experience political violence 2.3 Youth bulges Much of the developing world has experienced a recent mortality decline, while fertility many places has remained high. This has produced youthful populations in many countries, often referred to as youth bulges. The literature on youth bulges and political violence has focused in particular on spontaneous and low-intensity violence, but recent empirical results suggest that youth bulges may also increase the risk of more organized forms of political violence like internal armed conflict. Following September 11 2001, youth bulges have been argued to be an important driver of Islamic fundamentalism and international terrorism (Sciolino, 2001; Zakaria, 2001). Huntington argues that the resurgence of Islamism has been fueled by the young age structures of many predominantly Islamic countries, increasing the risk of instability and violence (1996: 116-118). More demographically dynamic ethnic groups experiencing higher growth rates and younger populations exert political, economic, and social pressures on less dynamic groups (ibid.:261). In Sri Lanka, cycles of political violence have apparently followed changes in the age structure of the perpetrator groups (ibid.:259). Youth bulges have been argued to provide both opportunities and the motives for political violence. Collier (2000: 94) has suggested that relatively large youth cohorts may be a factor that reduces recruitment costs through the abundant supply of rebel labor with low opportunity cost, increasing the risk of armed conflict. According to the opportunity perspective, rebellion is feasible only when the potential gain from joining is so high and the expected costs so low that rebel recruits will favor joining over alternative income-earning opportunities. Studies in economic demography also suggest that large cohorts are likely to experience a pressure on wages, so that the opportunity cost of a person belonging to a large cohort is on average lower than that of a person belonging to a smaller cohort (Easterlin, 1987; Machunovich, 2000). Much literature also focuses on how youth bulges may provide motives for political violence. Large youth cohorts are likely to be motivated for violence if they face unemployment, expansions in higher education with limited employment opportunities, lack of political openness, and crowding in urban centers (Moller, 1968; Choucri, 1974; Braungart, 1984; Huntington 1996; Goldstone, 1991; 2001; Cincotta et al., 2003). In India, the youth unemployment is particularly high, especially among educated youths (McNally et al., 2004: 162). While we do not have unemployment rates, we will use education as a proxy for youth opportunities. Further, we also address the issue of serious gender imbalances. Hudson & den Boer (2004) have suggested that great surpluses of young males represent a considerable security risk, and mention India as a particularly vulnerable country due to high male to female ratios in certain states. This study thus investigates two specific claims under the youth bulge heading, namely whether youth bulges are more likely to be associated with political violence in states where the sex ratios are particularly skewed towards men, and whether the conflict risk is particularly elevated when education is low (Goldstone, 1991, 2001). 6

Previously, Fearon & Laitin (2003) as well as Collier & Hoeffler (2004) have not found any support for the youth bulge hypothesis in cross-national studies of civil war. Esty et al. (1998) found a statistical relationship between youth bulges and ethnic conflict, while Urdal (2006) has found an effect of youth bulges on low-intensity internal armed conflict, as well as on terrorism and rioting. H6: The greater the proportion of young men relative to the total adult population, the greater the risk of political violence. H7: The greater the difference in age structure between religious groups the greater the risk of political violence H8: The lower the education among young men, the greater the risk of political violence. 3.0 Data, Operationalizations, Model The study builds on and uses the data structure of Urdal (2006). It covers all Indian states and union territories for the 1989-2009 period. However, only 22 states are covered in all the data sources used. 3.1 Dependent variables This paper employs new unique data on the location and timing of conflict events assembled by the Uppsala Conflict Data Program (UCDP). UCDP has recently transformed all of its dyad-year data into an events data format and assigned each event with attributes concerning its time and space, as part of the UCDP Geo-referenced Event Dataset (GED) (Sundberg et al., 2010). An event is defined as the use of armed force by an organized actor against another organized actor, or against civilians, resulting in at least 1 direct death[ ]at a specific location and a specific temporal duration (Sundberg, et al., 2010). 4 This definition is intended to capture the three types of organized violence of relevance to the UCDP: (1) statebased conflicts between the government of a state and another government (inter-state armed conflict), or against an organized opposition group (intra-state armed conflict); (2) one-sided violence carried out by an organized group (opposition group or government) directed at civilians and (3) non-state conflicts between two organized opposition groups. 5 In this paper, each event identified by the UCDP-GED in India 1989-2009 has been categorized according to its state location within India and its year. All types of violent events identified by the UCDP are of relevance to the present study (with the exception of events part of interstate conflicts) thus, a number of dependent variables have been constructed. First, a measure called Armed conflict fatalities sums the total number of fatalities resulting from armed conflict violence, that is between an organized opposition group and the government, 4 For specific coding criteria regarding each element of this definition, please consult the codebook (Sundberg, et al., 2010) 5 For full definitions of these three types of violence, see (Pettersson and Themnér, 2010 pp 23, 145, 203 ). 7

in a state a given year. 6 Second, Armed conflict events sums the total number of events assigned to a state-year. Third, the variable One-sided fatalities sums the number of fatalities in one-sided violence taking place in a state a given year. Fourth, One-sided events are the number of such events. Fifth, the number of deaths in so-called non-state conflict are categorized according to its state and year location in the variable Non-state fatalities. Last, the number of such events per state-year is provided by Non-state events. Note that for all types of violence, although some rebel groups have a clear link to a specific territory 7, their activity has often transcended into other areas. Therefore, also states without a coherent rebel presence may be the location of violent events. For this iteration of the paper we are using two operationalizations of the conflict data, both summarizing events in all three sub-categories of violence. First, we have created a dummy variable coded 1 if five or more people were killed in political violence in a state within one year, second we use a count measure of all events within a state-year. 3.2 Demographic measures, education Data on the age and gender structure as well as measures of educational status have been collected by Vegard Skirbekk and Marcin Stonawski at the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis at Vienna (REF). While data on the age structure and gender balance broken down on ethnic groups are not publicly available from the Indian census authorities, Skirbekk and Stonawski have used individual 2001 census files (check) and survey data to construct a dataset of five-year age groups for each of the three major religions (Hindus, Muslims, Christians) and a category of others covering 22 states. These data are further broken down by gender and education. The education variable distinguishes between three levels of analysis; no education (Illiterate; Literate without educational level; Below primary), medium education (Primary, Middle, Matric/Secondary), and higher education (Higher secondary/intermediate, Pre-University/Senior secondary, Non-technical diploma or certificate not equal to degree, Technical diploma or certificate not equal to degree, Graduate & above). Based on this rich dataset we have calculated the following variables: Youth bulges, total and by religion: population aged 15-24/adult population (aged 15+) Young male bulges, total and by religion: males aged 15-24/adult population (aged 15+) % young males aged 15-24 with no education as share of the total male population aged 15-24, total and by religion % % young males aged 15-24 with no education as share of the total population, total and by religion 3.3 Measuring Inequalities Variables measuring vertical and horizontal inequality are calculated using individual level data from the Demographic and Health Surveys (DHS) conducted in India during the years 6 Since we focus on intrastate armed conflict, events belonging to the interstate conflict India vs. Pakistan are excluded. 7 Specifically the rebel groups that have a stated incompatibility concerning territory, such as all groups in Northeast India. 8

1992, 1998, and 2005. 8 In a DHS, women between the ages 15 and 49 are interviewed about health, fertility, child survival, and other issues, such as ethnic or religious affiliation and ownership of various household assets. This provides a very rich data source from which one can construct indicators of horizontal as well as vertical inequalities (Østby, 2008). The Indian surveys include information on the respondents religious affiliation and whether they are classified as scheduled tribe or scheduled caste. Based on the DHS we measure state level horizontal inequalities as systematic differences in household asset ownership and educational length among religious groups. More precisely we measure the gap between the largest religious group and the other groups within each state. First, however, in order to test whether political violence is more likely in states with high inter-individual inequality, we calculate regional Gini coefficients for household assets and education years. The DHS survey lack information on household income or consumption expenditures. Instead we use the questionnaire to generate a household asset index, based on information on whether the household has electricity, a radio, a television, a refrigerator, a bicycle, a motorcycle, and/or a car. In India, where a large share of the population is part of the informal sector, household assets might actually better capture variation in welfare than conventional GDP pc measures (Filmer and Pritchett 2001). As an alternative welfare indicator we use data on completed education years. We apply the asymmetric inequality measures from Deiwiks, Cederman & Gleditsch (2010) to generate inter-religious HI measures based on household assets and education years respectively. Their point of departure is a measure for overall regional inequality: lineq2 = [log(g/g)]2 where g is the largest religious group s wealth and G is the average wealth for all other groups within the state. This measure is positive if the largest religious group s wealth deviates from the average for other groups in either direction, and 0 for states with no welfare differentials between the largest religious groups and the rest. In order to maximize the number of observations, the values from 1992 are applied to to the period 1989 1994; values from 1998 are applied to 1995 2001, and values from 2005 are applied to the period 2002 2009. 3.4 Data on migration Data on migration in India is collected as part of each census. These censuses are held every decade, the last ones being in 1991 and 2001 and with the 2011 census recently finalized (and data currently being processed). These reports provide data on, for instance, intrastate, interstate and international migration in India. From the data, we have constructed measures of migration where we use the 1991 census data to cover the years 1989 to 1996 and the 2001 data is used for all years 1997-2009 (Census of India, 2001, Census of India, 1991). 8 8 See the DHS webpage: http://www.measuredhs.com/ 9

First, the measure Born abroad sums the number of people in a given state that reported some country other than India as their place of birth in the census data. 9 We use this estimate to calculate Proportion born abroad, which is the proportion of the state s population that according to the census data are born abroad. As stated in the theoretical section, not only international migration is of relevance. Hence, we also estimate migration within India. Born other state counts the number of people in a state that had a place of birth outside of the state they currently reside in, but within India. This is used to construct Proportion born other state, which is the share of the state s population reportedly born in another state of India. 3.5 Control variables Total population, share of population that is rural, and literacy are collected from various Indian census sources. 3.6 Method: we are using a logit model for the binary variable measuring whether there were at least five casualties in a given state-year and a negative binomial regression model for the count data. 10 4.0 Results 4.1 Descriptive Analysis of Violent Events in India 1989-2009 As mentioned previously, the UCDP Geo-referenced Event Dataset (GED) provides information on conflict events for three types of conflict (state-based armed conflict, onesided violence, and non-state conflict). Starting with the first type of conflict, UCDP-GED has coded about 7000 separate events in India 1989-2009 (excluding the interstate conflict with Pakistan), resulting in over 31000 battle-related deaths. These violent events involve 20 different dyads, in eleven different armed conflicts (one over government and ten over territories). These events are geographically dispersed; indeed, fatal events have taken place in 25 out of the 35 states and Union Territories. 11 Table 1 shows the number of fatalities in these events over time. 9 It should be noted that self-reported census data on the place of birth is likely to be underestimated when it comes to international migrants. Especially migrants who have entered India illegally are unlikely to report their true place of birth fearing deportation. However, this is likely to be systematic across regions and we should hence be able to assess the relative impact of migration. 10 We also did initial runs with a zero-inflated negative binomial model, but admittedly we do not have a good theoretical model for the inflation model. The results from these models are quite volatile and thus inconclusive. 11 See Appendix 1 for maps of the geographical distributions of the three event measures. 10

Table 1: Annual number of fatalities state-based intrastate conflict, India 1989-2009 3500 3000 2500 2000 1500 1000 500 0 The second category, one-sided violence against civilians carried out by governments or organized opposition groups, amounts to approximately 2700 separate events resulting in over 9000 fatalities in India 1989-2009. In total, twenty-one opposition groups and the government of India has reached the level of inclusion in at least one year. This type of event is almost as geographically spread as regular state-based conflict, and has been identified in 23 Indian states in the time period. Table 2 illustrates that the annual number of fatalities in direct violence against civilians in India is relatively constant, with fatalities typically in the hundreds. Table 2: Annual number of fatalities one-sided violence, India 1989-2009 900 800 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 0 The third category of events is non-state conflict, i.e. when two groups fight each other. This category both includes dyads consisting of two groups that are highly organized, such as NSCN-IM vs. NSCN-K in Nagaland but also groups bound together by a shared ethnic 11

identity, such as the dyad Naga vs. Kuki. The UCDP identifies eight non-state conflicts in India, with clashes that have resulted in about 4700 deaths in approximately 400 separate events. This type of violence has been less geographically spread then state-based conflict and one-sided violence. Nevertheless, about half of all Indian state have experienced such events in the time period studied. The table below illustrates a clear temporal trend regarding non-state violence in India. After a flare-up in 1990, the annual number of fatalities from non-state violence have decreased significantly. The over 1700 fatalities identified in 1990 was attributed to mainly Hindu-Muslim violence throughout a large number of Indian states, e.g. Gujarat, Bihar, West Bengal, and Uttar Pradesh. Table 3: Annual number of fatalities non-state conflict, India 1989-2009 2000 1800 1600 1400 1200 1000 800 600 400 200 0 4.2 Multivariate Analysis Models 1 and 2 illustrate some early tests of the data and main hypotheses. Here, we only show the results for all the conflict data across the sub-categories, as there are initially no clear patterns emerging from the different forms of violence. Model 1, using the binary conflict measure, suggests that conflict as expected is statistically associated with greater differences in age structure between the two largest religious groups, with greater differential growth the greater the parity of the groups, and with an increasing presence of foreign born in the population. More unexpectedly, lower levels of education in the 15-24 year group are associated with less conflict, as are greater horizontal inequalities. Among the control variables, lower literacy and greater rural populations are also associated with increased conflict risks. Model 2, analyzing a count measure of all violent events, supports many of the findings from the logit model. The only statistically significant findings that differ from the first model are the share of the population that is rural, and the proportion of foreign-born, which both turn statistically insignificant in Model 2. 12

Model 1 Logit Model Using Fatality Dummy (5+ killed /year) Logistic regression Number of obs = 362 LR chi2(13) = 165.50 Prob > chi2 = 0.0000 Log likelihood = -158.80079 Pseudo R2 = 0.3426 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ allfatal_d~y Coef. Std. Err. z P> z [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------- totpopln -.2202714.3555774-0.62 0.536 -.9171904.4766475 literacy -.0124456.0021181-5.88 0.000 -.016597 -.0082942 ruralsh -.0724582.0356973-2.03 0.042 -.1424237 -.0024927 Ymap_all -36.68335 22.29552-1.65 0.100-80.38176 7.01506 Ymap_diff 27.95686 11.37258 2.46 0.014 5.667007 50.24671 reldisad -.1511248.0414546-3.65 0.000 -.2323743 -.0698753 parity -4.015214 2.509016-1.60 0.110-8.932794.902366 disad_par.6469336.1615807 4.00 0.000.3302413.9636259 A_ym~_ed_tot -.1210843.0339294-3.57 0.000 -.1875846 -.054584 HIr_as -13.53405 4.297079-3.15 0.002-21.95617-5.111927 propbornos -9.642786 9.921016-0.97 0.331-29.08762 9.802048 propbornab~d 52.27743 19.45821 2.69 0.007 14.14005 90.41482 lag_all_fa~y 1.182243.2892776 4.09 0.000.6152692 1.749217 _cons 22.23984 6.914089 3.22 0.001 8.688476 35.79121 Model 2 Negative Binomial Model Using Count of Events Random-effects negative binomial regression Number of obs = 362 Group variable: myid Number of groups = 19 Random effects u_i ~ Beta Obs per group: min = 9 avg = 19.1 max = 20 Wald chi2(13) = 121.35 Log likelihood = -728.63675 Prob > chi2 = 0.0000 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ conflictev~l Coef. Std. Err. z P> z [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------- totpopln.0785545.2386097 0.33 0.742 -.3891118.5462208 literacy -.0072298.0010881-6.64 0.000 -.0093624 -.0050972 ruralsh -.0286869.0220647-1.30 0.194 -.071933.0145592 Ymap_all 9.123966 17.3201 0.53 0.598-24.82281 43.07075 Ymap_diff 31.00545 10.3372 3.00 0.003 10.74491 51.26598 reldisad -.0693221.0218635-3.17 0.002 -.1121737 -.0264704 parity -4.937931 1.796654-2.75 0.006-8.459308-1.416553 disad_par.4144145.0853418 4.86 0.000.2471477.5816813 A_ym~_ed_tot -.0596068.0239141-2.49 0.013 -.1064777 -.0127359 HIr_as -7.589545 3.000233-2.53 0.011-13.46989-1.709196 propbornos -4.833339 6.011472-0.80 0.421-16.61561 6.948929 propbornab~d 15.904 13.31956 1.19 0.232-10.20185 42.00985 lagallevents.0005167.0007722 0.67 0.503 -.0009968.0020302 _cons 4.557762 4.096627 1.11 0.266-3.471479 12.587 -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------- /ln_r -.2152526.3162223 -.8350368.4045316 /ln_s 1.016543.4501903.1341861 1.8989 -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------- r.8063377.2549819.4338585 1.4986 s 2.763624 1.244157 1.143606 6.678541 13

5.0 References Abbi, B.L. (1984) Northeast Region: Problems and Prospects of Development. Chandigarh: Centre for Research in Rural and Industrial Development (CRRID). Brass, Paul R. (1997) Theft of an Idol: Text and Context in the Representation of Collective Violence. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Brown, Graham K. & Arnim Langer. (2010) Horizontal Inequalities and Conflict: A Critical Review and Research Agenda. Conflict, Security & Development 10(1): 27 55. Cederman, Lars-Erik; Kristian S. Gleditsch & Nils B. Weidmann. (2011) Horizontal Inequalities and Ethno-Nationalist Civil War: A Global Comparison. American Political Science Review, forthcoming. Census of India. (2001) Census Data Online. Office of the Registrar General & Census Commissioner. Retrieved from http://censusindia.gov.in/ (cited 15 August, 2010). Census of India. (1991) Census of India, 1991, Full Set of Tables. Office of the Registrar General & Census Commissioner. Cincotta, Richard P., Robert Engelman, and Daniele Anastasion. 2003. The Security Demographic: Population and Civil Conflict After the Cold War. Washington, DC: Population Action International. Deiwiks, Christa; Lars-Erik Cederman & Kristian S. Gleditsch. (2010) Inequality and Conflict in Federations. Paper presented to the GROW workshop, PRIO, Oslo, 18 June. Fearon, James D. & David D. Laitin. (2003) Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War. American Political Science Review 97(1): 75 90. Fearon, James D., and David D. Laitin. (2011) Sons of the Soil, Migrants, and Civil War. World Development 39:199-211. Filmer, Deon & Lant Pritchett. (2001) Estimating Wealth Effects without Expenditure Data Or Tears: An Application to Educational Enrollments in States of India, Demography 38(1): 115 132. Fjelde, Hanne & Gudrun Østby. (2010) Economic Inequality and Non-State Conflicts in Africa. Paper presented to the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, DC, 2 5 September. Goldstone, Jack A. (2001) Demography, Environment, and Security: An Overview. In Demography and National Security, edited by Myron Weiner and Sharon Stanton Russel, pp. 38-61. New York, NY: Berghahn Books. Goldstone, Jack A. 1991. Revolution and Rebellion in the Early Modern World. Berkely, CA: University of California Press. Mancini, Luca. (2008) Horizontal Inequality and Communal Violence: Evidence from Indonesian Districts. In Horizontal Inequalities and Conflict: Understanding Group Violence in Multiethnic Societies, edited by Frances Stewart, pp. 106 130. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Moller, Herbert. 1968. Youth as a Force in the Modern World. Comparative Studies in Society and History 10:238-60. Olson, Mancur. (1965) The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Østby, Gudrun. (2008) Polarization, Horizontal inequalities and Violent Civil Conflict. Journal of Peace Research 45(2): 143 162. Østby, Gudrun & Indra de Soysa. (2008) Too Weak to Fight? Horizontal Inequality and State Repression, 1980 2004. Paper presented to the 49th Annual Convention of the International Studies Association, San Francisco, CA, 26 29 March. 14

Østby, Gudrun; Ragnhild Nordås & Jan Ketil Rød. (2009) Regional Inequalities and Civil Conflict in Sub-Saharan Africa, 1986 2004. International Studies Quarterly 53(2): 301 324. Østby, Gudrun; Henrik Urdal, Zulfan Tadjoeddin, S. Mansoob Murshed & Håvard Strand. (2011) Population Pressure, Horizontal Inequality and Political Violence: A Disaggregated Study of Indonesian Provinces, 1990 2003. Journal of Development Studies 47(3), in press. Pettersson, Therése, and Lotta Themnér. (2010) States in Armed Conflict 2009. Department of Peace and Conflict Research, Uppsala University. Reynal-Querol, Marta. (2002) Ethnicity, Political Systems, and Civil Wars. Journal of Conflict Resolution 46(1): 29 54. Singh, B.P. (1987) The Problem of Change: A Study of North-East India. Delhi: Oxford University Press. Stewart, Frances, ed. (2008) Horizontal Inequalities and Conflict: Understanding Group Violence in Multiethnic Societies. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Sundberg, Ralph, Mathilda Lindgren, and Ausra Padskocimaite. (2010) Ucdp Georeferenced Event Dataset (Ged) Codebook, Version 1.0. Uppsala Conflict Data Program (UCDP) www.ucdp.uu.se. Tadjoeddin, Zulfan & S. Mansoob Murshed. (2007) Socioeconomic Determinants of Everyday Violence in Indonesia: an Empirical Investigation of Javanese Districts. 1994 2003. Journal of Peace Research 44(6): 689 709. Tirtosudarmo, Riwanto. (2001) Demography and Security: Transmigration Policy in Indonesia. In Demography and National Security, edited by Myron Weiner and Sharon Stanton Russel, pp. 199-227. New York: Berghahn Books. Toft, Monica D. 2002. Differential Demographic Growth in Multinational States: Israel's Two-Front War. Journal of International Affairs 56(1): 71 94. Toft, Monica Duffy. 2003. The Geography of Ethnic Violence: Identity, Interests, and the Indivisibility of Territory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Toft, Monica Duffy. 2007. Population Shifts and Civil War. International Interactions, 33:243-69. Ukiwo, Ukoha. (2008) Horizontal Inequalities and Ethnic Violence: Evidence from Calabar and Warri, Nigeria. In Horizontal Inequalities and Conflict: Understanding Group Violence in Multiethnic Societies, edited by Frances Stewart, pp. 190 204. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Urdal, Henrik. 2006. A Clash of Generations? Youth Bulges and Political Violence. International Studies Quarterly 50:607-29. Urdal, H. (2008) Population, resources and political violence: a sub-national study of India 1956-2002. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 52(4), pp. 590 617. Varshney, Ashutosh. (2002) Ethnic Conflict and Civic Life: Hindus and Muslims in India. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Weiner, Myron. (1978) Sons of the Soil. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Wilkinson, Stephen I. (2004) Votes and Violence: Electoral Competition and Ethnic Riots in India. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Woodward, Susan. (1995) Insurgent Collective Action and Civil War in El Salvador. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Weiner, Myron. (1978) Sons of the Soil. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. 15

Appendix 1 Maps Map 1: State-based fatalities 16

Map 2: One-sided fatalities 17

Map 3: Non-state fatalities 18