FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Similar documents
Deconstructing Structural Unemployment

Deconstructing Structural Unemployment

BY Rakesh Kochhar FOR RELEASE MARCH 07, 2019 FOR MEDIA OR OTHER INQUIRIES:

THE STATE OF THE UNIONS IN 2011: A PROFILE OF UNION MEMBERSHIP IN LOS ANGELES, CALIFORNIA AND THE NATION 1

Policy brief ARE WE RECOVERING YET? JOBS AND WAGES IN CALIFORNIA OVER THE PERIOD ARINDRAJIT DUBE, PH.D. Executive Summary AUGUST 31, 2005

Recent Job Loss Hits the African- American Middle Class Hard

The State of Working Wisconsin 2017

5A. Wage Structures in the Electronics Industry. Benjamin A. Campbell and Vincent M. Valvano

Second Quarter. April June 2016

Backgrounder. This report finds that immigrants have been hit somewhat harder by the current recession than have nativeborn

Geoff Bascand: Inflation pressures through the lens of the labour market

FISCAL POLICY INSTITUTE

THE STATE OF WORKING FLORIDA

Patrick Adler and Chris Tilly Institute for Research on Labor and Employment, UCLA. Ben Zipperer University of Massachusetts, Amherst

LEFT BEHIND: WORKERS AND THEIR FAMILIES IN A CHANGING LOS ANGELES. Revised September 27, A Publication of the California Budget Project

The behaviour of wages in Ireland during the recession

THE STATE OF THE UNIONS IN 2009: A PROFILE OF UNION MEMBERSHIP IN LOS ANGELES, CALIFORNIA AND THE NATION 1

THE STATE OF THE UNIONS IN 2007: A PROFILE OF UNION MEMBERSHIP IN LOS ANGELES, CALIFORNIA AND THE NATION 1

Business Address Date of Birth: August 3, 1961 Economic Research Department

Raising the Speed Limit on Future Growth

Latino Workers in the Ongoing Recession: 2007 to 2008

Leveling the Playing Field

How Have Hispanics Fared in the Jobless Recovery?

Explanations of Slow Growth in Productivity and Real Wages

Working women have won enormous progress in breaking through long-standing educational and

Update ,000 Missing Jobs: Wisconsin s Lagging Sectors

Remittances and the Macroeconomic Impact of the Global Economic Crisis in the Kyrgyz Republic and Tajikistan

Inequality in the Labor Market for Native American Women and the Great Recession

During the early 1990s, recession

Financial Crisis. How Firms in Eastern and Central Europe Fared through the Global Financial Crisis: Evidence from

What s so Scary about a Recession? A Long-term View of the State of Working Oregon

Offshoring and U.S. Labor Markets

Job Displacement Over the Business Cycle,

Executive summary. Part I. Major trends in wages

Immigrants are playing an increasingly

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS

Recession in Japan Part I

The U.S. Economy and Alaska Migration

San Francisco Economic Strategy Update: Phase I Findings

UNEMPLOYMENT IN AUSTRALIA

Second Anniversary of the Recovery Shows No Job Growth for Women (July 2011)

The State of. Working Wisconsin. Update September Center on Wisconsin Strategy

A COMPARISON OF ARIZONA TO NATIONS OF COMPARABLE SIZE

The Great Recession and its aftermath: What role do structural changes play?

Poverty in New York City, 2005: More Families Working, More Working Families Poor

The Improving Relative Status of Black Men

EPI BRIEFING PAPER. Immigration and Wages Methodological advancements confirm modest gains for native workers. Executive summary

EXPORT-ORIENTED ECONOMY - A NEW MODEL OF DEVELOPMENT FOR THE REPUBLIC OF MOLDOVA

Contents About this Report August 2017 Border Summary Housing

A Barometer of the Economic Recovery in Our State

Macro CH 21 sample questions

Government data show that since 2000 all of the net gain in the number of working-age (16 to 65) people

Falling Real Wages. Stephen Machin*

Real Wage Trends, 1979 to 2017

The labor market in Japan,

The Hispanic white wage gap has remained wide and relatively steady

Immigrants Employment Outcomes over the Business Cycle

Recent immigrant outcomes employment earnings

STAREBEI: DELIVERABLE 1

Impact of Oil Boom and Bust on Human Capital Investment in the U.S.

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men

The State of Working Connecticut 2011: Wages, Job Sector Changes, and the Great Recession

Job Growth and the Quality of Jobs in the U.S. Economy

WHAT S ON THE HORIZON?

ECON 141 Ch. 2 Dr. Mohammed Alwosabi

Low-paid Work and Economically Vulnerable Families over the Last Two Decades

The economic crisis in the low income CIS: fiscal consequences and policy responses. Sudharshan Canagarajah World Bank June 2010

Assessing Differences in Labor Market Outcomes Across Race, Age, and Educational Attainment. Working Paper April 2017

10/11/2017. Chapter 6. The graph shows that average hourly earnings for employees (and selfemployed people) doubled since 1960

MADE IN THE U.S.A. The U.S. Manufacturing Sector is Poised for Growth

Where have all the Wages Gone?

Executive Summary. Figures provided by the U.S. Census Bureau 1 demonstrate that teen employment prospects are dismal:

What Happened to the Immigrant \ Native Wage Gap during the Crisis: Evidence from Ireland

IPR 40 th Anniversary Distinguished Public Policy Lecture. Rebecca Blank. "Why Does Inequality Matter and What Should We Do About It?

ifo Business Climate Index Hits New Record High

RESEARCH BRIEF: The State of Black Workers before the Great Recession By Sylvia Allegretto and Steven Pitts 1

SUMMARY LABOUR MARKET CONDITIONS POPULATION AND LABOUR FORCE. UNRWA PO Box Sheikh Jarrah East Jerusalem

Monetary Theory and Central Banking By Allan H. Meltzer * Carnegie Mellon University and The American Enterprise Institute

Unemployment Rises Sharply Among Latino Immigrants in 2008

Does Political Business Cycle exist in India? By

Librarian Salaries: Have they kept pace with inflation? Denise M. Davis, Director Office for Research & Statistics American Library Association

SPECIAL REPORT. TD Economics ABORIGINAL WOMEN OUTPERFORMING IN LABOUR MARKETS

The ten years since the start of the Great Recession have done little to address

Over the past three decades, the share of middle-skill jobs in the

and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1

Speech given by Mervyn King, Governor of the Bank of England. At Salts Mills, Bradford, Yorkshire 13 June 2005

Productivity Growth, Wage Growth and Unions 1

Table 1. Nepal: Monthly Data for Key Macroeconomic Indicators.

The Mystery of Stagnant Wage Growth

How Has Job Polarization Contributed to the Increase in Non-Participation of Prime-Age Men?

SUMMARY LABOUR MARKET CONDITIONS !!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! POPULATION AND LABOUR FORCE. UNRWA PO Box Sheikh Jarrah East Jerusalem

Real Wages and Unemployment in the Big Squeeze

Chapter 10. Resource Markets and the Distribution of Income. Copyright 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

This Expansion Looks Familiar

I would like to add my voice to the chorus in thanking President Fisher and the

As Figure 1 below shows, unemployment levels jumped significantly during the

Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press. Volume URL: Chapter URL:

LABOUR MARKET SLACK. Article published in the Quarterly Review 2019:1, pp

11.433J / J Real Estate Economics

Productivity, Output, and Unemployment in the Short Run. Productivity, Output, and Unemployment in the Short Run

Transcription:

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER 212-1 April 2, 212 Why Has Wage Growth Stayed Strong? BY MARY DALY, BART HOBIJN, AND BRIAN LUCKING Despite a severe recession and modest recovery, real wage growth has stayed relatively solid. A key reason seems to be downward nominal wage rigidities, that is, the tendency of employers to avoid cutting the dollar value of wages. This phenomenon means that, in nominal terms, wages tend not to adjust downward when economic conditions are poor. With inflation relatively low in recent years, these rigidities have limited reductions in the real wages of a large fraction of U.S. workers. Real wage growth, that is, wage growth after accounting for inflation, has held up surprisingly well in the recent recession and recovery. Despite modest economic growth and persistently high unemployment, real wage growth has averaged 1.1% since 28. As Figure 1 shows, this pattern contrasts notably with previous decades, when real wage growth slowed substantially in response to business cycle downturns. One reason real wage growth has been so solid is that inflation has been low, with the personal consumption expenditures price index increasing at an average annual rate of 1.8% since the start of 28. Low inflation means that employers cannot reduce real wages simply by letting inflation erode the value of worker pay. Instead, if they want to reduce real labor costs, they must cut the actual dollar value of wages. Employers generally avoid doing so because cuts to nominal wages can reduce morale and prompt resistance even in difficult economic times (Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler 1986). Figure 1 Inflation and wage growth through business cycles 1 1 - Core inflation Nominal wage growth Real wage growth -1 8 82 84 86 88 9 92 94 96 98 2 4 6 8 1 12 Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics and authors calculations. The inability or unwillingness of employers to reduce nominal pay is known as downward wage rigidity. When economic conditions are poor, this rigidity can disrupt normal labor market functioning, especially in a low-inflation environment. If wages are downwardly rigid, workers may receive false signals about the value of remaining in a particular occupation or industry. For example, consider construction workers who are less productive now than they were five years ago because of the bursting of the housing bubble. If their wages fell, they might seek jobs in other industries. Because of downward wage rigidity, they may stay in construction instead. On the labor demand side, employers that can t cut

FRBSF Economic Letter 212-1 April 2, 212 wages may delay expanding payrolls as conditions improve. Either way, downward nominal wage rigidities can result in misallocation of resources in the economy. In this Economic Letter, we describe how economists identify nominal wage rigidities. We then update evidence of downward nominal wage rigidities over time, focusing on the behavior of nominal wages since the start of the recent recession. Data and methods Our analysis is based on individual-level data from 198 through 211 from the Current Population Survey (CPS), the monthly survey conducted by the Bureau of Labor Statistics used to measure the unemployment rate. Survey respondents are interviewed eight times over 16 months and asked to report their earnings near the beginning of their time in the survey and then a year later near the end of their survey tenure. We examine the subset of workers in the CPS who did not change jobs during the year in which they reported earnings. We consider both salaried workers and hourly wage workers, excluding those receiving the federal or state minimum wage, since employers cannot legally reduce their pay. For salaried workers, we calculate an hourly wage rate by dividing weekly earnings by hours worked. For hourly workers, we use their reported hourly wage. Following the methodology of Card and Hyslop (1996), we compute a nominal wage change for each worker in our sample based on pay as reported early in the survey and a year later. Our final data set consists of 12-month rolling panels of wage data from January 198 to December 211, which we use to evaluate trends in the behavior of nominal wage changes. For details and a technical explanation of using the CPS data to track wage changes, see Daly, Hobijn, and Wiles (211). Measuring nominal wage rigidities Researchers generally point to asymmetries in the distribution of observed wage changes among individual workers as evidence of nominal wage rigidities. Figure 2 plots an example of this type of wage change distribution in 211. The dashed black line shows a symmetric normal distribution. The blue bars plot the actual distribution of nominal wages. The figure s most striking feature is the blue bar that spikes at zero, indicating the large number of workers who report no change in wages over a year. This spike stands Figure 2 Distribution of observed nominal wage changes 18 16 14 12 1 8 6 4 2 -. -.4 -.3 -.2 -.1.1.2.3.4. Log change in reported earnings Sources: Current Population Survey (CPS) and authors calculations. out in the distribution of actual wage changes, suggesting that, rather than cutting pay, employers simply kept wages fixed over the year. This is supported by the large gap to the left of zero between the actual 2

FRBSF Economic Letter 212-1 April 2, 212 distribution of wage changes and the dashed black line representing the normal distribution. This gap suggests that the spike at zero is made up mostly of workers whose wages otherwise would have been cut. Downward nominal wage rigidities over the business cycle To understand whether such downward nominal wage rigidities might be important to the performance of the economy, we need to look at how common such rigidities are over the business cycle. Figure 3 plots the percentage of workers in the same job who report no year-overyear wage change. The figure includes data for all workers, and for hourly and salaried workers separately. As the figure shows, downward nominal wage rigidities begin to rise in recessions for both hourly and salaried workers. Wages mostly change on a yearly basis. For that reason, the prevalence of such rigidities typically lags the actual downturn of the economy, but then persists well into the recovery. During the recent recession and recovery, the run-up in the fraction of workers subject to downward nominal wage rigidity has been especially large. From 27 to the end of 211, the fraction of workers experiencing no yearly wage change rose to 16% from 11.2%. This is five percentage points higher than the average size of the spike at zero from 1983 to 27, and higher than in any period in our sample. Downward nominal wage rigidities by education Figure 3 No wage changes: Hourly and nonhourly workers 2 2 1 1 Hourly 8 82 84 86 88 9 92 94 96 98 2 4 6 8 1 Note: Breaks in lines associated with privacy recodes and survey redesign Figure 4 No wage changes by education level 2 2 1 1 No HS College This phenomenon has affected a broad range of workers during the recent period. Figure 4 plots the 8 82 84 86 88 9 92 94 96 98 2 4 6 8 1 share of workers receiving no wage change by education. Less-educated workers have historically been more likely to get no yearly wage change. Recently though, the percentage of workers with no wage change has increased markedly at all education levels. This contrasts with the business cycles of the early 199s and HS All Nonhourly Some college 3

FRBSF Economic Letter 212-1 April 2, 212 2s, when more-educated workers were shielded to a greater extent from increases in nominal wage rigidities. In fact, in the recent period, zero wage changes increased almost as much for college-educated workers as for workers with less than a high school education. That has not been seen in any other period in our sample, suggesting that a broad range of employers in a variety of sectors might feel pressure to cut wages, but are unable to do so because of downward nominal wage rigidity. Downward nominal wage rigidities by industry Workers in industries hit particularly hard in the recent recession might be considered more likely to see no wage change than workers in industries that fared relatively better. For example, construction and financial services did particularly poorly in the recession because of the housing bust and financial crisis. Consequently, relatively more workers in those industries might be expected to have their wages stay the same. Nonetheless, the increase in the percentage of workers holding the same job whose wages were unchanged is remarkably consistent across industries. Figure plots the fraction of workers receiving no nominal change in their wage across three sectors: construction, financial services, and manufacturing. In all three sectors, the percentage of workers reporting a wage change of zero rose. Although the increase was especially large in construction, it s notable that all three sectors experienced a large run-up in the fraction of workers reporting no yearly change in their wage. Figure No wage changes by industry 2 2 1 1 8 82 84 86 88 9 92 94 96 98 2 4 6 8 1 Construction Manufacturing Finance The breadth of the increase in workers reporting no wage change suggests that downward nominal rigidities pervade a broad array of industries. Nonetheless, there is also evidence that downward rigidities are more common in industries hit hardest by the recession, such as construction. If this is true, downward rigidities may be preventing necessary adjustments across industries in the economy. Conclusion The distribution of the dollar value of wage changes suggests that a significant fraction of workers are affected by downward nominal wage rigidities. Our analysis, based on data through the end of 211, suggests that downward nominal wage rigidities have affected a much larger share of the workforce in recent years. The fraction of workers reporting a wage change of zero is higher now than at any point in the past 3 years. This may partly explain why real wage growth has not significantly declined since the onset of the recession in December 27 and why hiring has been slow since the start of the recovery in mid-29. Because nominal wage growth for a large fraction of workers has been held to zero, a 4

1 FRBSF Economic Letter 212-1 April 2, 212 somewhat higher rate of inflation would grease the wheels of the labor market by allowing real wages to fall (Akerlof, Dickens, and Perry 1996). Mary C. Daly is a group vice president and associate director of research in the Economic Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. Bart Hobijn is a senior research advisor in the Economic Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. Brian Lucking is a research associate in the Economic Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. References Akerlof, George A., William T. Dickens, and George L. Perry. 1996. The Macroeconomics of Low Inflation. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1996(1). http://www.jstor.org/stable/234646 Card, David, and Dean Hyslop. 1996. Does Inflation Grease the Wheels of the Labor Market? National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 38. http://www.nber.org/papers/w38 Daly, Mary C., Bart Hobijn, and Theodore S. Wiles. 211. Aggregate Real Wages: Macro Fluctuations and Micro Drivers. FRBSF Working Paper 211-23. http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/papers/211/wp11-23bk.pdf Kahneman, Daniel, Jack L. Knetsch, and Richard Thaler. 1986. Fairness as a Constraint on Profit Seeking: Entitlements in the Market. American Economic Review 76(4). http://www.jstor.org/stable/1867 Recent issues of FRBSF Economic Letter are available at http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/letter/ 212-9 Emerging Asia: Two Paths through the Storm http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/letter/212/el212-9.html 212-8 Job Creation Policies and the Great Recession http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/letter/212/el212-8.html 212-7 Do Fed TIPS Purchases Affect Market Liquidity? http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/letter/212/el212-7.html 212-6 U.S. and Euro-Area Monetary Policy by Regions http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/letter/212/el212-6.html 212- Mortgage Prepayment: An Avenue Foreclosed? http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/letter/212/el212-.html 212-4 Government Spending: An Economic Boost? http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/letter/212/el212-4.html 212-3 Why Is Unemployment Duration So Long? http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/letter/212/el212-3.html 212-2 The Federal Reserve and the Economic Recovery http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/letter/212/el212-2.html Hale / Kennedy Neumark Christensen / Gillan Malkin / Nechio Laderman Wilson Valletta / Kuang Williams Opinions expressed in FRBSF Economic Letter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. This publication is edited by Sam Zuckerman and Anita Todd. Permission to reprint portions of articles or whole articles must be obtained in writing. Please send editorial comments and requests for reprint permission to Research.Library.sf@sf.frb.org.