Title: Origin and destination social capital in international migration from DR Congo, Ghana and Senegal

Similar documents
MAFE Project Migrations between AFrica and Europe. Cris Beauchemin (INED)

Heather Randell & Leah VanWey Department of Sociology and Population Studies and Training Center Brown University

Leaving, returning: reconstructing trends in international migration with five questions in household surveys

The Impact of International Migration on the Labour Market Behaviour of Women left-behind: Evidence from Senegal Abstract Introduction

Legal Status at Migration and Migrant Networks. Mao-Mei LIU 1

The Impact of International Migration on the Labour Market Behaviour of Women left-behind: Evidence from Senegal. Cora MEZGER 1 Sorana TOMA 2

Political turmoil, economic crisis, and international migration from Africa to Europe. Evidence from event-history data in DR Congo

Reasons for migration & their impact on return behaviour

Gender differences in the role of migrant networks in Congolese and Senegalese international migration

Marrying transnationally? The Role of Migration in Explaining the Timing and Type of Partnership Formation Among the Senegalese

Becoming a Man: Legal status, Networks and Male Migration between Senegal and Europe

Gender differences in naturalization among Congolese migrants in Belgium. Why are women more likely to acquire Belgian citizenship?

Household Vulnerability and Population Mobility in Southwestern Ethiopia

Discovering Migrant Types Through Cluster Analysis: Changes in the Mexico-U.S. Streams from 1970 to 2000

Transnational Ties of Latino and Asian Americans by Immigrant Generation. Emi Tamaki University of Washington

Fertility Behavior of Migrants and Nonmigrants from a Couple Perspective: The Case of Senegalese in Europe

The Role of Migration and Income Diversification in Protecting Households from Food Insecurity in Southwest Ethiopia

Do Migrant Remittances Lead to Inequality? 1

MAFE Working Paper 30 Migrant Families between Africa and Europe: Comparing Ghanaian, Congolese and Senegalese Migration Flows

PREDICTORS OF CONTRACEPTIVE USE AMONG MIGRANT AND NON- MIGRANT COUPLES IN NIGERIA

How Job Characteristics Affect International Migration: The Role of Informality in Mexico

Abstract for: Population Association of America 2005 Annual Meeting Philadelphia PA March 31 to April 2

TESTING OWN-FUTURE VERSUS HOUSEHOLD WELL-BEING DECISION RULES FOR MIGRATION INTENTIONS IN SOUTH AFRICA. Gordon F. De Jong

What Do Networks Do? The Role of Networks on Migration and Coyote" Use

Selection and Assimilation of Mexican Migrants to the U.S.

An Integrated Analysis of Migration and Remittances: Modeling Migration as a Mechanism for Selection 1

Roles of children and elderly in migration decision of adults: case from rural China

Irregular Migration in Sub-Saharan Africa: Causes and Consequences of Young Adult Migration from Southern Ethiopia to South Africa.

Male labor migration and migrational aspirations among rural women in Armenia. Arusyak Sevoyan Victor Agadjanian. Arizona State University

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

EXTENDED FAMILY INFLUENCE ON INDIVIDUAL MIGRATION DECISION IN RURAL CHINA

THE EMPLOYABILITY AND WELFARE OF FEMALE LABOR MIGRANTS IN INDONESIAN CITIES

Emigrating Israeli Families Identification Using Official Israeli Databases

Determinants of Migrants Savings in the Host Country: Empirical Evidence of Migrants living in South Africa

*** DRAFT DO NOT CITE *** Legal status, gender, and economic incorporation of Senegalese migrants in France, Italy, and Spain.

Title: Religious Differences in Wome n s Fertility and Labour Force Participation in France Nitzan Peri-Rotem

2.2 THE SOCIAL AND DEMOGRAPHIC COMPOSITION OF EMIGRANTS FROM HUNGARY

Workshop on International Migration Statistics. Anna Di Bartolomeo. 18 June 2013

Transitions to residential independence among young second generation migrants in the UK: The role of ethnic identity

Changing patterns of migration between Africa and Europe: Departures, trajectories & returns MAFE PROJECT Policy Briefing No. 2

Characteristics of migrants in Nairobi s informal settlements

Evaluating Methods for Estimating Foreign-Born Immigration Using the American Community Survey

Tracing Emigrating Populations from Highly-Developed Countries Resident Registration Data as a Sampling Frame for International German Migrants

(606) Migration in Developing Countries Internal migration in Indonesia: Mobility behaviour in the 1993 Indonesian Family Life Survey

Gender, age and migration in official statistics The availability and the explanatory power of official data on older BME women

MIGRANT VULNERABILITY TO HUMAN TRAFFICKING AND EXPLOITATION BRIEF

Richard Bilsborrow Carolina Population Center

Labor force participation of Latin-American mothers in Spain: the role of multigenerational living arrangements in times of economic crisis

Characteristics of the Ethnographic Sample of First- and Second-Generation Latin American Immigrants in the New York to Philadelphia Urban Corridor

MAFE Working Paper 22. Factors of Migration between Africa and Europe: Assessing the Role of Resources, Networks and Context. A Comparative Approach

Reconstructing Trends in International Migration with Three Questions in Household Surveys. Lessons from the MAFE project

Ties that bind? Networks and Gender in International Migration The case of Senegal

GENDER DIFFERENCES IN THE DESTINATION CHOICES OF LABOR MIGRANTS: MEXICAN MIGRATION TO THE UNITED STATES IN THE 1990s

Journal of Business & Economics Research January, 2009 Volume 7, Number 1

DETERMINANTS OF INTERNAL MIGRATION IN PAKISTAN

Margarita Mooney Assistant Professor University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill Chapel Hill, NC

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at

Mexican Migration and Union Formation in Sending Communities: A Research Note

Learning about Irregular Migration from a unique survey

DETERMINANTS OF IMMIGRANTS EARNINGS IN THE ITALIAN LABOUR MARKET: THE ROLE OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND COUNTRY OF ORIGIN

Does Paternity Leave Matter for Female Employment in Developing Economies?

Social Networks and Their Impact on the Employment and Earnings of Mexican Immigrants. September 23, 2004

Economics of Migration. John Palmer Pompeu Fabra University 2016

Definition of Migratory Status and Migration Data Sources and Indicators in Switzerland

VOLUME 28, ARTICLE 19, PAGES PUBLISHED 19 MARCH DOI: /DemRes

The Remitting Patterns of African Migrants in the OECD #

Domestic and International Migration from China: the Impact of Migration Networks and Rural Political Economy* (draft) Zai Liang and Miao David Chunyu

REMITTANCE TRANSFERS TO ARMENIA: PRELIMINARY SURVEY DATA ANALYSIS

262 Index. D demand shocks, 146n demographic variables, 103tn

Working paper 20. Distr.: General. 8 April English

Migration, Remittances, and Labor Supply in Albania

Individual and Community Effects on Immigrant Naturalization. John R. Logan Sookhee Oh Jennifer Darrah. Brown University

A home of her own: an analysis of asset ownership for non-married black and white women

How international migration impacts fertility? The role of migrant networks, spouse s migration, and own migration

Social Capital and International Migration from Latin America

The migration model in EUROPOP2004

Internal Migration and the Use of Reproductive and Child Health Services in Peru

Determinants of the Use of Public Services by Mexican Immigrants Traveling Alone and With Family Members

Survey respondents 1.9% 19.6% 6.3% 9.1% 11% 11% 0.1% 21.1% Gender 23.6% 76.4% Age 0.3% 8.6% 22.9% 45.6% 2.7% 19.7%

Differences in remittances from US and Spanish migrants in Colombia. Abstract

How to collect migration statistics using surveys

International emigration and the labour market outcomes of women staying behind in Morocco

Rainfall and Migration in Mexico Amy Teller and Leah K. VanWey Population Studies and Training Center Brown University Extended Abstract 9/27/2013

SENSIKO Working Paper / 3. Sicherheit älterer Menschen im Wohnquartier (SENSIKO) An attrition analysis in the SENSIKO survey (waves 1 and 2)

Agency, Education and Networks: Gender and International Migration from Albania

Design of Specialized Surveys of International Migration: The MED-HIMS Experience

Impact of remittance on immigrant homeownership trajectories: An analysis of the LSIC in Canada from

Reunifying versus Living Apart Together Across Borders: A Comparative Analysis of Sub-Saharan Migration to Europe

Choice of destination country: evidence from refugees in Australia and potential asylum seekers in Afghanistan, Bangladesh, Pakistan and Sri Lanka

A spike in the number of asylum seekers in the EU

3.3 DETERMINANTS OF THE CULTURAL INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS

Defining migratory status in the context of the 2030 Agenda

How Distance Matters: Comparing the Causes and Consequence of Emigration from Mexico and Peru

Collecting better census data on international migration: UN recommendations

The role of family and international migration dynamics in the formation of single-parent families

Discussion comments on Immigration: trends and macroeconomic implications

VOLUME 35, ARTICLE 13, PAGES PUBLISHED 18 AUGUST DOI: /DemRes

Migration and Remittances in Senegal: Effects on Labor Supply and Human Capital of Households Members Left Behind. Ameth Saloum Ndiaye

The Economic and Social Outcomes of Children of Migrants in New Zealand

Existing survey programs and need for new survey modules.on migration

Transcription:

Extended abstract submitted to PAA 2014 Title: Origin and destination social capital in international migration from DR Congo, Ghana and Senegal Abstract: This paper explores how origin and destination social capital influence migration. In quantitative migration scholarship to date, studies of origin social capital (e.g. household structure, strategies) and destination social capital (e.g. migrant networks) are largely segregated. Yet, qualitative migration scholarship has shown that potential migrants are swayed by a complex and geographically-distributed web of kin and friends. Utilizing the recent longitudinal Migration between Africa and Europe project data (2012), this paper aims to unify these diverse research streams. Comparing different origin contexts (DR Congo, Ghana, Senegal), this study will also reveal how the social capital influences are mediated by gender, generation and familial culture. Background New Economics of Labor Migration Theory and Social Capital Theory Both the new economics of labor migration theory and social capital theory explore how an individual s social ties can impact their likelihood of migration (see review of major migration theories in Massey et al 1993), yet their respective literatures have been strongly segregated between origin and destination. The first theory, new economics of labor migration, has an origin-looking approach in terms of social ties. Scholars propose that migration decisions are made by groups of people, usually family or household, to diversify risk and to maximize expected income (Stark and Bloom 1985). In doing so, families and households overcome the limitations of different markets (credit, unemployment insurance, futures, labor) by assigning some members to work locally and others to work abroad. The second theory, social capital theory (or migrant networks, as named by Massey et al 1987), has a destination-looking approach in terms of social ties. It proposes that an individual s links to migrants abroad directly affects one s likelihood to migrate, by providing information and resources. The network influence is expected to depend on the strength of the tie (Coleman 1988, Granovetter 1973, Burt 1995), and the quantity and quality of network resources (Lin 2000, Garip 2008, Liu 2013). Both negative and positive network effects are theoretically possible (Portes 1998). Despite their importance for understanding migration flows, empirical scholarship has not yet explored whether these migration theories complement one another or work in competition. Most scholarship considers the theories to be complimentary (e.g. Massey et al 1993), and some work considers them competitive (e.g. Palloni et al 2001), but rare is the work that explores this at length. Indeed, even Espinosa and Massey s influential paper (1997) theorized the complementary nature of different migration theories, while its empirical section treated them as competitive explanations by assigning one or more indicators to each and running all the indicators in the models. In any case, a wealth of literature has developed out of both new economics of labor migration and social capital theory. As related to the new economics of labor migration, quantitative scholarship has found that interest rates are the major macroeconomic determinant of migration and that home ownership dissuades migration (Massey and Espinosa 1997). Remittances also appear to increase economic development (for review, see Taylor 1999). Yet, exploration of how household make decisions about migration has been more limited. In terms of social capital theory, empirical studies have generally found that migrant networks facilitate migration by reducing the costs and risks of the migration trip (Donato et al 2008, Singer and page 1

Massey 1986), while increasing its benefits through higher earnings and job quality at destination (Amuedo-Dorantes and Mundra 2007, Munshi 2003). Origin and Destination Social Capital and Migration If origin and destination social capital influences on migration behavior are interrelated, studying each in isolation hobbles our understanding of international migration. Qualitative migration literature offers us different examples of how migrant social capital and household (non-)migration strategies jointly influence individual migration behavior: sometimes reinforcing one another, sometimes counteracting one another. In her anthropological study on unauthorized Senegalese boat migrants to the Canary Islands, Poeze (2010) identifies two models of origin and destination social capital influence. The opportunistic model applies to individuals with large migrant networks and views friendship migrant networks as a key conduit for developing feelings of relative deprivation. Individuals then may decide to migrate, in spite of household opposition. The conformist model captures individuals without large migrant networks, nor feelings of relative deprivation, in a context where the family hierarchy decides to send them abroad, and individuals negotiate and strategize to deal with the costs and risks of migration and family disobedience. In her study of Cameroon migrants to Germany, Fleischer (2007) finds that migration is a family project: in this case, family authority figures at origin (parents, older siblings and sometimes extended family) decide who migrates. In his study of Pakistani migrants to Europe, Ahmad (2008) documents how unauthorized migrants are attracted by the romantic appeal of migration and migrate despite household and elder opposition. Quantitative literature should follow the lead of qualitative migration scholars in analyzing together origin and destination social capital. Few studies have previously analyzed origin and destination social capital. In their clever study of brother pairs in Mexico-US migration, Palloni and colleagues (2001) found evidence for the importance of migrant network hypothesis (proxied by migrant brother), while controlling for household migration strategies (proxied by migrant father). In a previous paper about Senegal- Europe migration (Liu 2013), I utilized the MAFE project data to develop a time-varying control indicator for household migrant networks to help differentiate the migrant network hypothesis from the new economics of labor migration theory. However, since the paper was focused on migrant networks, there was no further exploration of origin social capital. In this current paper, I seek to explore origin and destination social capital, their composition, their influence and possible interactions as they influence international migration. Data & Methods Data This paper utilizes recent longitudinal survey data from the Migration between Africa and Europe Project (2012), collected in three sub-saharan African countries (Democratic Republic of Congo, Ghana and Senegal) and five countries in Europe (Belgium, France, Italy, the Netherlands, Spain, the UK). Beauchemin (2012) discusses the multi-site survey methodology. Based on retrospective individual questionnaires, the data contains full housing, partnership, children, work, and migration histories. Additional information about migrant networks, legal status, remittances and property ownership is also included. In terms of origin and destination social capital, there is time-varying information about household composition and year-by-year migration history for each migrant network member. 1,456 current Congolese, Ghanaian and Senegalese migrants in Europe and 3,943 residents in African capital regions (Accra and Kumasi in Ghana, Kinshasa in DR Congo and Dakar in Senegal) were interviewed between early 2008 and early 2010. page 2

This paper uses discrete-time event history analysis to predict the likelihood of first migration to Europe and how they migrated. As detailed below, the predictors in the logistic regression models capture variation by origin social capital, destination social capital, economic context and a wealth of other individual indicators. Focusing on adult migration, I restrict the sample to adults aged 17 and older, with the first possible migration to Europe at age 18. All individuals in the sample were born in DR Congo, Ghana or Senegal. Operational Measures Dependent variable The dependent variable First time migration to Europe is a dichotomous indicator coded 1 the year the respondent first moves to Europe. Moves from the origin country to other destinations are censored at year of migration. For all previous years, the dependent variable is coded 0. For the multinomial logistic regression models, there are three sets of dependent variables: mode of migration decision-making, mode of migration funding, and mode of migration trip. Defined in the year of first migration to Europe, these indicators represent respectively: how the migration decision was made, how it was funded and who actually traveled. The categories are identical for each indicator. For example, I identify three modes of migration decisionmaking: alone (the reference category), with origin network and with migrant network. Independent variables: Measuring Origin networks and Destination migrant networks Origin Networks We use household migrant networks to proxy for origin social capital. This is justified since household migrant networks represent the household migration strategy, whether or not the respondent then obeys the strategy or not. The household network indicator was constructed by matching time-varying information about household composition and the respondent s migrant network. For each housing spell, the survey includes information about the respondent s links to other household members (e.g., father, mother, partner, brother/s, sister/s, other relative, friend/s, other), but not their exact identities (e.g. which sister, which friend). The household network indicator is very generous, if any brother is listed as a household member; all brothers in the migrant networks are considered household members for the entire housing spell. Figure 2 graphically shows the construction of the household migrant network. Different household network composition indicators are then constructed and include household tie strength composition (nuclear family only, extended family only, nuclear and extended family, friend only), household gender composition (male only, female only, mixed). Migrant Networks The migrant network indicators are based on two survey questions. First, respondents were asked to name all parents, siblings, partners and children who had lived at least one year abroad. Second, respondents were asked to list other relatives and friends who had helped them migrate or could have helped them migrate and who had lived at least one year abroad. For both lists of individuals, the interviewer elicited a complete migration history (year, country) that included return migration, as well as gender, relationship with respondent, year met for friends and spouses and year of death where appropriate. For precision s sake, I have made three restrictions to the network indicators. First, I restrict all network indicators to years lived in Europe. This is justified since my research focus is on migration to Europe, and I am interested in how migrant networks in Europe can transfer page 3

information and resources that enable subsequent migration. Second, I follow previous work (Liu 2013) to exclude children and spouses from network measures in an attempt to separate out general network effects from the specific network effects and pathways involved in legal family reunification. Third, I also follow previous work (Liu 2013) to drastically restrict friendship networks in order to avoid problems of endogeneity. Tie Strength Following conventions found in migration literature, parents and siblings will be defined as strong ties, while extended family and friends will be defined as weak ties. Covariates and Macro Indicators The origin covariates are urban origin 1, religious affiliation (Muslim brotherhoods of Khadre, Layène, Mouride, Tidiane and a category for other Muslim, Catholic and other Christian); father s education (no school, primary, secondary and above); if father was deceased or unknown; if Ego was the firstborn; number of siblings; and Ego s highest level of education (pre-school or lower, primary, lower secondary, and higher secondary or higher). The timevarying covariates are marital status; polygamous union, number of children; occupational status (working, unemployed, studying, working at home, inactive); and property ownership (whether Ego owned land, housing or a business). To capture some macro-level effects, I include a series of period indicators 2 and two timevarying macro-economic indicators for Senegal: GDP % growth per capita and urban population growth (% of total). The macro-economic indicators were collected by the World Bank s World Development Indicators, and are available from 1961 through the time of the survey. Other potentially important indicators at destination, such as Senegalese foreign stock, rates of inflation and unemployment, were not available for the entire time frame in the wide range of data sources investigated (European Migration Network, Eurostat, IMF International Financial Statistics, OECD, UNPD, WDI), nor from individual country sources. Working Hypotheses Complementary or Competitive Theories of Migration H1 Following Massey and colleagues (1998), I expect that the new economics of labor migration theory and social capital theory are complementary explanations of migration. I expect to find evidence that origin-based and destination-based social capital complement one another. Poeze Opportunistic and Conformist Models of Migration H2- We test Poeze s opportunistic and conformist models (2010) that predict that the use of origin networks depending on an individual s access to large weak-tied migrant networks. I expect that large weak migrant networks will be more important for individuals without strongly-tied origin networks. On the other hand, I expect that large weak migrant networks will not influence individuals who already have strongly-tied origin networks. Strength of Ties of Origin Networks 1 The urban origin indicator is based on the most recent comprehensive data available, the 2002 Senegal census, and specifically the 2002 ANSD urban/rural classification. 2 The periods are before 1985, 1985-1993, 1994-1998, 1999-2003, after 2004. In 1985, France introduced a compulsory visa policy for Senegalese. In 1994, Senegal experienced a grave economic crisis when its currency, the CFA franc, was unlinked from the French franc and devalued by half. The rest of the periods were made to be of approximately equal length. page 4

H3 Since potential migrants are more likely to draw pre-migration resources from originbased networks than destination-based networks and more strongly-tied networks are more dependable, I expect that strongly-tied origin networks will have a larger influence than weakly-tied origin networks on migration. Modes of Migration Decision H4 In the sub-saharan context, extended families and households play a strong traditional role. As a result, migration decisions are often a family or household-level decision. Given this context, I expect that origin family networks will have a negative influence on migrations decided alone, but will positively influence migrations decided with others. Modes of Migration Funding H4 In the sub-saharan context, individuals planning a secret migration project will sometimes fundraise their migration through their friends and family under other pretexts (Fleischer 2007, Poeze 2010). As a result, migration decisions are often a family or household-level decision. Given this context, I expect that origin family networks will have a positive influence on migrations funded with others and a null influence on migrations funded alone. Modes of Migration Trip H4 In the sub-saharan context, origin family and households approval of higher risk (unauthorized) smuggled migration is variable, while they tend to support other kinds of less risky (authorized) migration (e.g. Fleischer 2007, Poeze 2010). Given this context, I expect that origin family networks will have a null influence on migration trips accompanied by a passeur or smuggler and positive influences on other kinds of migration. Results (to be completed) Table 1: Descriptive Information of Non-migrants and Migrants in the MAFE-Senegal data (at time of interview) Non-migrants Migrants Mean SE Mean SE CONTROLS Age 39.20 (0.614) 40.18 (0.528) Gender (male=1) 0.449 (0.0234) 0.710 (0.0242) * Family of Origin Urban origin 0.712 (0.0205) 0.750 (0.0251) Firstborn 0.241 (0.0203) 0.262 (0.0220) Number of Siblings 8.463 (0.261) 7.634 (0.290) Father unknown or deceased 0.0969 (0.0145) 0.0683 (0.0119) Father s Education No formal schooling 0.517 (0.0234) 0.440 (0.0263) Primary school 0.166 (0.0178) 0.203 (0.0224) Secondary and above 0.225 (0.0199) 0.289 (0.0264) Religious affiliation Muslim Layene 0.0294 (0.00746) 0.0337 (0.0218) Khadre 0.0305 (0.00727) 0.0239 (0.00803) Mouride 0.303 (0.0213) 0.351 (0.0258) Tidiane 0.478 (0.0234) 0.297 (0.0232) Other Muslim 0.0776 (0.0131) 0.158 (0.0179) Christian Catholic 0.0768 (0.0132) 0.0598 (0.0106) Other Christian 0.000773 (0.000555) 0.00309 (0.00273) Individual Status (at time of interview) Current Household Structure Married 0.740 (0.0206) 0.799 (0.0193) Has children 0.694 (0.0219) 0.738 (0.0222) Number of Children 2.968 (0.155) 2.342 (0.122) * Education No formal schooling 0.308 (0.0217) 0.170 (0.0189) * Primary school 0.372 (0.0231) 0.198 (0.0192) * Lower secondary 0.160 (0.0161) 0.251 (0.0280) * page 5

Baccalaureate & above 0.160 (0.0167) 0.380 (0.0252) * Property Land 0.0879 (0.0128) 0.287 (0.0266) * House 0.104 (0.0140) 0.381 (0.0285) * Business 0.0819 (0.0120) 0.0959 (0.0236) Current Occupational Status Working 0.619 (0.0228) 0.805 (0.0233) * Studying 0.0375 (0.00834) 0.0465 (0.0177) Unemployed 0.0546 (0.0113) 0.0616 (0.0124) At Home 0.230 (0.0195) 0.0481 (0.0104) * Retired 0.0352 (0.00896) 0.0307 (0.00834) Other Inactive 0.0245 (0.00791) 7.72e-3 (0.00466) DESTINATION-BASED MIGRANT NETWORK No Ties 0.509 (0.0233) 0.288 (0.0222) * Only Strong Tie 0.157 (0.0169) 0.302 (0.0257) * Only Weak Tie 0.259 (0.0211) 0.201 (0.0189) Both Ties 0.0755 (0.0116) 0.208 (0.0249) * ORIGIN-BASED MIGRANT NETWORK Having a Network 0.169 (0.0175) 0.313 (0.0259) * SPOUSAL MIGRANT NETWORK Having a Network 0.021 (0.0039) 0.092 (0.0141) * Individuals 1011 659 Note: * Differences significant at p<0.01. Individual weights included. Source: MAFE-Senegal 2008. Table 2 Logistic estimation of the odds of being a first-time migrant in a year: origin and destination social capital B SE No social capital 0.515*** 0.061 Origin social capital only (ref) Destination social capital only 1.281 0.175 Both origin and destination social capital 1.228 0.243 Control for Migrant Spouse 1.783*** 0.262 N (person-years) 28,379 Notes: Results are presented in odds ratios. Controls include age, ln(age), urban origin, religious affiliation, father s education, father unknown/deceased at respondent s age 15, firstborn, siblings, own highest level of education, marital status, polygynous, number of children, occupational status, landownership, homeownership, business ownership, period effects, % urban population growth, and % GDP per capita growth. All indicators other than those listed in italics are time-varying, year by year. Source: MAFE-Senegal 2008. p <.10; *p <.05; **p <.01; ***p <.001 page 6

Table 3 Logistic estimation of the relative risk of being a first-time migrant in a year, by who decided to migrate and who financed the trip: Origin and Destination social capital Model 1 Model 2 Decided alone Decided with Family and friends Paid oneself others helped finance trip B SE B SE B SE B SE Origin Social Capital 1.719*** 0.251 1.544*** 0.215 1.788*** 0.322 1.580*** 0.193 Destination Social Capital 1.835*** 0.277 2.203*** 0.323 1.502* 0.295 2.241*** 0.283 Control for Migrant Spouse 0.386** 0.146 3.011*** 0.525 0.206** 0.124 2.564*** 0.419 N (person-years) 28,379 28,379 28,379 28,379 Notes: Results are presented in relative risk. Controls include age, ln(age), urban origin, religious affiliation, father s education, father unknown/deceased at respondent s age 15, firstborn, number of siblings, own highest level of education, marital status, polygynous, number of children, occupational status, landownership, homeownership, business ownership, period effects, % urban population growth, and % GDP per capita growth. All indicators other than those listed in italics are time-varying, year by year. Source: MAFE-Senegal 2008. p <.10; *p <.05; **p <.01; ***p <.001 Table 4 Logistic estimation of the relative risk of being a first-time migrant in a year, by trip travel companions: Origin and Destination social capital Model 1 Traveled with passeur Traveled alone or with others B SE B SE Origin Social Capital 5.90e-7 0.012 1.615*** 0.165 Destination Social Capital 0.000 0.453 1.994*** 0.214 Control for Migrant Spouse 2.35e-8 0.000 1.828*** 0.269 N (person-years) 28,379 28,379 Notes: Results are presented in relative risk. Controls include age, ln(age), urban origin, religious affiliation, father s education, father unknown/deceased at respondent s age 15, firstborn, number of siblings, own highest level of education, marital status, polygynous, number of children, occupational status, landownership, homeownership, business ownership, period effects, % urban population growth, and % GDP per capita growth. All indicators other than those listed in italics are time-varying, year by year. Source: MAFE-Senegal 2008. p <.10; *p <.05; **p <.01; ***p <.001 References Ahmad, H. 2008. The romantic appeal of illegal migration: Gender, masculinity and human smuggling from Pakistan Illegal migration and gender in a global and historical perspective (ed. Marlou Schrover, Joanne van der Leun, Leo Lucassen and Chris Quispel). Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press (IMISCOE Research). pp 127-150. Amuedo-Dorantes, C. and K. Mundra. 2007. Social Networks and Their Impact on the Earnings of Mexican Migrants Demography 44(4): 849-863 Burt, R. 1995. Structural holes: the social structure of competition. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Coleman, J. 1988. Social Capital in the Creation of Human Capital American Journal of Sociology 94(S): S95- S120. Donato, K., B. Wagner and E. Patterson. 2008. The Cat and Mouse Game at the Mexico-U,S, Border: Gendered Patterns and Recent Shifts International Migration Review 42(2): 330-359. Fleischer, A. 2007. Family, obligations, and migration: the role of kinship in Cameroon. Demographic research, 16(13), 413-440. page 7

Garip, F. 2008. Social Capital and Migration: How do Similar Resources Lead to Divergent Outcomes? Demography 45(3): 591-617. Granovetter, M. 1973. The Strength of Weak Ties. American Journal of Sociology 78(6): 1360-1380. Lin, N. 2000. Inequality in Social Capital. Contemporary Sociology 29: 785-95. Liu, M.-M. 2013. Migrant Networks and International Migration: Testing Weak Ties. Demography 50: 1243-77. Massey, D and K. Espinosa. 1997. What s Driving Mexico-U.S. Migration? A Theoretical, Empirical and Policy Analysis. American Journal of Sociology 102(4): 939-999. Munshi, K. 2003. Networks in the Modern Economy: Mexican Migrants in the U.S. Labor Market. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(2): 549-599. Palloni, A., D. Massey, M. Ceballos, K. Espinosa and M. Spittel. 2001. Social Capital and International Migration: A Test using Information on Family Networks. The American Journal of Sociology 106: 1262-1298. Poeze, M. 2010. In search of greener pastures? Boat-migrants from Senegal to the Canary Islands. Leiden (Netherlands): African Studies Centre. Portes, A. 1998. Social Capital: Its Origins and Application in Modern Sociology. Annual Review of Sociology 24: 1-24. Singer, A. and D. Massey. 1998. The Social Process of Undocumented Border Crossing among Mexican Migrants. International Migration Review 32(3):561-592. Stark, O. and D.E. Bloom. 1985. The new economics of labor migration. The American Economic Review, 75(2), 173-178. Taylor, E. 1999. The New Economics of Labour Migration and the Role of Remittances in the Migration Process. International Migration: 37(1), 63-88. Figures Figure 1: Construction of household migrant network & non-household migrant network indicators (Source: Liu 2013) page 8