Why do states commit to international labor standards? Interdependent ratification of core ILO conventions,

Similar documents
Congruence in Political Parties

Political Power and Women s Representation in Latin America

Civil and Political Rights

WORLDWIDE DISTRIBUTION OF PRIVATE FINANCIAL ASSETS

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads

MODELLING EXISTING SURVEY DATA FULL TECHNICAL REPORT OF PIDOP WORK PACKAGE 5

Taiwan s Development Strategy for the Next Phase. Dr. San, Gee Vice Chairman Taiwan External Trade Development Council Taiwan

APPENDIX 1: MEASURES OF CAPITALISM AND POLITICAL FREEDOM

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

Women and Politics: A Global Perspective Sociology 670

A GAtewAy to A Bet ter Life Education aspirations around the World September 2013

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

@The Human Rights of Women in the United Nations: Developments

2018 Social Progress Index

GLOBAL RISKS OF CONCERN TO BUSINESS WEF EXECUTIVE OPINION SURVEY RESULTS SEPTEMBER 2017

Strengthening Protection of Labor Rights through Preferential Trade Agreements (PTAs)

Volume 30, Issue 1. Corruption and financial sector performance: A cross-country analysis

The Nation Brand Index perspectives on South Africa s global reputation. Brand South Africa Research Note. By: Dr Petrus de Kock

Comparative Political Economy. David Soskice Nuffield College

Levels and Trends of International Migration in Asia and the Pacific

Income and Population Growth

Women and Voting in the Arab World: Explaining the Gender Gap

CSI Brexit 2: Ending Free Movement as a Priority in the Brexit Negotiations

INTERNATIONAL CO-ORDINATING COMMITTEE OF NATIONAL INSTITUTIONS FOR THE PROMOTION AND PROTECTION OF HUMAN RIGHTS (ICC)

Appendix: Regime Type, Coalition Size, and Victory

A Global Perspective on Socioeconomic Differences in Learning Outcomes

Voter Turnout, Income Inequality, and Redistribution. Henning Finseraas PhD student Norwegian Social Research

Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix

PISA 2015 in Hong Kong Result Release Figures and Appendices Accompanying Press Release

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

The globalization of inequality

BY Amy Mitchell, Katie Simmons, Katerina Eva Matsa and Laura Silver. FOR RELEASE JANUARY 11, 2018 FOR MEDIA OR OTHER INQUIRIES:

2017 Recurrent Discussion on Fundamental

Brand South Africa Research Report

The Determinants of Low-Intensity Intergroup Violence: The Case of Northern Ireland. Online Appendix

UGANDA UNDER REVIEW BY UNITED NATIONS UNIVERSAL PERIODIC REVIEW:

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

The Multidimensional Financial Inclusion MIFI 1

DPI403. Human rights, justice, and rule of law

Panacea for International Labor Market Failures? Bilateral Labor Agreements and Labor Mobility. Steven Liao

CHILE S GENDER QUOTA: WILL IT WORK?

FIGURES ABOUT AMNESTY INTERNATIONAL AND ITS WORK FOR HUMAN RIGHTS. -- Amnesty International was launched in 1961 by British lawyer Peter Benenson.

Improving the accuracy of outbound tourism statistics with mobile positioning data

The Political Economy of Public Policy

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

Appendix to Sectoral Economies

A Partial Solution. To the Fundamental Problem of Causal Inference

92 El Salvador El Salvador El Salvador El Salvador El Salvador Nicaragua Nicaragua Nicaragua 1

ADDITIONAL RESULTS FOR REBELS WITHOUT A TERRITORY. AN ANALYSIS OF NON- TERRITORIAL CONFLICTS IN THE WORLD,

Does Government Ideology affect Personal Happiness? A Test

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

General Assembly UNITED NATIONS. Distr. GENERAL. A/HRC/10/69/Add.1 17 March Original: ENGLISH. HUMAN RIGHTS COUNCIL Tenth session Agenda item 6

Electoral Systems and Support for Female Candidates

BASIC DOCUMENTS ON HUMAN RIGHTS

PRESS OFFICERS FROM: PRESS AND PUBLICATIONS DATE: 9 MAY 1991 WEEKLY UPDATE SERVICE 16/91

ISSUE BRIEF: U.S. Immigration Priorities in a Global Context

Table A.1. Jointly Democratic, Contiguous Dyads (for entire time period noted) Time Period State A State B Border First Joint Which Comes First?

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018

September Press Release /SM/9256 SC/8059 Role of business in armed conflict can be crucial for good or ill

KINGDOM OF CAMBODIA NATION RELIGION KING 3 TOURISM STATISTICS REPORT. September 2010

Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins

Analyzing the Location of the Romanian Foreign Ministry in the Social Network of Foreign Ministries

Online Appendix for. Home Away From Home? Foreign Demand and London House Prices

Why are Immigrants Underrepresented in Politics? Evidence From Sweden

REMITTANCE PRICES WORLDWIDE

R esearch on gender in comparative politics has come

WP 2015: 9. Education and electoral participation: Reported versus actual voting behaviour. Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE

TANZANIA UNDER REVIEW BY UNITED NATIONS UNIVERSAL PERIODIC REVIEW:

DETERMINANTS OF NUCLEAR REVERSAL: WHY STATES GIVE UP NUCLEAR WEAPONS PROGRAMS

The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis

Syllabus. Graduate School for Social Research Women in Politics in Comparative Perspective

Re: A Call for Human Rights Concerns to be reflected in the Fortaleza Declaration of Sixth BRICS Summit

parties and party systems

Determinants of Return Migration to Mexico Among Mexicans in the United States

Powersharing, Protection, and Peace. Scott Gates, Benjamin A. T. Graham, Yonatan Lupu Håvard Strand, Kaare W. Strøm. September 17, 2015

Share of Countries over 1/3 Urbanized, by GDP per Capita (2012 $) 1960 and 2010

TANZANIA UNDER REVIEW BY UNITED NATIONS UNIVERSAL PERIODIC REVIEW:

Japan s Policy to Strengthen Economic Partnership. November 2003

Industrial & Labor Relations Review

BUILDING RESILIENT REGIONS FOR STRONGER ECONOMIES OECD

The International Covenant on Economic, Social, and Cultural Rights

Gender attitudes in the world of work: cross-cultural comparison

On the Future of Criminal Offender DNA Databases

European International Virtual Congress of Researchers. EIVCR May 2015

KINGDOM OF CAMBODIA NATION RELIGION KING 3 TOURISM STATISTICS REPORT. March 2010

TABLE 1 FINANCE AGREEMENTS INCLUDED IN THE SAMPLE Signature Date

What Are the Social Outcomes of Education?

FACT SHEET on the International Labour Organization (ILO) AI Index: IOR 42/004/2002

Thinking Outside the Alliance:

Appendix: Uncovering Patterns Among Latent Variables: Human Rights and De Facto Judicial Independence

Constitutional prohibitions of the death penalty

Employment Outlook 2017

Dirk Pilat:

Practice Questions for Exam #2

QGIS.org - Donations and Sponsorship Analysis 2016

Government 385: Women and Politics

International Egg Market Annual Review

Perceptions and knowledge of Britain and its competitors in Foresight issue 156 VisitBritain Research

Global Trends in Location Selection Final results for 2005

PISA 2009 in Hong Kong Result Release Figures and tables accompanying press release article

Transcription:

Why do states commit to international labor standards? Interdependent ratification of core ILO conventions, 1948-2009 Web-Appendices Contents Web-Appendix A. The control variable RATIFIED HUMAN RIGHTS TREATIES... 1 Web-Appendix B. An alternative measure of economic competition... 2 Web-Appendix C. Survival estimates for four conventions... 4 Web-Appendix D. Interdependence among ILO conventions... 5 Web-Appendix E. Assessing the tipping-the-balance hypothesis... 9 Web-Appendix F. Identifying unconditional ratifiers... 12 References in Web-Appendices... 14 Note: the tables in the Web-Appendixes use the following abbreviations. C29: Forced Labor Convention; C89: Freedom of Association Convention; C98: Collective Bargaining Convention; C100: Equal Remuneration Convention; C105: Abolition of Forced Labor Convention; C111: Discrimination Convention; C138: Minimum Age Convention. Web-Appendix A. The control variable RATIFIED HUMAN RIGHTS TREATIES In the main text, we noted that the analysis of ratification of ILO core conventions should control for the propensity of states to commit to human rights norms. To capture this propensity, created a variable RATIFIED HUMAN RIGHTS TREATIES that counts how many core international human rights treaties a state ratified in previous years. The treaties included are (1) the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights, (2) its first optional protocol, (3) its second optional protocol, (4) the International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights, (5) the International Covenant on the Elimination of Racial Discrimination, (6) its provisions on individual petition, (7) the Convention on the Elimination of All Forms of Discrimination Against Women, (8) the Convention against Torture and Other Cruel, Inhuman or Degrading Treatment or Punishment, (9) its optional protocol, (10) the 1

Convention on the Rights of the Child, (11) the International Convention on the Protection of Migrant Workers and Members of Their Families. Ratification information is from UCL s Nominal Commitment to Human Rights project. 1 Web-Appendix B. An alternative measure of economic competition We checked whether and how our findings change by using the measure of export similarity developed by Elkins, Guzman and Simmons instead of the measure developed by Polillo and Guillén. 2 This indicator is obtained by disaggregating trade flows into 17 sectors and then assessing whether countries export the same basket of goods. Data are from the World Development Indicators. To create an index of export similarity, we correlated the export basket of all countries. 3 We label this variable EXPORT SIMILARITY 2. We constructed a variable labeled COMPETITORS RATIFICATION 2 using the same procedure that yielded COMPETITORS RATIFICATION (see main text), but on the basis of EXPORT SIMILARITY 2 instead of EXPORT SIMILARITY. Table A.1 shows that COMPETITORS RATIFICATION 2 has a positive and statistically significant effect on the ratification of all conventions except the Minimum Age Convention. 1 See Çali et al. 2009. 2 Elkins et al. 2006, 830. 3 For computational reasons, and following Elkins et al. 2006, we rescale the correlation index from 0 to 2. 2

Table A.1. Determinants of ratification of seven core conventions, including COMPETITORS RATIFICATION 2. (A1) (A2) (A3) (A4) (A5) (A6) (A7) C29 C87 C98 C100 C105 C111 C138 COMPETITORS RATIFICATION 2 1.083*** 0.482*** 0.492*** 0.484*** 0.461*** 0.832*** 0.006 (0.271) (0.178) (0.179) (0.169) (0.135) (0.169) (0.067) NEIGHBORS RATIFICATION 0.218-1.110-0.297-2.031** -0.813 2.262*** -1.641* (1.066) (0.820) (1.043) (0.804) (1.200) (0.819) (0.926) CUMULATIVE RATIFICATIONS -0.003-0.011-0.005 0.004 0.012** 0.000 0.008 (0.007) (0.007) (0.005) (0.004) (0.006) (0.005) (0.007) GDPPC 0.014-0.167* -0.112-0.181** -0.044-0.022 0.074 (0.100) (0.096) (0.089) (0.080) (0.083) (0.080) (0.054) REGIME 0.258 0.289* 0.328 0.465** 0.435** 0.186 0.139 (0.271) (0.165) (0.258) (0.188) (0.213) (0.207) (0.188) LEGAL TRADITION 0.083-0.943*** -0.510** 0.674** 0.479** 0.521** - 0.625*** (0.245) (0.267) (0.254) (0.269) (0.215) (0.242) (0.216) RATIFIED HUMAN RIGHTS TREATIES -0.145** -0.051 0.064-0.013 0.009 0.148*** 0.072 (0.065) (0.037) (0.046) (0.050) (0.050) (0.042) (0.047) ABSOLUTE IGO MEMBERSHIPS 0.003 0.008 0.001 0.011 0.008-0.003 0.005 (0.013) (0.010) (0.009) (0.008) (0.008) (0.007) (0.006) POPULATION -2.978** -0.687* -2.170** 0.420-0.437** -0.365-0.028 (1.219) (0.389) (0.957) (0.413) (0.179) (0.375) (0.103) COLD WAR -0.379-0.901*** 0.578 0.088 0.287 0.867*** -0.640 (0.462) (0.276) (0.425) (0.347) (0.392) (0.213) (0.534) PH test (Prob>chi2) 0.67 0 0.29 0.03 0.53 0 0.47 Number of countries 125 172 173 173 172 173 169 Number of ratifications 92 99 109 138 135 137 128 Observations 1,867 3,969 3,354 2,945 2,511 2,675 3,567 Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 3

0.2.4.6.8 1 0.2.4.6.8 Web-Appendix C. Survival estimates for four conventions Figures A.1. Abolition of Forced Labor Convention: estimated probability of nonratification at different levels of COMPETITORS RATIFICATION. 1955 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 time span Competitors' ratification=mean-std Competitors' ratification=mean+std Figures A.2. Freedom of Association Convention: estimated probability of non-ratification at different levels of ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION. 1949 1969 1989 2009 time span Associates' ratification=mean-std Associates' ratification=mean+std 4

0.2.4.6.8 Estimated Probability of Non-Ratification.2.4.6.8 1 1 0 0.2.4.6.8 Estimated Probability of Non-Ratification.2.4.6.8 1 1 Figures A.3, a, b. Equal Remuneration Convention: estimated probability of non-ratification at different levels of COMPETITORS RATIFICATION and ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION. 1950 1970 1990 2010 time span Competitors' ratification=mean-std Competitors' ratification=mean+std 1950 1970 1990 2010 time span Associates' ratification=mean-std Associates' ratification=mean+std Figures A.4, a, b. Minimum Age Convention: estimated probability of non-ratification at different levels of COMPETITORS RATIFICATION and ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION. 1975 1985 1995 2005 40 time span Competitors' ratification=mean-std Competitors' ratification=mean+std 1975 1985 1995 2005 40 time span Associates' ratification=mean-std Associates' ratification=mean+std Web-Appendix D. Interdependence among ILO conventions As noted in the main text, it is possible that the ratification of a core convention x by country i might influence the probability that country j ratifies a core convention other than x. This interdependence among conventions is illustrated by Figure A.5, which shows the 5

0 Density.1.2.3.4 distribution of the maximum number of ILO conventions ratified in the same year by each country in the dataset. For instance, Botswana, Eritrea, and Gambia ratified all seven conventions in the same year, whereas Brunei, Bhutan, and Taiwan have ratified no conventions during the period under investigation. 4 In general, the majority of the countries ratified more than one convention per year, whereas less than 10 percent of the countries do not ratify any core conventions. 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Number of core ILO conventions ratified in the same year Figure A5. Distribution of the maximum number of ILO conventions ratified in the same year by each country in the dataset. To account for the possibility that states may be influenced not only by the ratification of a specific convention by others, but also by the ratification of core conventions in general, we pooled six core conventions together (we left the Minimum Age Convention out from this analysis, because this convention was ratified much later than the others and so we would lose many observations by including it). As noted in the main text, by pooling the conventions together, our dependent variable becomes the number of years before a country ratifies one of the six conventions. Thus, countries do not leave the dataset when they ratify a convention. In other words, we have multiple unordered failures of the same events. To 4 Brunei ratified the Minimum Age Convention in 2011. 6

correctly estimate this model, we used the Efron method and stratified observations by convention. In essence, we allowed for a different baseline hazard function for each convention. Table A.2 shows the results of this analysis. Spatial terms capturing COMPETITORS RATIFICATIONS for each convention are highly collinear with one another as well as the spatial terms capturing ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION. Thus, we include each spatial term in a separate model to avoid multicollinearity problems. Moreover, results for COMPETITORS RATIFICATION of the Forced Labor Convention are very similar to results for COMPETITORS RATIFICATION of the Freedom of Association Convention and the Collective Bargaining Convention. Likewise, results for ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION of the Forced Labor Convention are very similar to results for ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION of the Freedom of Association Convention and the Collective Bargaining Convention. As such, we only report estimates of models including COMPETITORS RATIFICATION of the Forced Labor Convention and ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION of the FORCED LABOR CONVENTION. The other results are available upon request. The key finding is that both COMPETITORS RATIFICATION and ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION of the Forced Labor Convention, the Equal Remuneration Convention, the Abolition of Forced Labor Convention, and the Discrimination Convention influence the ratification of the other conventions. Indeed, the coefficients of these variables are positive and statistically significant at the 99 percent level, with the exception of ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION of C111 We note that if we include COMPETITORS RATIFICATION of the Freedom of Association Convention, or of the Collective Bargaining Convention, and ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION of the Freedom of Association Convention or the Collective Bargaining Convention instead of the corresponding variables for the Forced Labor Convention, we obtain similar results to those reported in Table A.2: competitor as well as associate ratification variables have a positive and statistically significant effect on the ratification of other conventions. 7

Table A.2. Pooled analysis of core conventions. Cox model with robust standard errors clustered by country. VARIABLES (A8) (A9) (A10) (A11) (A12) (A13) (A14) (A15) COMPETITORS RATIFICATION of C29 0.325*** (0.044) COMPETITORS RATIFICATION of C100 0.271*** (0.043) COMPETITORS RATIFICATION of C105 0.099** (0.041) COMPETITORS RATIFICATION of C111 0.220*** (0.043) ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION of C29 0.227*** (0.041) ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION of C100 0.166*** (0.032) ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION of C105 0.056*** (0.020) ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION of C111 0.027 (0.019) GDPPC -0.046** -0.064*** -0.063*** -0.063*** -0.043** -0.054** -0.057*** -0.063*** (0.022) (0.021) (0.021) (0.021) (0.021) (0.021) (0.021) (0.021) REGIME -0.124-0.140-0.136-0.133-0.094-0.107-0.121-0.124 (0.088) (0.096) (0.093) (0.090) (0.072) (0.076) (0.084) (0.086) POPULATION -0.111** -0.127*** -0.126*** -0.123*** -0.078* -0.080* -0.107** -0.098** (0.047) (0.046) (0.046) (0.046) (0.047) (0.046) (0.046) (0.047) LEGAL TRADITION -0.213*** -0.195** -0.245*** -0.321*** -0.255*** -0.239*** -0.296*** -0.153* (0.080) (0.084) (0.089) (0.084) (0.077) (0.077) (0.078) (0.087) COLD WAR 0.218*** 0.241*** 0.251*** 0.253*** 0.212*** 0.225*** 0.238*** 0.231*** (0.064) (0.063) (0.063) (0.063) (0.063) (0.064) (0.064) (0.064) RATIFIED HUMAN RIGHTS TREATIES -0.018-0.024-0.030* -0.037** -0.015-0.025-0.033* -0.015 (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) ABSOLUTE IGO MEMBERSHIPS -0.005** -0.002-0.001-0.000-0.003* -0.003-0.002-0.001 (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) Observations 47,849 47,849 47,849 47,849 47,849 47,849 47,849 47,849 Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 8

Web-Appendix E. Assessing the tipping-the-balance hypothesis The UK case study presented in the main text prompted us to formulate the following general conjecture: ratification by social peers can tip the balance in the domestic contest between supporters and opponents of ratification, by providing argumentative ammunition to former and potentially extending the pro-ratification coalition to include actors interested in the good standing of their state in international forums in addition to (or sometimes instead of) the consequences of the ratification on domestic labor markets. In order to assess this conjecture empirically, we formulate a more directly testable hypothesis: Hypothesis 3: ratification of ILO conventions by social peers will have the clearest impact on states where the coalition in favor of ratification is neither very weak nor very strong relatively to anti-ratification groups. The rationale underpinning this hypothesis is that, according to our tipping-the-balance argument, foreign examples of ratification should play a major role where the coalition in favor of ratification is strong enough to make effective use of them, but not so strong to be able to obtain ratification regardless of what other states do. We test this hypothesis with reference to the Equal Remuneration Convention. We focus on this convention because the previous discussion of the UK case suggests a suitable proxy for the strength of the pro-ratification coalition on equal pay issues: the percentage of legislators who are women. We expect that (a) women legislators should be more actively supportive of ratification than men, and (b) a higher percentage of women legislators in a state should increase the probability of ratification. These expectations are grounded in theoretical and empirical research that maintains that the gender identity of legislators affect their policy priorities, preferences, and actions. 5 A substantial body of research on various countries shows that female legislators are more likely than male legislators to prioritize legislation related to women, children, families, health care and social services, and to introduce, speak and vote for bills on those topics. 6 Other studies show that the proportion of female elected representatives influences the 5 Phillips 1995, Sweers 2002, Wängnerud 2009. 6 See, for instance, Bratton and Haynie 1999, Wängnerud 2000, and Schwindt-Bayer 2006. 9

content of legislation, notably ensuring higher attention to women s rights and to social welfare policy. 7 In some countries, the executive has exclusive competence over ratification of international treaties and in most other countries the executive is responsible for submitting treaties for ratification to the legislature. But, as we have seen in the UK case, pro-ratification legislators can press the executive to ratify or submit for ratification, and all else being equal this pressure is likely to be stronger if a significant number of women sit in the legislative assembly. Moreover, all else being equal, an executive can be more confident that its request to ratify the treaty will be accepted by the legislature if in the latter there is a significant presence of women. Thus, Hypothesis 3 can be tested by ascertaining whether ratification of the Equal Remuneration Convention by social peers is most influential when the percentage of women legislators is intermediate rather than very low or very high. For this purpose, we analyze the interaction between our variable ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION and a new variable expressing the percentage of FEMALE LEGISLATORS. This variable ranges between 0 (United Arab Emirates) and 56.3 (Rwanda) with a mean of 8.7. 8 Moreover, we further interact ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION and FEMALE LEGISLATORS with REGIME, since women legislators can be expected to have an independent effect on ratification when the legislature itself has an independent effect of ratification, i.e. it is not merely a passive tool of unelected executives. In sum, we have a triple interaction term consisting of ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION FEMALE LEGISLATORS REGIME on the right handside of our equation as well as double interaction terms deriving from the combination of these three variables. As shown by Ai and Norton (2003), in non-linear models the significance and the sign of interaction terms are difficult to interpret. Interpretation is particularly problematic with a triple interaction term. For ease of interpretation, we split the sample at different values of FEMALE LEGISLATORS in addition to showing the estimation with the triple interaction term and three double interaction terms. Specifically, we split the sample into first quartile [0, 2.9), 7 See, for instance, Thomas 1991, Kittilson 2008, and Bolzendahl 2011. 8 Data are from Paxton et al. (2008) and World Bank (2012). 10

interquartile [2.9, 13.3.], and third quartile (13.3, 56.3]. 9 Then, we show the effect of ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION on the probability for ratifying the Equal Remuneration Convention for these three sub-samples, considering only electoral democracies. 10 Table A.3 reports the results. In line with our hypothesis, ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION has a positive and statistically significant effect on the probability of ratifying the Equal Remuneration Convention only in the interquartile sub-sample, i.e. when FEMALE LEGISLATORS is neither too low nor too high. By contrast, the coefficient of ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION is not statistically significant at the conventional level for very low values and very high values of FEMALE LEGISLATORS, i.e., in the first and third quartile. This provides support for our Hypothesis 3. 9 Japan and Turkey are democratic regimes that usually belong to the first category. Argentina, Brazil, Israel, the US and many European countries usually belong to the second category, though the US moved to the third category since 2000. Scandinavian countries, the Netherlands, and Canada usually belong to the third category. 10 For a similar approach, see Simmons (2009). 11

Table A.3. The effect of ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION on the ratification of the Equal Remuneration Convention at different levels of FEMALE LEGISLATORS. Cox model with robust standard errors clustered by country. VARIABLES (A16) (A17) (A18) (A19) Medium Low FEMALE FEMALE High FEMALE LEGISLATORS LEGISLATORS LEGISLATORS in democracies in democracies in democracies ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION 0.594** -0.048 0.606* 0.111 (0.291) (0.363) (0.330) (0.152) FEMALE LEGISLATORS 0.042 (0.104) ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION x FEMALE LEGISLATORS -0.004 (0.019) REGIME -0.149 (2.191) ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION x REGIME 0.099 (0.398) FEMALE LEGISLATORS x REGIME 0.137 (0.144) ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION x FEMALE LEGISLATORS x REGIME -0.026 (0.026) GDPPC -0.204** -0.112-0.155-0.787 (0.085) (0.322) (0.164) (0.690) POPULATION -1.121** -0.602-4.216** -11.462*** (0.533) (0.772) (1.924) (2.518) LEGAL TRADITION -0.485*** -0.234-0.573** -0.021 (0.174) (0.461) (0.247) (1.091) RATIFIED HUMAN RIGHTS TREATIES -0.077-0.099-0.201** -0.375** (0.051) (0.159) (0.097) (0.185) ABSOLUTE IGO MEMBERSHIPS 0.014* 0.065* 0.038** 0.143*** (0.008) (0.034) (0.017) (0.039) PH test (Prob>chi2) 0.12 0.65 0.54 1 Number of countries 161 45 53 29 Number of ratifications 123 15 36 9 Observations 2,327 409 458 147 Web-Appendix F. Identifying unconditional ratifiers In the main text we found strong support for the influence of competitors and associates in ratification decisions. However, ratification by associates or competitors is neither a 12

necessary nor a sufficient condition for domestic ratification when we consider the population of countries as a whole. Some states ratify core labor conventions regardless of ratification by competitors and associates. Our method for estimating the extent of spatial interdependencies can also help us to identify those states that are indifferent to foreign ratifications what, for the sake of brevity, could be called unconditional ratifiers with respect to our variables of interest. Unconditional ratifiers can be defined as those states that have very low values of both ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION and COMPETITORS RATIFICATION shortly before they ratify the convention. The absence or near absence of ratifications among their competitors and associates does not deter such states from ratifying. Defining low values as those at, or lower than, the 5 th percentile, we obtain the list of unconditional ratifiers presented in Table A.4. Interestingly, no state qualifies as an unconditional ratifier in relation to the Equal Remuneration Convention, the Abolition of Forced Labor Convention, and the Minimum Age Convention. The table also shows that, with the partial exception of the Forced Labor Convention, unconditional ratifiers tend to be electoral democracies and have above-average per capita incomes. Such conclusions are of course tentative, and the question deserves to be researched more thoroughly. Table A.4. Countries that ratified ILO core conventions despite low values ( 5 th percentile) of both ASSOCIATES RATIFICATION and COMPETITORS RATIFICATION. Year Electoral democracy Above-average GDPpc Forced Labor Convention Argentina 1950 Yes Yes Indonesia 1950 No No Sri Lanka 1950 No No Freedom of Association Convention United Kingdom 1949 Yes Yes Norway 1949 Yes Yes Sweden 1949 Yes Yes Austria 1950 Yes Yes Finland 1950 Yes Yes Israel 1950 Yes Yes Mexico 1950 No No Netherlands 1950 Yes Yes Collective Bargaining Convention United Kingdom 1950 Yes Yes Sweden 1950 Yes Yes Discrimination Convention Israel 1959 Yes Yes 13

References in Web-Appendices Ai, Chunrong, and Edward Norton. 2003. Interaction Terms in Logit and Probit Models. Economics Letters 80, no. 1: 123-129. Bolzendahl, Catherine. 2011. "Beyond the big picture: Gender influences on disaggregated and domain-specific measures of social spending, 1980 1999." Politics & Gender 7, no. 1: 35-70. Bratton, Kathleen A., and Kerry L. Haynie. 1999. "Agenda setting and legislative success in state legislatures: The effects of gender and race." Journal of Politics 61, No. 3: 658-679. Çali, Başak, Alice Wyss and Cristian Anton. 2009. Nominal Commitment to Human Rights: A Global Survey. London: UCL School of Public Policy. Elkins, Zachary, Andrew T. Guzman and Beth A. Simmons. 2006. Competing for Capital: The Diffusion of Bilateral Investment Treaties, 1960-2000. International Organization 60, no. 4: 811-46. Kittilson, Miki Caul. 2008. Representing Women: The Adoption of Family Leave in Comparative Perspective. Journal of Politics 70, no. 2: 323-334. Paxton, Pamela, Jennifer Green, and Melanie Hughes. 2008. Women in Parliament, 1945-2003: Cross-National Dataset [Computer file]. ICPSR24340-v1. Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor], 2008-12- 22. doi:10.3886/icpsr24340 Phillips, Anne. 1995. The Politics of Presence. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Polillo, Simone, and Mauro F. Guillén. 2005. Globalization Pressures and the State: The Worldwide Spread of Central Bank Independence. American Journal of Sociology 110, no. 6: 1764 1802. Schwindt Bayer, Leslie A. 2006. "Still supermadres? Gender and the policy priorities of Latin American legislators." American Journal of Political Science 50, no. 3: 570-585. Simmons, Beth A. 2009. Mobilizing for Human Rights: International Law in Domestic Politics. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. Swers, Michele L. 2002. The Difference Women Make: The Policy Impact of Women in Congress. Chicago: University of Chicago. 14

Thomas, Sue. 1991. The Impact of Women on State Legislative Policies. Journal of Politics 53, no. 4: 958 76. Wängnerud, Lena. 2000. "Testing the politics of presence: women s representation in the Swedish Riksdag." Scandinavian Political Studies 23, no. 1: 67-91. Wängnerud, Lena. 2009. Women in Parliaments: Descriptive and Substantive Representation. Annual Review of Political Science 12: 51 69. World Bank. 2012. World Development Indicators. Available at data.worldbank.org. 15