Conceptualizing Capitalism:

Similar documents
How Mythical Markets Mislead Analysis: An institutionalist critique of market universalism. Geoffrey M. Hodgson

Conceptualizing capitalism: A summary

Western Philosophy of Social Science

CONCEPTUALIZING CAPITALISM: SEMINAR WITH GEOFFREY HODGSON KONCEPTUALIZOVANJE KAPITALIZMA: SEMINAR SA DŽOFRI HODŽSONOM. Edited by Marjan Ivković

Social Science 1000: Study Questions. Part A: 50% - 50 Minutes

INDEPENDENT SCHOOL DISTRICT 196 Rosemount-Apple Valley-Eagan Public Schools Educating our students to reach their full potential

The Communist Manifesto: Annotations

Communism. Marx and Engels. The Communism Manifesto

(3) parliamentary democracy (2) ethnic rivalries

SOCIAL STUDIES GRADE 7. I Can Checklist Office of Teaching and Learning Curriculum Division

As Joseph Stiglitz sees matters, the euro suffers from a fatal. Book Review. The Euro: How a Common Currency. Journal of FALL 2017

The Three Great Thinkers Who Changed Economics

World History Semester B Study Guide Credit by Exam for Credit Recovery or Acceleration

When Thomas Piketty s Capital in the 21 st Century was published. Book Review. Anti-Piketty: Capital for the 21 st Century. Quarterly Journal of

The State, the Market, And Development. Joseph E. Stiglitz World Institute for Development Economics Research September 2015

Essential Question: How did both the government and workers themselves try to improve workers lives?

James M. Buchanan The Limits of Market Efficiency

COMPARATIVE ECONOMIC SYSTEMS: PAST, PRESENT, AND FUTURE BEFORE YOU BEGIN

Define, significance, source [author & title of book/article], example

Summary The Beginnings of Industrialization KEY IDEA The Industrial Revolution started in Great Britain and soon spread elsewhere.

The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time. By Karl Polayni. Boston: Beacon Press, 2001 [1944], 317 pp. $24.00.

Assembly Line For the first time, Henry Ford s entire Highland Park, Michigan automobile factory is run on a continuously moving assembly line when

25.4 Reforming the Industrial World. The Industrial Revolution leads to economic, social, and political reforms.

ECONOMIC GROWTH* Chapt er. Key Concepts

LECTURE 5: CLASSICAL POLITICAL ECONOMY. Dr. Aidan Regan Website: Twitter: #CapitalUCD

3. Which region had not yet industrialized in any significant way by the end of the nineteenth century? a. b) Japan Incorrect. The answer is c. By c.

Thomas Piketty Capital in the 21st Century

Soci250 Sociological Theory

The Beginnings of Industrialization

Introducing Marxist Theories of the State

Gordon Tullock and Karl Popper: Their Correspondence

Political Economy of. Post-Communism

13 Arguments for Liberal Capitalism in 13 Minutes

Dependency theorists, or dependentistas, are a group of thinkers in the neo-marxist tradition mostly

Unit 9 Industrial Revolution

Lecture 2: The Capitalist Revolution

Magruder s American Government

EMES Position Paper on The Social Business Initiative Communication

Political Science The Political Theory of Capitalism Fall 2015

George R. Boyer Professor of Economics and ICL ILR School, Cornell University

Starting in England around 1750, the introduction of new

CURRICULUM CATALOG. World History from the Age of Enlightenment to the Present (450835)

Radical Equality as the Purpose of Political Economy. The ruling ideas of each age have ever been the ideas of its ruling class.

Rethinking critical realism: Labour markets or capitalism?

Standards Social Studies Grades K-12 Mille Lacs Indian Museum

Business Ethics Concepts & Cases

The uses and abuses of evolutionary theory in political science: a reply to Allan McConnell and Keith Dowding

Planning Activity. Theme 1

The Three Great Thinkers Who Changed Economics

AP EUROPEAN SURVIVAL GUIDE

1. The Pennsylvania state constitution of 1776 created a(n) legislature and, overall, the most democratic government in America and Europe.

Econ Modern European Economic History John Lovett. Part 1: (70 points. Answer on this paper. 2.0 pts each unless noted.)

Classical Political Economy. Part III. D. Ricardo

Remarks on the Political Economy of Inequality

A Critique on the Social Justice Perspectives in the Works of Friedrich A. Hayek

Ch. 15: The Industrial Revolution

Labor Unions and Reform Laws

Adam Habib (2013) South Africa s Suspended Revolution: hopes and prospects. Johannesburg: Wits University Press

In a core chapter in their book, Unequal Gains: American Growth. Journal of SUMMER Mark Thornton VOL. 21 N O

World History (Survey) Chapter 22: Enlightenment and Revolution,

Period V ( ): Industrialization and Global Integration

The Three Great Thinkers Who Changed Economics

PHILOSOPHY OF ECONOMICS & POLITICS

Book Review: The Street Porter and the Philosopher: Conversations on Analytical Egalitarianism

Subverting the Orthodoxy

Marx s unfinished Critique of Political Economy and its different receptions. Michael Heinrich July 2018

PHILOSOPHY OF ECONOMICS & POLITICS

The character of the crisis: Seeking a way-out for the social majority

FRED S. MCCHESNEY, Northwestern University, Chicago, IL 60611, U.S.A.

Late pre-classical economics (ca ) Mercantilism (16th 18th centuries) Physiocracy (ca ca. 1789)

Social fairness and justice in the perspective of modernization

Groveport Madison Local School District Seventh Grade Social Studies Content Standards Planning Sheets

Course Title. Professor. Contact Information

KARL MARX AND HIS IDEAS ABOUT INEQUALITY

Big Data and Super-Computers: foundations of Cyber Communism

Economic Sociology I Fall Kenneth Boulding, The Role of Mathematics in Economics, JPE, 56 (3) 1948: 199

Classics of Political Economy POLS 1415 Spring 2013

CH 17: The European Moment in World History, Revolutions in Industry,

Book reviews on global economy and geopolitical readings. ESADEgeo, under the supervision of Professor Javier Solana and Professor Javier Santiso.

THE FINANCIAL INSTABILITY HYPOTHESIS AS AN INSTITUTIONALIST/EVOLUTIONARY THEORY. Levy Institute Minsky Summer School, June 19-26, 2010

Book Review: Centeno. M. A. and Cohen. J. N. (2010), Global Capitalism: A Sociological Perspective

Economic Assistance to Russia: Ineffectual, Politicized, and Corrupt?

Economics 555 Potential Exam Questions

TWO DIFFERENT IDEAS OF FREEDOM: DEMOCRACY IN THE HISTORICAL CONTEXT OF GREEK POLEIS AND FREEDOM OF MODERN TIMES

INFORMATION, SOCIAL RELATIONS AND THE ECONOMICS OF HIGH TECHNOLOGY

TEKS 8C: Calculate percent composition and empirical and molecular formulas. Enlightenment Philosophy

POLI 111: INTRODUCTION TO THE STUDY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE

College of Arts and Sciences. Political Science

It is a great honor and a pleasure to be the inaugural Upton Scholar. During

Graduate School of Political Economy Dongseo University Master Degree Course List and Course Descriptions

Name: Global 10 Section. Global Regents Pack #10. Turning Points

Feminist Critique of Joseph Stiglitz s Approach to the Problems of Global Capitalism

Karl Marx ( )

Economic Freedom and Mass Migration: Evidence from Israel

and government interventions, and explain how they represent contrasting political choices

CHAPTER 2: SECTION 1. Economic Systems

The Industrial Revolution Beginnings. Ways of the World Strayer Chapter 18

Section 5-1: Forms of Government

Executive Summary. International mobility of human resources in science and technology is of growing importance

Economic Systems and the United States

Transcription:

Conceptualizing Capitalism: How the Misuse of Key Concepts Impedes our Understanding of Modern Economies Geoffrey M. HODGSON One the most commonly used concepts in modern humanities and social sciences, capitalism is also one of the most misunderstood. Away from politically biased takes on the subject, Geoffrey M. Hodgson proposes a new, law-based framework for understanding capitalism. Something happened in the eighteenth century to stimulate an unprecedented explosion in economic productivity. Around 1800, GDP per capita began to take off in Europe, and accelerated further upwards. In 2003 Western European GDP per capita was about twenty times larger than it was in 1700. World GDP per capita in 2003 was about eleven times larger than it was in 1700. In less than half the time, US GDP per capita in 2003 was about twelve times greater than it was in 1870 1. As a result of technological developments in medicine and the improved average standard of living, between 1800 and 2000 life expectancy at birth rose from a global average of about thirty years to sixty-seven years, and to more than seventy-five years in several developed countries. At the same time, global growth since 1700 has seen a widening gap between rich and poor nations. What name do we give to the economic system that became prominent in the eighteenth century and led to such huge rises in productivity? We have no better term than capitalism especially as the new system was driven by developments in finance and the borrowing and investment of money capital. What changes led to an unprecedented explosion in production, innovation, and human longevity? Many argue that technology explains the take-off in output. To be sure, technology was a necessary condition of much progress, and many increases in productivity have resulted from new technologies from steam engines to modern electronics. But technological change also requires explanation. What were the necessary conditions for the development and diffusion of these new technologies? Property rights were necessary to provide incentives, and finance was required to purchase materials and labour power. There had to be networked communities of scientists and engineers, to scrutinize, share, and develop ideas. These communities required political conditions allowing relatively free and open enquiry, with the uncensored publication of much 1 This essay draws on material from the author s new book Conceptualizing Capitalism: Institutions, Evolution, Future (University of Chicago Press, forthcoming 2015). This book won the 2014 Schumpeter Prize, awarded by the International Joseph A. Schumpeter Association. 1

scientific information. Addressing these necessary conditions, we are brought back to the role of institutions. Both technology and institutions must be part of the explanation of the growth explosion, along with the ideas that were developed and fostered in the changing circumstances. A key task then is to identify the key institutions that developed in the eighteenth century and led to a huge increase in productivity. If we call the new era capitalism, then what definition of capitalism does this imply? Re-assessing traditional definitions of capitalism Several dictionaries define capitalism simply as a system involving markets and private property. But these institutions have existed for thousands of years. Trade between tribes has existed for tens of thousands of years. Private property developed fully when legal systems in early civilizations codified rights of individual ownership and contract. If markets are defined more narrowly than trade or exchange, involving a public space where goods or services are recurrently exchanged, then we have evidence of markets (from the Bible and from Herodotus) located in Greece and the Middle East, dated to the sixth century BC. A Chinese former student of mine (Xueqi Zhang) found documentary evidence of organized markets in China about 3000 years BC. Consequently, if we define capitalism simply as private property and markets and even if we define those terms sharply, to mean property buttressed by a legal system (and not mere possession) and markets as organized forums of exchange (and not mere trade in general) then capitalism has existed for up to five thousand years and was well established in ancient Greece, Rome and China. Some things must be added to the definition of capitalism to make it correspond more closely to the system that emerged in the eighteenth century. But before we discuss these additions we can already detect the terminological problems that confound our understanding of capitalism. We need to be careful when using basic terms such as property and market. Many economists including the anti-capitalist Karl Marx and the pro-market Ludwig von Mises have defined property simply in terms of use or control of an asset, neglecting the question of legally-sanctioned ownership rights. Other economists, such as the Nobel laureates Ronald Coase and Douglass North, wrote of markets for ideas or political markets, overlooking that in these so-called markets there is no property being traded. The widespread misuse and over-extension of basic terms impedes our understanding. More careful definitions are required. What additional institutional criteria are needed to define capitalism? Marx argued that the employment contract was part of its essence. In the first volume of Capital, Marx dated the rise of wage labour and employment to England in the sixteenth century. But agricultural wage labour was well established in England two centuries earlier. Neither date locates in the seventeenth century, just before the take-off of capitalism. While widespread wage-labour is a distinctive and familiar feature of capitalism, its diffusion was too early to explain the great burst of productivity that accompanied the Industrial Revolution. Daron Acemoglu, Douglass North, Mancur Olson, Barry Weingast and other contemporary institutional economists have claimed that capitalism depends upon secure property rights and allegedly it took off historically when they were established in the political settlement following the British Glorious Revolution of 1688. The problem here is that property rights were relatively secure in England as early as the twelfth century, when a sophisticated legal - 2 -

system emerged following the reforms of Henry II. While some English kings infamously seized property or defaulted on debts or contracts, these were relatively isolated events. Prior to 1688, a key impediment to the rise of capitalism in England was not the lack of property rights as such, but the feudal nature of an extensive system of well-established ownership rights, enjoying the support of powerful interest groups. Complex feudal obligations impeded the commodification of land and other property. The removal of these feudal restrictions was a long process, beginning before 1688 and continuing long afterwards, with the most extensive reforming activity after 1750. The 1688-focused argument concerning property rights falls down on matters of historical detail. Joseph Schumpeter promoted a different argument. In a footnote to his History of Economic Analysis he wrote: Owing to the importance of the financial complement of capitalist production and trade, the development of the law and the practice of negotiable paper and of created deposits afford perhaps the best indication we have for dating the rise of capitalism. Hence Schumpeter identified the development of a financial system as a key feature in the birth of the capitalist system proper. In particular he identified the emergence of a banking system involving negotiable instruments and the buying and selling of debt. The neglected British economist Henry Dunning MacLeod wrote in his Principles of Economic Philosophy (1872): If we were asked Who made the discovery which has most deeply affected the fortunes of the human race? We think, after full consideration, we might safely answer The man who first discovered that a Debt is a Saleable Commodity. This prompts us to search for the key institutional changes that enabled the buying and selling of debt. The idea of selling debt was originally an anathema: debt is not a good or service but a promise. Exchanges of promissory notes involve the purchase of a promise, and originally this was not recognized as a valid contract in law: the selling of debt was not sanctioned by legal recognition of the transfer of the obligation to its purchaser. Major legislative changes were necessary to make this possible. In the seventeenth century, the failure of common law courts to deal adequately with the negotiability of debt led businessmen to press Parliament for robust legislation. In 1704, during the reign of Queen Anne, Parliament passed An Act for giving like Remedy upon Promissory Notes, as is now used upon Bills of Exchange, and for the better Payment of Inland Bills of Exchange. Significant further legislation, including another Act as late as 1758, was required to consolidate negotiability. Once negotiability was established, the capitalist financial genie was out of the bottle. These changes in the eighteenth century were part of what historians such as Peter Dickson Stephen Epstein, Henry Roseveare, Carl Wennerlind and others have described as the Financial Revolution. This took place in the decades after the new political settlement after 1688. It was in part prompted by the state and its dependence on the private banking system to help finance the Nine Years War (1688-97) and the War of Spanish Succession (1701-13). During this period the state administration was reformed, mainly to meet the needs of war. Financial reforms continued well into the eighteenth century, preparing the ground for the Industrial Revolution. - 3 -

Re-affirming the role of financial institutions In my book Conceptualizing Capitalism I propose a definition of capitalism that includes private property, widespread markets, widespread employment contracts and developed financial institutions. The latter item is included for the reasons given above capitalism is above all a system based on finance. The development of financial institutions was crucial to its birth and take-off. Widespread employment contracts are included in the definition not because they mark the beginning of capitalism as Marx wrongly suggested but because their possible future replacement by widespread self-employment or worker cooperatives would change the system into something quite different. My claim that the rise of sophisticated financial institutions marks the dawn of capitalism is not original, but why have so many economists and historians (including Marx) downplayed these vital developments? A major part of the answer lies in the metaphors that economists and others have used to frame their basic concepts and understandings of key elements in the system. These problems were evident in Adam Smith s classic book on The Wealth of Nations (1776). Inspired by developments in astronomy and physics, Smith made extensive use of mechanical and physical metaphors. In business usage, then and now, the term capital means money held or invested, or the money value of other assets on the balance sheet of an individual or firm. But Smith changed the meaning of capital from money or money value, to the assets themselves. Capital became a physical force or thing including machines and labour rather than a monetary asset. This change of meaning has pervaded economics ever since and has spread into sociology with mutated terms such as social capital. But social capital cannot be readily owned, valued, sold or used as collateral. It is thus highly remote from the stillprevailing business meaning of capital as money or the money-value of owned assets. In all the discussion of Thomas Piketty s celebrated book on Capital in the Twenty-First Century it has been rarely noted that he abandoned all these perversions of the term capital and reverted to its proper meaning of money or monetizable assets. On this basis we can see that the concentrated distribution of collateralizable assets is a major generator of further inequality within capitalism. Economists and other social scientists often think of property as a thing, rather than a legally-sanctioned right to a thing. Marx was reluctant to emphasise the crucial role of the legal system because her saw it as part of the superstructure rather than of the economic structure the real foundation. But he never defined these terms clearly. His relegation of law was partly inspired by an architectural and physical metaphor. Other social scientists downplay the role of state law because they want categories such as property and exchange to apply to all human existence since the birth of our species. Accordingly, custom is misleadingly identified as law, even in the absence of an institutionalised judiciary or legislature. Property is treated as primarily a matter or possession or control. The economic analysis of these miss-labelled property rights may bring insights on how people control assets in the absence of a developed legal system, but it is inadequate to deal with the mechanisms of authority, legitimation and legal control in modern, largescale, complex economies. Consequently, the understanding of the modern system that we describe as capitalism requires a new approach to analysis that differs from much found in economics, sociology and Marxist theory. The underlying physical metaphors of things and forces are replaced by the - 4 -

notion of an economy as an evolving, information-processing system. This system entails the generation, allocation and exchange of recognised legal rights over many kinds of asset. Because of its focus on historically specific institutions such as law, property and finance, this analysis is not intended to cover all types of economic system. Far from being a weakness, such a historical focus can strengthen such a theory and give it greater analytical power. Marx s analysis of capitalism was historically specific but flawed in its reliance on physical metaphors and its neglect of its legal foundations. Much of mainstream economics and mainstream sociology also downplays the role of law, and furthermore attempts to be universal rather than historically specific. Legal institutionalism and the rise of modern economy The proposed new approach to the analysis of capitalism can be described as legal institutionalism. It puts legal institutions and relations at the centre, seeing them as a major source of power in modern society. Among others, this approach is influenced by Marx on the question of historical specificity, by Schumpeter in regard to the central role of finance, by Friedrich Hayek on the understanding of markets as information-processing systems, and by the American institutionalist John R. Commons with respect to the foundational and constitutive role of law. The approach of legal institutionalism is primarily analytic rather than normative, but it does illuminate some particular policy perspectives. First, because information is dispersed and hugely varied in large-scale complex economies, markets are unavoidable and the classical socialist vision of wholesale collective planning is ruled out. But post-capitalist possibilities exist through the supersession of the employment relationship by selfemployment or worker cooperatives. Second, the emphasis on the legal foundation of basic capitalist institutions, in regard to property, contract, firms and finance, suggests that the construction of effective and relatively incorrupt legal institutions is important for developing countries. While all laws depend on customary support and on acknowledgement of authority, it is unrealistic to expect that these arrangements will evolve spontaneously, apart from the intervention of the state apparatus. Historically this has never happened in large-scale, complex, modern economies. Third, because complete futures markets for labour power are ruled out by the abolition of slavery and the adoption of employment contracts, capitalism always has missing markets. The theory of general equilibrium with missing markets tells us that in such a system a market equilibrium may be Pareto suboptimal. Furthermore, when markets are incomplete, opening new markets may make things worse rather than better. Fourth, the primary mechanism for the extension of inequalities in income and wealth is identified as the concentration of ownership of collateralisable assets in the hands of a minority of the population. Unlike the owners of labour power, the owners of capital goods and monetary assets can use their property to borrow more money, and make still more. This puts policies to alleviate inequality at the top of the agenda. Among both opponents and critics, few appreciate that capitalism cannot in principle be a 100 percent market system, no matter how far it tries to move in that direction. By pushing back slavery and widening wage-labor, capitalism limited markets at its core: it disallowed complete futures markets for labor power. Capitalism inescapably implies limits to the scope of markets and commodity exchange. - 5 -

The birth of capitalism was stimulated by Enlightenment ideas of individual liberty and equality under the law. But rightly we lack the liberties to enslave others, trade in slaves, or enslave ourselves. We have equal legal rights to use property to produce more wealth. But the owner of labor power is placed at two indelible disadvantages, compared with the owner of non-labor assets. Because of the ban on slavery, the individual cannot be used as collateral for obtaining loans, and cannot separate himself or herself from the deployment of his or her labor in production. These are systemic limitations to the Enlightenment principles of liberty and equality that are embedded in capitalism at its core. Books&Ideas.net, May 7, 2015 booksandideas.net - 6 -