When do legislators pass on pork?

Similar documents
Acentral challenge in political economy is to identify the conditions under which legislators seek

When do legislators pass on pork?

Publicizing malfeasance:

Vote Buying and Clientelism

USING MULTI-MEMBER-DISTRICT ELECTIONS TO ESTIMATE THE SOURCES OF THE INCUMBENCY ADVANTAGE 1

Gerrymandering Decentralization: Political Selection of Grants Financed Local Jurisdictions Stuti Khemani Development Research Group The World Bank

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Subhasish Dey, University of York Kunal Sen,University of Manchester & UNU-WIDER NDCDE, 2018, UNU-WIDER, Helsinki 12 th June 2018

BJP s Demographic Dividend in the 2014 General Elections: An Empirical Analysis ±

Electoral competition and corruption: Theory and evidence from India

Does Political Competition Reduce Ethnic Discrimination?

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative. Electoral Incentives

All democracies are not the same: Identifying the institutions that matter for growth and convergence

PANCHAYATI RAJ AND POVERTY ALLEVIATION IN WEST BENGAL: SUMMARY OF RESEARCH FINDINGS. Pranab Bardhan and Dilip Mookherjee.

Executive Summary. 1 Page

Are Female Leaders Good for Education? Evidence from India.

Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents

Response to the Report Evaluation of Edison/Mitofsky Election System

The Distortionary Effects of Power Sharing on Political Corruption and Accountability: Evidence from Kenya

An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature. Abstract

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy

Chapter 6 Political Parties

Incumbents, Challengers and Electoral Risk

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

Political Selection and Bureaucratic Productivity

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS

Does Political Reservation Affect Voting Behavior? Empirical Evidence from India

Political Budget Cycles and the Organization of Political Parties

Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India

A Tale of Two Villages

United States House Elections Post-Citizens United: The Influence of Unbridled Spending

Chapter- 5 Political Parties. Prepared by - Sudiksha Pabbi

Democratization and clientelism: Why are young democracies badly governed?

Election Outcomes and Food Security: Evidence from the. Consumption of Scheduled Castes and Tribes in India. Sharad Tandon.

! # % & ( ) ) ) ) ) +,. / 0 1 # ) 2 3 % ( &4& 58 9 : ) & ;; &4& ;;8;

Ohio State University

Does political turnover adversely affect the state. expenditure policy? Evidence from Indian state. legislative elections

Luck of the Draw? Members Bills, the Electoral Connection & Party List Placement

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

Corrupt States: Reforming Indian Public Services in the Digital Age

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means

SHORT ANSWER TYPE QUESTIONS [3 MARKS]

The Ethnicity Distraction?

Prologue Djankov et al. (2002) Reinikka & Svensson (2004) Besley & Burgess (2002) Epilogue. Media and Policy. Dr. Kumar Aniket

Federal Politics and Budget Deficits: Evidence from the states of India

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference?

Information and Wasted Votes: A Study of U.S. Primary Elections

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design.

Rural America Competitive Bush Problems and Economic Stress Put Rural America in play in 2008

Congressional Gridlock: The Effects of the Master Lever

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Electoral Threshold, Representation, and Parties Incentives to Form a Bloc.

Incumbency Effects and the Strength of Party Preferences: Evidence from Multiparty Elections in the United Kingdom

Retrospective Voting

By Any Means Necessary: Multiple Avenues of Political Cycles

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997)

Randall S. Kroszner Graduate School of Business University of Chicago Chicago, IL and N.B.E.R. and

Do formula-based intergovernmental transfer mechanisms eliminate politically motivated targeting? Evidence from Ghana

SPEECH BY SHRI NAVIN B.CHAWLA AS ELECTION COMMISSIONER OF INDIA

A Vote Equation and the 2004 Election

INDIAN SCHOOL MUSCAT SENIOR SECTION DEPARTMENT OF SOCIAL SCIENCE CLASS: IX: DEMOCRATIC POLITICS CHAPTER: 4- ELECTORAL POLITICS WORKSHEET - 11

Wisconsin Economic Scorecard

Efficiency Consequences of Affirmative Action in Politics Evidence from India

Distributive Politics, Presidential Particularism, and War

From Banerjee and Iyer (2005)

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

The Robustness of Herrera, Levine and Martinelli s Policy platforms, campaign spending and voter participation

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

Columbia University. Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series

Does opportunism pay off?

Reading the local runes:

Support for Peaceable Franchise Extension: Evidence from Japanese Attitude to Demeny Voting. August Very Preliminary

Do Criminal Politicians affect Firm Investment and Value? Evidence from a Regression Discontinuity Approach* Vikram Nanda a, Ankur Pareek b

2017 CAMPAIGN FINANCE REPORT

Voting for Parties or for Candidates: Do Electoral Institutions Make a Difference?

Journal of Public Economics

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

In The Supreme Court of the United States

Forecasting the 2018 Midterm Election using National Polls and District Information

Do Elections Select for Better Representatives?

Measuring the Shadow Economy of Bangladesh, India, Pakistan, and Sri Lanka ( )

Introduction to the declination function for gerrymanders

An Increased Incumbency Effect: Reconsidering Evidence

Coattails and the Forces that Drive Them: Evidence from Mexico

Economics 270c. Development Economics. Lecture 6 February 20, 2007

Case Study: Get out the Vote

STRENGTHENING POLICY INSTITUTES IN MYANMAR

Who Would Have Won Florida If the Recount Had Finished? 1

Internal and international remittances in India: Implications for Household Expenditure and Poverty

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One

Julie Lenggenhager. The "Ideal" Female Candidate

Patterns of Poll Movement *

Understanding the Party Brand: Experimental Evidence on the Role of Valence. September 24, 2013

Testimony of FairVote The Center for Voting and Democracy Jack Santucci, Program for Representative Government. October 16, 2006

Transcription:

When do legislators pass on pork? The Role of Political Parties in Determining Legislator Effort Philip Keefer and Stuti Khemani Development Research Group The World Bank pkeefer@worldbank.org and skhemani@worldbank.org May 21, 2008 Abstract: A central challenge in political economy is to identify the conditions under which legislators seek to bring home the pork to constituents. We conduct the first systematic analysis of one determinant of constituency service, voter attachment to political parties, holding constant electoral and political institutions. Our analysis takes advantage of data from a unique type of public spending program that is proliferating across developing countries, the constituency development fund (CDF), which offers more precise measures of legislator effort than are common in the literature. Examining the CDF in India, we find that legislator effort is significantly lower in constituencies that are party strongholds. This result, which is robust to controls for alternate explanations, implies that legislators pass on pork when voters are more attached to political parties. It has implications not only for understanding political incentives and the dynamics of party formation, but also for evaluating the impact of CDFs. Acknowledgements: This paper has benefited greatly from the comments of Pradeep Chhibber, Herbert Kitschelt, Steven Wilkinson, and Adam Ziegfeld. We also thank seminar participants at New York University, the University of California Berkeley, Annual Meetings of the American Political Science Association, Chicago, the National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, and the Centre for Policy Research, New Delhi. We thank Rohini Somanathan for sharing valuable data. We are very grateful for the expert assistance of Victor Macías. We thank the Knowledge for Change Program for the funding that enabled this work. Disclaimer: The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors, and do not necessarily represent the views of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent.

2 1. Introduction The puzzle of pork-barrel policies has long pre-occupied scholars (Ferejohn, 1974; Weingast et al, 1981; Baron and Ferejohn, 1987; Carey and Shugart, 1995; Ames 1995; Cox and McCubbins, 1993; Lizzeri and Persico, 2001; Persson and Tabellini, 2000). Why do individual politicians or legislators persistently target public spending to specific projects in their constituencies to win elections or to gain rents, often when those same resources could deliver greater welfare benefits when targeted more broadly, in the form of public goods? A related literature has analyzed legislator efforts to perform constituency services to build a personal vote, arguing that such effort is an important determinant of observed incumbency advantage (Cain, Ferejohn, and Fiorina, 1987; Fiorina and Rivers, 1989; King, 1991; Levitt and Snyder, 1997). Research in these areas generally focuses on the influence of institutions, investigating, for example, the influence of voting rules or the form of government on legislator incentives to provide constituent services or pork. The effect of political parties on legislator behavior is not closely examined except insofar as institutions affect the relationship between parties and party legislators. Our analysis is the first to show that voter attachment to political parties curbs legislator incentives to provide pork to their constituents, even in a setting where legislators operate within identical institutions. 1 1 Cain, Ferejohn and Fiorina (1987) argue that constituency service is less pronounced in Great Britain than in the United States because parties are stronger in parliamentary than in presidential systems. Carey and Shugart (1995) and Cox and McCubbins (1993) similarly make institutional arguments that work through the channel of political parties in making predictions about constituency service, but do not analyze the influence of parties independent of the institutional setting.

3 There are at least two significant reasons to investigate the role of voter attachment to parties on constituency service or pork, independent of the institutional environment. First, voter attachment changes the electoral benefits to legislators of constituent service. Ashworth and Bueno de Mesquita (2006) derive this prediction directly from a model in which voters have preferences over both legislator action and the policy program of the legislator s party, and, for any given set of preferences, seek to elect candidates of high ability to deliver public goods and constituency service. Ability, however, is difficult for voters to observe, and incumbent legislators can only use constituency service to signal high ability. Where voter preferences for a particular party s platform are great, however, the evaluation of incumbent ability matters less in voters re-election decision, and incumbent incentives to provide constituent service correspondingly fall. Second, voter attachment reduces party leader incentives to choose candidates who prefer constituent service or candidates who, more than their challengers, can credibly promise constituency services to a large fraction of constituency voters. For example, a central problem in the growing literature on political party formation (e.g., Aldrich, 1995; Caillaud and Tirole, 2002; Snyder and Ting, 2002; Levy, 2004; and Morelli, 2004) is the ability of political parties to credibly project a policy program to voters when the policy preferences of party candidates are heterogeneous. Where voter attachment to the party is high (e.g., when constituency voters strongly prefer a party s ideology), party leaders can choose candidates with policy preferences, including preferences over constituency service, that are further from the constituency s and closer to the party s. However, there is no systematic empirical evidence on the influence of parties on candidate incentives to form personal constituencies. Our analysis is the first systematic test of the effect of party influence on legislators decisions to provide pork or constituent service and strongly

4 demonstrates that greater voter attachment to a political party reduces these. The tests here are based on a constituency development fund (CDF), a specific type of public spending program that India, Kenya, the Philippines and other developing countries have adopted. CDFs allocate budgetary resources directly to individual legislators to spend on public works in their constituencies. The data for this analysis are from the Indian CDF, the Member of Parliament Local Area Development Scheme (MPLADS). Using a measure of voter attachment based on whether constituencies are party strongholds or not, we find robust evidence that legislators substantially reduce effort to provide public works to their constituents when their constituency is a party stronghold. This directly demonstrates that voter attachment to parties reduces legislator incentives to cultivate a personal vote that in the presence of strong parties, even legislators in single member constituencies, electoral institutions that give legislators strong incentives to attract a personal vote, nevertheless often pass on pork. Past efforts to examine legislator effort have relied on measures of legislator output as proxies for unobserved effort. These measures are generally unable to distinguish between beneficiaries of the output, and do not easily capture the degree to which output is due to effort rather than other factors. Our analysis of data from legislator usage of constituency development funds avoids these disadvantages and makes a methodological improvement over existing research on legislator behavior. The next section of the paper describes the specific CDF program in India and explains why disbursements under the program should accurately represent legislator effort on behalf of their local constituency. Section 3 lists the conditions under which legislators have weak incentives to exert such effort, yielding tests for the influence of political parties. We then perform these tests using available data on spending under the CDF program.

5 Section 4 describes the data and specifications we use to examine cross-constituency variation in spending from 1999 onwards, and sections 5 and 6 present the main results and a discussion of robustness. Section 7 concludes by describing the implications of the analysis for the spread of CDF schemes and directions for future research. 2. Measuring constituency service: The MPLADS Program Since legislator effort is not directly observable, scholars use various proxies to identify the effort of legislators to direct benefits to their districts. None of these measures comes as close as the MPLADS data to meeting the two conditions of the ideal proxy: that the measure be uniquely attributed to the legislator s effort, and that it be associated with benefits that flow uniquely to the legislator s constituents. For example, Heitshusen et al (2005) analyze determinants of legislators subjective assessments of their own priorities for constituency service; these need not be strongly correlated with actual provision of benefits to constituents or with actual effort exerted by legislators. Stratmann and Baur (2002) examine committee membership of legislators and characterize some committees as better enabling legislators to provide geographically targeted benefits. Shiller (1995) and Wawro (2002) consider the number and relevance of bills that American legislators sponsor. Padro i Miguel and Snyder (2004) rely on subjective assessments of legislator performance by third parties (journalists, for example). Committee membership, the number of bills introduced and subjective evaluations are all useful measures of legislator activity, but unlike MPLADS they do not directly identify the beneficiaries or the benefits of legislator effort. Many studies use correlations between legislator voting behavior and ownconstituency spending as evidence of legislator incentives for pork-barrel spending (e.g., Knight, 2004; Ames, 1995; Baqir, 2002). However, even in the apparently most

6 straightforward case, omnibus pork barrel legislation with constituency-specific benefits in a country with single member electoral districts, although benefits can be precisely measured, a wide array of unobserved factors make it difficult to attribute differences in benefits to the actions of an individual legislator. For example, apparent budget shortfalls to a constituency in one piece of legislation may have been compensated in other, unobserved legislation. Unobserved factors also influence executive implementation of legislative priorities. The design of the MPLADS program in India fortuitously avoids the shortcomings of other measures of legislator effort. The scheme was inaugurated in December 1993 by a dominant national party, the Congress Party. It allocated 10 million rupees annually (about $250,000) to each single-member parliamentary constituency for use on local public works recommended by the MP. In fiscal year 1998, the Bharatiya Janata Party (BJP)-controlled national government doubled the annual entitlement of each constituency to 20 million rupees. 2 Unspent money accumulates over time, such that when an MP leaves office the unspent balance remains at the disposal of the successor MP. By March 2004, the end of fiscal year 2003 in India, each parliamentary constituency had thus been entitled to spend 165 million rupees on local public works over the preceding ten years. 3 The MPLADS program is unique in the degree to which it can isolate the contribution of a legislator s own efforts to constituency-specific benefits. First, the amounts available to spend are independent of legislator effort and are identical across legislators in 2 Current, purchasing power parity-adjusted income per capita in 2004 was 7.2 times higher in the United States than in India. In the U.S. context, therefore, these allocations would be equivalent to approximately $1.4 million annually before 1998 and $2.8 million annually after 1998. 3 Again, in terms of purchasing power parity in 2004, this money per district would amount to about $23 million in the US.

7 other measures of legislator effort, the effort that legislators could have undertaken is generally unobserved. Second, spending on public works under the program must be initiated by the legislator, acting alone, and is identified with the legislator s name through information placards located at the project site. Third, the MPLADS program is unique in allowing national legislators access to local public works for which they can take credit. Beyond this CDF program, national legislators in India have to work through their party to access large public works programs that spread benefits across constituencies. 4 Fourth, however, successful initiation of such public works by legislators does require substantial effort on their part. 5 Legislators must identify multiple small or mid-size projects because of size limits on any one project; they also need to negotiate implementation with local bureaucrats, who have considerable power either to reject the project on grounds of nonconformity with project guidelines or to stall its implementation. 6 4 Indeed, Banerjee and Somanathan (2007) interpret evidence of convergence in public infrastructure across electoral districts in India over time as arising from the presence of a strong national political party that was successfully able to make a broad appeal across districts to deliver basic infrastructure everywhere. 5 The implementation procedures are available at the following web-site: http://mplads.nic.in/dpguid.htm 6 A telling anecdote on the challenges of getting projects implemented through local bureaucracies is provided in a study of MPLADS undertaken by the Planning Commission of India (2001). An MP from the state of Kerala recommended construction of additional classrooms to a rural high school on November 11, 1996. The concerned District Collector (DC) took 38 days to review and forward this proposal for estimate preparation to the relevant Block Development Officer (BDO). The BDO took 46 days to prepare the estimate and forward it to the District Rural Development Agency

8 Two pieces of evidence further support the argument that MPLADS disbursement requires legislators to exert effort. First, the report of the MPLADS audit conducted by the Comptroller and Auditor General, covering the period 1997-2000, showed that only 40 percent of projects recommended by MPs were subsequently sanctioned by District Commissioners (the top public officials in every district, an administrative unit in India that does not necessarily correspond to electoral constituencies), taken up by implementing agencies and completed. 7 Actual spending under MPLADS is a close approximation of project execution because the money is released against the issuance of completion certificates by the implementing agents. 8 Second, MP disbursements from the program were very low until a wave of publicity made voters aware of the program and MPs own disbursement record. Between the time of (DRADA) for approval. The DRDA provided its approval after 130 days. It then took the DC 250 days to formally provide administrative sanction to the work. The Block Level Beneficiary Committee which had to execute the work (because the Guidelines prohibit using professional contractors for MPLADS works) was constituted 220 days after the DC had sanctioned the work, by which time they declared the work could not be undertaken because the funds allotted were insufficient. 7 MPLADS expenditures were last audited in 2000, covering the period 1997-2000 and 241 out of 786 constituencies. The audit was critical and has not been repeated. See http://cag.nic.in/html/reports/civil/2001_book3a/index.htm 8 Although the audit report points to some irregularities in this, with money being released without proper collection of completion certificates, and even with such certificates it is possible that the money was diverted to things other than the intended works, getting their allocations recorded as spent requires considerable effort on the part of MPs.

9 the initiation of the MPLADS program in December 1993 and 1999, MPs left most of their allocation unutilized. MPLADS disbursements in the average and median districts amounted to approximately 31 million rupees, out of a total allocation of 85 million, or only 36 percent of the available funds. 9 The highest ranking district in utilization spent 78 percent, while the second highest ranked district spent only 57 percent. In a dramatic shift, by the end of the period 1999 2003, the median MP office had disbursed 85 percent of accumulated funds. All but 32 out of 543 increased their utilization of MPLADS by at least 20 percentage points; most increased it by more than 45 percentage points. We would not expect high spending in the early years of MPLADS if it required high effort, and if the program were not known to voters. In fact, MPLADS was introduced and approved almost surreptitiously, without parliamentary debate, as a supplementary demand for grants to pay for additional expenditures out of a Contingency Fund in the union budget (The Times of India, 30th November, 1997). The national ruling party, the Congress Party, did so at a time when it faced the loss of control of several state governments, a critical tier of government that the party had been using to deliver goods to voters to win their support. 10 Only legislators from the communist parties of the Left Front, a coalition of strong parties dominating the state of West Bengal, commented on the program at the time of its initiation, 9 The allocation up to March 2000 (end of fiscal year 1999) was Rs. 5 million in FY 1993 (through March 31, 1994); 10 million rupees each in 1994-95, 1995-96, 1996-97 and 1997-98; and 20 million rupees each in 1998-99 and 1990-2000. 10 Khemani (2007a, 2007b) provides evidence that the national government targets significant fiscal resources to states controlled by the same political party. Other authors have also emphasized the importance to the Congress Party of control of state governments as a key vehicle for reaching voters (Saez, 2002; Chhibber, 1995).

10 objecting to it on the grounds that MPLADS would be used by national parties to encroach upon the policy domain of lower tier governments (Inter Press Service Global Information Network, February 1, 1994). The timing and manner of program initiation, and these remarks from a political party with predominantly regional strength, suggests that MPLADS may have been conceived as a vehicle for the dominant national party to channel funds to its MPs in the growing number of states controlled by the opposition. 11 In sum, when MPLADS was initiated there appears to have been no political incentive to inform voters about the program as a means of constituency service by legislators. Correspondingly, there was also no coverage of the program in the media. A search on the media database News Plus/Factiva for newspaper coverage of the MPLADS program yields only 6 articles in the four and a half year period between October 1993, just before MPLADS was introduced in the parliament, and June 1998. Only one article, written in February 1994, discussed the program itself in any significant detail, with the others mentioning it only in passing as part of other stories. Even this single article was published in a less visible media, the Inter Press Service Global Information Network, rather than in a leading newspaper. In sum, the program was not widely politically salient for the first years after its initiation. The scenario changed suddenly in 1999 after the Comptroller and Auditor General (CAG) of India published a pilot audit of the MPLADS program in a few states 11 The MPLADS program appears to have been modeled after a similar program initiated by various state governments to provide constituency-specific allocations to state legislative assembly members (MLAs). The MLALADS can similarly have been a political response to declining control of political parties in state elections coalition governments of multiple political parties had become a constant feature of the state-level political landscape.

11 (Government of India, 1998). The CAG report revealed both lack of utilization of funds and some inconsistencies in the way funds were used. It concluded that guidelines needed to be revised for proper implementation and prevention of funds misuse. These findings fed a critical and newsworthy view of politician behavior. A search on News Plus/Factiva for the period July 1998 to December 1999 yields 60 articles: ten times as many articles were written in the 1.5 years following the CAG report than in the 4.5 years following the introduction of the program. Most of the articles were published in leading newspapers, focused on the issues raised in the CAG report, and made legislator accountability the key story. In response to the CAG report and possibly to the media coverage as well, the BJP-led government in 1999 instituted more stringent program implementation guidelines, including provisions for review and scrutiny by ministry authorities if funds are severely under-utilized (Business Line, 18 November, 1999). The publicity surrounding MPLADS, triggered by the CAG audit, significantly raised the political salience of MPLADS disbursements. The national elections of December 1999 ushered in a new cohort of MPs precisely during this period of increasing media coverage and political salience of MPLADS. Over the four years in office of this 1999-elected cohort, until the elections of June 2004, media coverage intensified, with the same News Plus/Factiva search producing 244 articles mentioning MPLADS. The utilization (nonutilization) of allocations was a major theme of this news coverage. The uniform rise in MPLADS spending across constituencies and the surge in media scrutiny accompanying this rise indicate that while legislators must exert non-trivial effort to implement the program, the electoral incentives of legislators, or the political incentives of parties in choosing which types of candidates to nominate, can still be sufficient for them to exert this effort. We have also found no evidence that MPLADS requires more effort than

12 other forms of constituent service. In particular, there is no indication that the effort required to deliver MPLADS relative to other types of constituency services is systematically and coincidentally higher in constituencies where political parties are dominant. Consequently, unobserved variation across legislators in their costs of delivering pork through other means should not affect the relationship between the effort that they exert in disbursing MPLADS allocations and the degree of party dominance that we investigate. 3. When do legislators pass on pork? Institutional determinants of constituency service and pork barrel policies have received the most attention in the literature: voting rules and regime type fix the electoral returns to legislators of building a personal constituency. Political parties have an effect on legislator behavior in this work, but their effect derives from the institutional environment. Our focus, in contrast, is on direct influence of political parties on constituent service, even when institutions are identical across legislators. Central to the pork barrel literature is the idea that voters can be more certain of a legislator s contribution to their welfare when it comes in the form of benefits that flow only to the legislator s constituency rather than benefits that flow to multiple constituencies and to which multiple legislators contribute. Less often articulated, but key to this rationale, is that constituency spending gives legislators an electoral advantage that challengers, for whatever reason, cannot match. In Ashworth and Bueno de Mesquita (2006), constituency service allows incumbents, but not challengers, to demonstrate their ability to voters. Voter preferences over candidates depend on the policy stance of the candidates party, the candidate s efforts in providing constituency service and public good provision, and the candidate s ability. However, voters can only infer ability from constituency service. In the most interesting case, where voters value public good provision more than constituency

13 service, legislators nevertheless persist in providing constituent services to demonstrate their ability. They predict that where the electorate overwhelmingly favors the policies of one political party, which are not affected by candidate ability, candidates have less incentive to dedicate effort to constituent service. Constituency service may also reflect tradeoffs in how party leaders select candidates to maximize chances of electoral success.. In the literature on political party formation (e.g., Aldrich, 1995; Caillaud and Tirole, 2002; Snyder and Ting, 2002; Levy, 2004; and Morelli, 2004), the policy platforms that parties can credibly project depend on the policy preferences of the party s candidates. In constituencies where voters are deeply attached to the party, party leaders can recruit candidates with policy preferences or other characteristics that assist the party in capturing votes in other constituencies (e.g., candidates who best represent the ideological stance of the party, candidates whom they seek to groom for a larger statewide or nationwide political career, or famous candidates movie stars, retired generals, etc.). In particular, they can do this even when these candidates are less favorable to constituency service than constituents would prefer. Candidate selection is also affected by the credibility of pre-electoral policy promises. For example, one implication of the analysis in Keefer and Vlaicu (forthcoming), though it is not about party-building specifically, is that in constituencies where parties cannot make credible promises to voters regarding either public goods or more narrowly targeted pork barrel policies, parties are more likely to seek out candidates who can make locally credible promises to provide pork or constituency service. 12 This leads to a policy bias in favor of 12 Keefer and Vlaicu (forthcoming) specifically analyze the conditions under which non-credible parties will choose to appeal to voters directly, or instead to channel their appeals through local patrons who can make credible promises regarding targeted transfers to their clients.

14 constituency service. However, when voters in the constituency are attached to the party for ideological or other reasons, party leaders can recruit candidates who might increase the party s vote share everywhere, perhaps by raising the credibility of its broad public good promises, even if those candidates are less able to make credible promises to local constituents regarding pork. The central hypothesis of the party building literature is therefore identical to that of the candidate ability model: when voter attachment to a party is high in a constituency, constituency service will decline. The key issue in testing this hypothesis is the measurement of voter attachment. In fact, four sources of voter attachment to parties can be found in Indian constituencies; all are consistent with the low incentives of individual legislators to build local public infrastructure identified in the foregoing discussion. One is identity: parties can credibly claim to defend the interests of a social class of voters (say, Hindus, or low-caste voters). Second, parties that can stake out credible ideological positions (e.g., to serve the interests of the poor), can also achieve dominance, independent of effort exerted on behalf of local constituents. The Communist Party in West Bengal or in Kerala has such appeal. Third, parties can also benefit from charisma: parties may have individual leaders and prominent candidates whose individual charisma attracts votes. Finally, fourth, voters can be attached to parties because they have a machine that reliably provides individual favors for party supporters (jobs, favorable treatment by the bureaucracy, etc.), independent of the state. We cannot definitively distinguish which of these matters across party strongholds in India. However, the effects of party dominance in reducing legislator effort are particularly

15 strong in, for example, West Bengal, where the dominance of the Communist Party can be explained by both its ideological appeal and its internal, "machine-like" organization. 13 There are no independent measures of constituency-level voter attachment to parties in India. 14 Our measure is the degree to which parties have won repeated elections in a constituency, irrespective of which candidate they nominate to the party s ticket. The best, though not the only explanation of why the same party persistently wins in a constituency, irrespective of the candidate they field, is that voters in the constituency are more strongly attached to the party compared to voters in other constituencies where the party is less successful. This is true regardless of the source of the attachment. It is also true regardless of whether voters are positively attached to the party or simply hostile to all of the party s competitors. One alternative explanation for party strongholds, other than voter attachment to the party, is that the successful party has chosen a popular candidate to nominate to the constituency ticket. If, in turn, the candidate s popularity is built on ascriptive (e.g., religious, ethnic or caste) or other appeals that are unrelated to local public works provision, low 13 Parties might also be dominant precisely because they have succeeded in providing large, national infrastructure projects. However, we control for measures of the total district stock of public infrastructure, such as schools, roads, power projects, and find these are not significantly correlated with spending under the CDF program. 14 For example, in the party identification literature, voter attachment is identified by survey results indicating how close voters say they are to particular parties. Although such questions began to be asked in the 1990s through small sample national exit polls at election times, there is no survey-based data on voter attachment at the level of the 483 electoral constituencies we examine.

16 MPLADS disbursements would be unrelated to party influence. However, we control for candidate dominance in the estimations below. Disproportionate voter attachment to a single party gives rise to apparently noncompetitive elections that is, party strongholds. However, elections may be noncompetitive for other reasons. It is possible, for example, that a party has enjoyed a string of favorable electoral shocks. This should not necessarily reduce political incentives to provide constituency service, though, since a positive shock in the current election does not affect the probability of such a shock in the next election. A string of favorable shocks is also unlikely, since the number of constituencies that are party strongholds is large and the favorable shocks would have had to occur in four successive elections. In any case, our results are robust to a control for electoral volatility. Elections may also be non-competitive because dominant parties use extrainstitutional means (vote-rigging, violence) to retain power. There is no evidence that party dominance is systematically associated with such extra institutional influences in India, however. On the contrary, party dominance is in fact less likely in those states in India most associated with such extra-institutional electoral influences, such as Bihar or Uttar Pradesh. 15 In any case, the potential for extra-institutional influence is most heavily determined by state-level characteristics, but our results are robust to state-level fixed effects. In addition, the use of extra-institutional measures to maintain party dominance could be associated with systematically larger majorities and a splintered opposition. However, in all our specifications we control for the electoral margin of victory (the difference in vote share between the winning and runner-up parties). 15 Only 8 percent of constituencies in Bihar, a state known for electoral violence, are party strongholds, compared to an average of 20 percent for all states.

17 The party stronghold measure also addresses an issue raised by Ashworth and Bueno de Mesquita (2006), that electoral results, such as proportion of votes won, are likely to be a noisy measure of partisan attachment because they are affected by numerous factors other than voter attachment to parties. Consistent with their observation, electoral margin of victory in our analysis is always insignificant. In contrast, our measure, the persistence of party dominance over several electoral cycles is more likely to be rooted in party attachment than victory in any one election. Moreover, our controls capture factors other than party attachment that might affect dominance. For example, Ashworth and Bueno de Mesquita single out incumbent advantage as a key confounding variable; we control for candidate dominance, however. In the next section of the paper we test the proposition that voter attachment to parties reduces MPLADS disbursements using cross-constituency data after 1999. We take advantage of the fact that, even after the dramatic rise in MPLADS disbursements following the increase in newspaper coverage, 30 percent of districts still had spent less than 75 percent of accumulated allocations by 2004, leaving at least $500,000 of their entitlement unspent. There was also much more variation across the 543 districts after 1999: the standard deviation of utilization rates of accumulated funds across districts increased from 9 percentage points before 1999 to 16 percentage points afterwards. In the state of West Bengal, MPs left 40 percent unspent; in Tamil Nadu, only 6 percent. 4 Cross-constituency variation in MPLADS spending: Data and specifications The MPLADS spending data is available from the relevant central ministry responsible for overseeing its implementation. The first available data point is for cumulative spending incurred in each parliamentary district since the inception of the program in 1993

18 until March 31 st, 2000 (the end of fiscal year 1999). 16 Three different cohorts of MPs had access to MPLADS during this period: MPs elected in 1991 who faced elections again in 1996; MPs elected in 1996 who faced elections in 1998; and MPs elected in 1998 who faced elections in 1999. It is not possible to analyze the influence of specific legislator characteristics on MPLADS spending over the period 1993-1999 because we cannot disaggregate constituency spending between the 3 cohorts. However, the fourth cohort of MPs with access to MPLADS was elected in 1999; its term in office lasted until the next elections of April 2004, or four fiscal years. For this cohort we have constituency-level data on spending incurred by individual MPs over their term in office from 1999-2004. We therefore analyze the determinants of variation in MPLADS spending by this 1999-elected cohort of legislators across 483 electoral districts. 17 We first estimate the following basic specification to examine the role of political parties in determining legislator effort to bring public works to their constituencies: UtilizationMPLADS + β * Reserved 3 + η + λ + ε d s ds ds d s = β * PartyStronghold + β * MarginVictory 4 1 ds ds + β * CandidateStronghold + β * 1993 99Spending 5 2 ds ds (1) 16 The implementing ministry, the Ministry of Statistics and Program Implementation, informed us that annual data on spending during this period is not available because of lack of proper reporting procedures at that time. This was rectified in 1999 under the new implementation guidelines. 17 The total number of national electoral districts in India is 543. We drop 39 districts from our analysis because the Election Commission of India does not provide 1999 electoral data for these districts. We also omit 20 districts which held by-elections between 1999 and 2004, usually due to the death of the 1999-elected incumbent, thereby changing the identity of the politician in the middle of the term in office. One last district was dropped because of an apparent data error in which total MPLADS spending was reported as negative.

19 The left-hand side variable, UtilizationMPLADS, is the actual spending incurred by the MP in constituency d in state s as a percentage of what the MP was entitled to spend on public works in his/her constituency. The entitlement includes the legacy of unspent allocations that MPs had at their disposal in 1999 and additional yearly allocations from 1999 on. As discussed in previous sections, this is our measure of the effort exerted by MPs to bring local infrastructure to their constituents. The variable PartyStronghold equals one if the party won every election in constituency d in state s in the 1990s (in the 1991, 1996, 1998, and 1999 elections) and zero otherwise. This was a period of substantial electoral volatility and emerging incumbency disadvantage, supporting our interpretation of the PartyStronghold indicator variable as identifying those constituencies where voters are particularly attached to political parties. The variable CandidateStronghold equals 1 if the same person has been elected into office in constituency d in state s in every election between, and including, 1991 and 1999, irrespective of his/her party affiliation. We include this variable to test whether a party could have an electoral lock on a constituency for reasons other than the citizens intrinsic preference for the party. The most important is that parties might be dominant because they have been fortunate in finding a candidate whose personal characteristics are highly valued by voters. 18 Of the 483 constituencies in our analysis, 97 (20 percent) are party strongholds, and of these the party switched the nominated candidate in 61 districts, retaining the same 18 The total number of candidate stronghold constituencies in our sample is 42, of which only 6 are candidate strongholds without being party strongholds (where the dominant candidate switched his/her party affiliation). The Indian data therefore do not suggest that candidates can maintain dominance without a dominant party.

20 candidate in the remaining 36 districts. We test whether the effect of party stronghold is different in constituencies where a party switched its candidate than in constituencies where there was no such switch. That is, we estimate the following specification: (2) UtilizationMPLADS d s + φ * PartyStronghold *( NotSwitched) 2 + φ * 1993 99Spending 5 = φ * PartyStronghold * ( CandidateSwitched) 1 ds + η + λ + ε d s ds ds + φ * Reserved 3 ds ds + φ * MarginVictory The first interaction term equals 1 for those party stronghold constituencies where the party switched its candidate, and the second those constituencies where the party retained the same candidate on its ticket. We test for the equality of coefficients φ 1 and φ 2 to ensure that the effect of party strongholds is driven by voter attachment to parties rather than candidates. Specifications (1) and (2) are obviously susceptible to reverse causality. Incumbents who spent more of their allocation before 1999 to maintain their dominance would have relatively smaller accumulated entitlements by the time they were re-elected in 1999. It would therefore require less effort for them to disburse a given fraction of their remaining allocation than it would have for incumbents whose predecessors had left them a larger legacy of unspent MPLADS funds. However, this reverse causality argument predicts exactly the opposite sign (positive instead of negative) for the coefficients of PartyStronghold and CandidateStronghold than the one predicted by our argument that strong parties reduce legislator incentives to spend. We control for previous spending under MPLADS from 1993 to 1999 by including the variable 1993 99Spending which measures the total MPLADS spending undertaken in constituency d since the inception of the program until the 1999 elected cohort took office. This variable also captures other constituency-specific 4 ds

21 characteristics related to administrative effectiveness or opportunities for rent-seeking using MPLADS. To ensure that party stronghold effects are not simply reflective of non-competitive elections, we control for the closeness of electoral races in constituencies, MarginVictory. 19 This is the average margin of victory in constituency d of the winning candidate (over the runner-up candidate, under a simple plurality electoral law in single-member constituencies) over the three elections of 1996, 1998, and 1999. 20 Competitiveness of districts may also be influenced by a unique institutional arrangement in India of political affirmative action for disadvantaged groups. This requires that in approximately 20 percent of constituencies (108 of 483 in our sample) parties must nominate candidates from constitutionally scheduled castes and tribes. The last electoral delimitation law of 1977, which was fully implemented by 1982, determined which 19 Candidates and parties are expected to target closely-contested districts with greater resources and effort (Dixit and Londregan, 1996; Lindbeck and Weibull, 1987; and Snyder, 1989). Consequently, all studies of legislator responsiveness take into account some measure of the electoral competitiveness of a district at the time a policy decision is made. However, the evidence that governments target spending to those districts where the vote was closest is mixed. For example, looking at Indian state governments, although Cole (2001) finds evidence governments target spending to close districts, Bardhan and Mookherjee (2005) find marginality is a weak predictor of service allocation by the state ruling party in the Indian state of West Bengal. 20 We test robustness of estimates to calculating the average over different periods of elections, including just the most recent election of 1999. There is no difference in the sign or significance of any of the estimated coefficients relating to changes in how the average margin of victory is calculated.

22 constituencies would be reserved (Pande, 2003). 21 To control for the impact of this affirmative action policy on legislator incentives to distribute pork, we include an indicator variable for whether a constituency is reserved for candidates belonging to the scheduled castes and tribes: Reserved equals 1 if constituency d is so reserved, and 0 otherwise. The unobserved error in our specification consists of a constituency-specific term, η d, a state-specific term, λ s, and noise, ε ds. We are relying on the variable 1993-99Spending to account for unobserved constituency-specific characteristics that could explain MPLADS spending and be correlated with PartyStronghold, the central variable in our tests. That is, we assume that the expected value of η d is zero, conditional upon the inclusion of previous years MPLADS spending in the constituency. In the results below we will show that including other constituency-specific variables, such as the constituency s stock of public infrastructure, electoral volatility, and social fragmentation, does not change our estimates of the impact of party strongholds and reservations. While we cannot definitively exclude the possibility that omitted variables drive our results, these specifications do account for the most plausible alternative explanations for our findings. Moreover, the results are robust to controls for state fixed effects, λ s. The estimates of λ s, which are most negative for states that are known to have strong parties, provide further independent support for the hypothesis that voter attachment to political parties reduces legislator incentives to exert effort on spending their MPLADS allocation. The summary statistics of all the variables used in the basic specification are listed in Table 1. 5. Cross-constituency variation in MPLADS spending: Results 21 Reservations were introduced substantially before the initiation of the MPLADS program, and before most of the parties we consider in this study were even established.

23 Table 2 presents the results of three estimates of specification (1) that vary the assumptions about the distribution of errors across constituencies within a state. All three estimates demonstrate the importance of the party stronghold variable. The coefficient estimates in columns (1) and (2) are identical (although standard errors are bigger in the second case, because of clustering at the state level) and indicate that MPLADS disbursements in constituencies with a dominant party are ten percentage points less, more than one-half of a standard deviation. The size of the coefficient falls slightly when we include state fixed effects in column (3), to seven percentage points. This estimate measures the deviation of party stronghold constituencies within each state from the state average. The state fixed effects themselves, listed in Table 3, also support the argument that voter attachment to a single party reduces incumbent incentives to disburse MPLADS. States with dominant parties have significantly lower spending than other states. West Bengal, the only state where a single political party, the Communist Party of India (Marxist) has dominated state politics and leadership since 1977, stands out as a state with significantly and substantially lower MPLADS spending than other states. Average spending in constituencies in West Bengal is 18 percentage points lower than average spending in other states. In contrast, in those states where voters exhibit more even attachment to rival political parties, as in the state of Tamil Nadu in India, legislators exert significantly greater effort. When parties are neck-to-neck in electoral contests they use any additional instruments available to them to demonstrate the superiority of individual candidates they nominate. As discussed in the previous section, one effect that could give rise to spurious negative associations between party strongholds and MPLADS disbursements is prior spending on MPLADS. The control for prior disbursements is robustly significant and a

24 positive determinant of utilization after 1999, consistent with the earlier observation that more spending prior to 1999 reduces the effort needed to utilize allocations after 1999. If these characteristics influenced both voter attachment to a dominant party and MPLADS spending, party stronghold would be insignificant. Instead, party stronghold is significant in all regressions with the control for prior spending. Party stronghold effects are also robust to the control for a constituency s average margin of victory. This variable is significant at the 10 percent level, but only in specifications without state fixed effects. Its sign is positive, suggesting that closeness of electoral competition as measured by lower margins of victory is associated with lower MP effort in disbursing their entitlement. However, this correlation could well be due to reverse causality MPs that exert greater effort in spending their MPLADS allocation are able to achieve higher margins of victory. Our concern is the robustness of the party stronghold effect when we control for the margin of victory; the results here amply support the argument that the party stronghold effect is primarily driven by voter attachment to a party rather than lower levels of electoral competition per se. The systematic evidence from Table 2 is compelling that legislators provide less constituency service in high attachment areas. There is no data to test whether, consistent with the arguments presented earlier, these same legislators are also more likely to shirk, or to be less able, or to exert greater effort on public good provision or party-building activities. However, some evidence supports these corollary hypotheses. Bardhan and Mookherjee (2005) argue that greater voter attachment to a dominant party in the Indian state of West Bengal is associated with greater shirking by village governments in implementing the party s policy of land reforms. The Marxist parties of West Bengal, which generally enjoy high voter attachment, are also known to demand that their

25 candidates provide significant support to the party as a whole. Finally, it is well known that parties aim to find congenial constituencies for party luminaries (eg. veteran party leaders, or heirs of deceased party luminaries) who can influence policy-making in the legislature, even if they have no comparative advantage in disbursing MPLADS (e.g., because their patronclient ties within the constituency are few). In many parliamentary systems, such candidates are disproportionately likely to stand for election in constituencies with high voter attachment to their party, though we cannot confirm this in the case of India. In contrast to the significant results for the party stronghold variable, candidate dominance (CandidateStronghold) exhibits no significant correlation with MPLADS spending. Moreover, column (4) in Table 2 indicates no statistical difference in spending between party stronghold constituencies that switched their nominated candidate and those in which they did not (in which the candidate was dominant as well). This is an important robustness check for the party stronghold results, demonstrating that lower spending in party stronghold constituencies is driven by voter attachment to parties rather than to individual candidates. The CandidateStronghold results are also notable because of their implications for the effects of legislator experience. In the adverse selection model of Ashworth (2005) and Ashworth and Bueno de Mesquita (2006), constituency service is greater when there is greater uncertainty about legislators underlying ability to deliver goods, leading to the prediction that legislators with less political experience would be more likely to exert effort on constituency service to build their reputation with voters as high ability candidates. We, however, do not find robust or significant evidence that dominant and experienced candidates, as in candidate strongholds, spend less of their MPLADS allocation. This is also