Matthew A. Cole and Eric Neumayer. The pitfalls of convergence analysis : is the income gap really widening?

Similar documents
Convergence Divergence Debate within India

Handout 1: Empirics of Economic Growth

POLICY OPTIONS AND CHALLENGES FOR DEVELOPING ASIA PERSPECTIVES FROM THE IMF AND ASIA APRIL 19-20, 2007 TOKYO

Trends in the Income Gap Between. Developed Countries and Developing Countries,

Workers Remittances. and International Risk-Sharing

Book Discussion: Worlds Apart

Comment on Dowrick and DeLong, Globalisation and Convergence

Real Convergence in the European Union

LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES

THE EVALUATION OF OUTPUT CONVERGENCE IN SEVERAL CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES

Hong Kong, China (SAR)

Lecture 1 Economic Growth and Income Differences: A Look at the Data

Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices. Solomon Islands

Female parliamentarians and economic growth: Evidence from a large panel

Venezuela (Bolivarian Republic of)

Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices. Serbia. HDI values and rank changes in the 2014 Human Development Report

Economic assimilation of Mexican and Chinese immigrants in the United States: is there wage convergence?

Honors General Exam Part 1: Microeconomics (33 points) Harvard University

Income Convergence in the EU: A tale of two speeds

Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices. Belarus. HDI values and rank changes in the 2014 Human Development Report

WORKINGPAPER SERIES. A more or less unequal world? World income distribution in the 20th century. Bob Sutcliffe POLITICAL ECONOMY RESEARCH INSTITUTE

Convergence across EU Members and the Consequences for the Czech Republic

Global Inequality Fades as the Global Economy Grows

REAL ECONOMIC CONVERGENCE *

DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

Global Income Inequality

The former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia

WHY POOR REGIONS REMAIN POOR? EVIDENCE FROM MALAYSIA

Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices. Armenia. HDI values and rank changes in the 2014 Human Development Report

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

University of Groningen. Corruption and governance around the world Seldadyo, H.

Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices. Dominican Republic

Lao People's Democratic Republic

Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices. Palestine, State of

Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices. Cambodia. HDI values and rank changes in the 2014 Human Development Report

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Sri Lanka. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

Korean Economic Integration: Prospects and Pitfalls

INCOME INEQUALITY WITHIN AND BETWEEN COUNTRIES

ECONOMIC GROWTH* Chapt er. Key Concepts

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

Does Learning to Add up Add up? Lant Pritchett Presentation to Growth Commission October 19, 2007

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

Working Papers in Economics

Direction of trade and wage inequality

TRENDS IN INCOME INEQUALITY: GLOBAL, INTER-COUNTRY, AND WITHIN COUNTRIES Zia Qureshi 1

Venezuela (Bolivarian Republic of)

China component in international income inequality: based. on method of controlling economic factors MS 379

Ludovica Marchi Comparing approaches: strategic culture versus the domestic level the CSDP in Libya in 2011

Lecture notes 1: Evidence and Issues. These notes are based on a draft manuscript Economic Growth by David N. Weil. All rights reserved.

5. Destination Consumption

Demographic Changes and Economic Growth: Empirical Evidence from Asia

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict,

Test Bank for Economic Development. 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith

Key Facts about Long Run Economic Growth

Tilburg University. The digital divide across all citizens of the world James, Jeffrey. Published in: Social Indicators Research

PROJECTION OF NET MIGRATION USING A GRAVITY MODEL 1. Laboratory of Populations 2

Riding the Elephants: The Evolution of World Economic Growth and Income Distribution at the End of the Twentieth Century ( )

Albania. HDI values and rank changes in the 2013 Human Development Report

Eric Neumayer. The determinants of aid allocation by regional multilateral development banks and United Nations agencies

Wage Structure and Gender Earnings Differentials in China and. India*

The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis

Democracy and Changes in Income Inequality

Human Capital and Income Inequality: New Facts and Some Explanations

Economic Freedom and Economic Performance: The Case MENA Countries

Cambridge International Examinations Cambridge International General Certificate of Secondary Education

The Impact of Foreign Direct Investment on Income Convergence: Evidence from Provinces of Vietnam

Do Remittances Promote Household Savings? Evidence from Ethiopia

Do We See Convergence in Institutions? A Cross- Country Analysis

Changes in the global income distribution and their political consequences

The Role of Internet Adoption on Trade within ASEAN Countries plus People s Republic of China

CONVERGENCE OF REAL GDP PER CAPITA

REGIONAL INCOME DIVERGENCE IN CHINA: A NON-STATIONARY PANEL APPROACH

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Economic Growth and Regional Income Disparities in Canada and the Northern United States

Hungary. HDI values and rank changes in the 2013 Human Development Report

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Indonesia

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries

Religious Demography of Emerging Economies

and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1

SIMPLE LINEAR REGRESSION OF CPS DATA

Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Worlds Apart: Measuring International and Global Inequality

Application of PPP exchange rates for the measurement and analysis of regional and global inequality and poverty

ARTNeT Trade Economists Conference Trade in the Asian century - delivering on the promise of economic prosperity rd September 2014

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis

Ghana Lower-middle income Sub-Saharan Africa (developing only) Source: World Development Indicators (WDI) database.

Online Appendix for The Contribution of National Income Inequality to Regional Economic Divergence

CONVERGENCE IN GLOBAL MANUFACTURING COMPENSATION COSTS: AN INTERNATIONAL TRADE PERSPECTIVE. Emily Kolinski Morris

Have We Already Met the Millennium Development Goal for Poverty?

Columbia University. Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series

ADDITIONAL RESULTS FOR REBELS WITHOUT A TERRITORY. AN ANALYSIS OF NON- TERRITORIAL CONFLICTS IN THE WORLD,

REMITTANCES, POVERTY AND INEQUALITY

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach

Trade, convergence and globalisation: the dynamics of the international income distribution, *

MEASURING INTRA-REGIONAL INCOME INEQUALITY OF GDP PER CAPITA DURING : A STUDY ON SOUTH ASIA

Full file at

Transcription:

LSE Research Online Article (refereed) Matthew A. Cole and Eric Neumayer The pitfalls of convergence analysis : is the income gap really widening? Originally published in Applied economics letters, 10 (6). pp. 355-357 2003 Routledge, part of the Taylor and Francis Group. You may cite this version as: Cole, Matthew A. & Neumayer, Eric (2003). The pitfalls of convergence analysis : is the income gap really widening? [online] London: LSE Research Online. Available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/archive/00000603 Available online: February 2006 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. This document is the author s final manuscript version of the journal article, incorporating any revisions agreed during the peer review process. Some differences between this version and the publisher s version remain. You are advised to consult the publisher s version if you wish to cite from it. http://eprints.lse.ac.uk Contact LSE Research Online at: Library.Researchonline@lse.ac.uk

The Pitfalls of Convergence Analysis: Is the Income Gap Really Widening? (Running title: Pitfalls of convergence analysis) MATTHEW A. COLE* and ERIC NEUMAYER** * Department of Economics, University of Birmingham, Edgbaston, Birmingham, B15 2TT, UK. ** Corresponding author. Department of Geography and the Environment, London School of Economics, Houghton Street, London, WC2A 2AE, UK. Fax. +44 (0)207 955 7412. E-mail: e.neumayer@lse.ac.uk. ABSTRACT A number of studies have tested whether, globally, per capita incomes are converging over time. To date, the majority of studies find no evidence of absolute convergence, but many find evidence of conditional convergence, i.e. convergence having controlled for differences in technological and behavioural parameters. The lack of evidence of absolute convergence has led to claims that global income inequality is deteriorating. We believe this to be untrue. Most convergence studies are aimed at proving or disproving the neoclassical growth model and hence take the country as the unit of measurement. However, if one is making inferences about world income distribution the focus should be on people rather than countries to prevent China and Luxembourg, for example, receiving equal weighting in the 1

analysis. We use the β-convergence method and two different measures of per capita income and show that there is indeed evidence of income divergence between countries. However, crucially, we also find convincing evidence of income convergence if we weight our regressions by population. Thus, we find that poor peoples incomes are growing faster than rich peoples incomes, suggesting that global income inequality is in fact improving. I. INTRODUCTION Neoclassical growth theory predicts that poor economies grow faster than rich economies. If all economies are assumed to have the same steady state, then the only difference across countries lies in their initial level of capital and poor economies grow faster because they are further away from their steady state. This process is called absolute convergence. If, more realistically, economies are assumed to have different steady states contingent on differences in technological and behavioural parameters, then neoclassical theory only predicts conditional convergence, that is poor economies grow faster only if these differences in parameters are controlled for (Sala-i-Martin, 1996). Convergence has been empirically tested for countries in the world, regions in Europe, American states, Japanese prefectures and many other economies. As concerns countries in the world, the results are somewhat mixed, but most evidence seems to suggest that there is no absolute convergence (De Long, 1988; Pritchett, 1997). Pritchett (1996, p. 40), for example, suggests that one can forget about absolute convergence: The overwhelming feature of modern economic history is a massive divergence in per capita incomes between rich and poor countries, a gap which is continuing to grow today. However, there is evidence of conditional 2

convergence. Sala-i-Martin (1996), for example, estimates a speed of conditional convergence of two per cent per annum in a sample of 110 countries if the primary and secondary school enrolment ratio, the saving rate and some political variables are controlled for. In this letter, we focus on the finding of absolute divergence of incomes across countries. We have no quarrel with the finding that in a sample of world economies poor countries do not grow faster than rich ones. Indeed, further below we report evidence from the newly available update of the Penn World Tables (PWT) income data, a source used by most studies, which buttresses this finding. What we demonstrate is that this finding needs to be interpreted with great care. In particular, absolute income divergence across countries only implies that poor countries do not catch up with rich countries, but it does not imply that poor people do not catch up with rich people. We will show that there is absolute divergence only if countries are the point of reference. If one focuses on population as the point of reference instead, then there is evidence that the poor have grown faster than the rich and that world income distribution has become more equal over time. Thus, for example, Hobijn and Franses s (2001, p. 195) suggestion of a persistent gap between the rich and poor is misleading as this gap only persists between countries, but not if one weights for differences in population. One needs to focus on countries if the aim is to test neoclassical growth theory. After all, each country represents a separate economy and should follow the prediction of the theory. However, if we are concerned with issues of equity and how world income distribution changes over time, then our focus should be on population rather than countries. The two can lead to extremely contrary conclusions. A simple thought experiment makes this point very clear. Imagine the world consists of 1 rich 3

country and 10 poor countries. Of these 10 poor countries, imagine 9 have small populations and 1 has a very large population that exceeds the combined populations of all the other countries (rich and poor). If the 9 poor countries with small populations grow slower than the rich country, but the one very populous poor country grows faster than the rich country, then we would observe absolute income divergence if countries are the point of reference. However, if population is our point of reference then we find absolute income convergence since the income of the majority of people in the poor countries grows faster than the income of people in the rich country. II. CONVERGENCE ANALYSIS To analyse country based versus population based income convergence, we test for so-called β-convergence. Strictly speaking, β-convergence is only a necessary, but not a sufficient, condition for convergence (see, for example, Quah, 1996, 1997). However, β-convergence is insufficient for convergence only if the once rich countries grow poor and the once poor countries grow rich such that the dispersion of incomes has not decreased (Sala-i-Martin, 1996). Because this is not the case empirically and due to space constraints, we refrain from applying more advanced statistical techniques such as kernel density, Markov transition or cluster analysis. Let g i,t,t+t log(y t+t /y i,t )/T be the country s annualised growth rate between t and t + T, then there is absolute β-convergence (divergence) if β is statistically significant and negative (positive): g i,t,t+t = α + βlog(y i,t ) + u i,t 4

We start our analysis with gross domestic product per capita in purchasing power parity (chain method) and constant 1996 dollars from the recently updated PWT 6.0 database (Heston, Summers and Aten, 2001). Whilst the series goes back to 1950, we take 1960 as the initial period as many countries do not have data available prior to this year. Column I of table 1 presents results for the regression with countries as the point of reference, that is without applying population weights. The regression coefficient is followed by its t-value and the number of observations. There is absolute divergence at the 90% significance level between 1960 and 1996 for 110 countries, covering approximately 85 per cent of the world population. There is divergence at the 99% level between 1980 and 1996 for 123 countries, covering approximately 88 per cent of the world population. The opposite is true, however, if weighted least squares is used where the weights are equal to the average population size in the period of study (see column II). Also note that whilst the country-based regression suggests a higher speed of divergence from 1980 onwards, the populationweighted regressions suggest a higher speed of convergence in that period. What is the reason for this striking difference? The answer is poor, populous, fast growing China that grows particularly fast from the 1980s onwards. If China is taken out in column III of table 1, then β is insignificantly positive in the period 1960 to 1996 and insignificantly negative in the period 1980 to 1996. < Insert Table 1 about here > If the income data are taken from World Bank (2001) instead, which uses a different methodology for computing GDP per capita data in purchasing power 5

parity, then there is less sensitivity of the results with respect to China. 1 Column I of table 2 reports the unweighted, column II the population weighted regression results. Note that World Bank (2001) does not provide data on GDP per capita in purchasing power parity before 1975. In the unweighted regression, β is positive, but insignificant, whereas there is strong evidence for convergence in the weighted regressions. Convergence remains, and is still statistically significant, if China is removed from the sample (see column III). < Insert Table 2 about here > III. CONCLUSIONS We have demonstrated in this letter that in looking only at country based convergence analysis one might be tempted to conclude that the gap between the rich and the poor is increasing rather than shrinking. We believe this to be an inaccurate conclusion which stems from the fact that country based convergence analysis does not assess whether, on average, the gap between poor people and rich people is shrinking over time. To test this one needs to weight for differences in population size and we have shown that there is substantial evidence for convergence in population weighted income levels. This is welcome news from an equity point of view and it also puts into doubt allegations that the process of globalisation leads to higher income inequality in the world. We have shown that our result is sensitive towards the inclusion of China in the sample if income data are drawn from the PWT, but not from the World Bank. Note, however, that even in the PWT case it would be inappropriate to exclude China from 1 Data are converted into constant 1995 dollars with the help of the U.S. GDP deflator. 6

the sample. The sensitivity of the results to the inclusion of China are because China covers more than 20 per cent of world population, and not because it is such a strong outlier in the classic statistical sense. No one could reasonably argue that in analysing trends in world income distribution one should exclude one fifth of the world population from the sample. Of course, our analysis is still simplistic and represents merely a first step. Implicitly, we ignore within country income inequalities and changes therein. The problem is that within country income distribution data are so sparse and unreliable that a long-term convergence analysis is currently impossible. Milanovic (2002) represents one of the most comprehensive first attempts at taking into account both between and within country inequality, but he can only compare two years, 1988 and 1993. It remains to be seen whether future research that takes changes in the within country income distribution into account will confirm the results of our analysis and still find convergence in population weighted income levels. REFERENCES De Long, J.B. (1988) Productivity growth, convergence, and welfare: comment, American Economic Review, 78, 1138 1154. Heston, A., Summers, R. and Aten, B. (2001) Penn World Table Version 6.0, Center for International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania (CICUP). Hobijn, B. and Franses, P.H. (2001) Are living standards converging? Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 12, 171 200. Milanovic, B. (2002) True world income distribution, 1988 and 1993: first calculation based on household surveys alone, Economic Journal, 112, 51 92. 7

Pritchett, L. (1996) Forget convergence: divergence past, present, and future, Finance & Development 33, 40 43. Pritchett, L. (1997) Divergence, big time, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11, 3 17. Quah, D.T. (1996) Empirics for economic growth and convergence, European Economic Review, 40, 1353 1375. Quah, D.T. (1997) Empirics for growth and distribution: stratification, polarization, and convergence clubs, Journal of Economic Growth, 2, 27 59. Sala-i-Martin, X.X. (1996) The classical approach to convergence analysis, Economic Journal, 106, 1019 1036. World Bank (2001) World Development Indicators on CD-Rom, Washington D.C. 8

Table 1. Convergence analysis for PWT income data. I country-based log gdp1960.0042* (1.92) (N = 110) log gdp1980.0077*** (3.57) (N = 123) II population weighted -.0034** (2.33) (N = 110) -.0098*** (4.71) (N = 123) III population weighted, excluding China.0007 (.46) (N = 109) -.0025 (1.37) (N = 122) Where *, ** and *** denote statistical significance at the 90%, 95% and 99% confidence levels, respectively. 9

Table 2. Convergence analysis for World Bank income data. I country-based log gdp1975.0001 (0.10) (N = 111) log gdp1980.0007 (.33) (N = 124) II population weighted -.0136*** (7.37) (N = 111) -.0163*** (7.74) (N = 124) III population weighted, excluding China -.0035** (2.35) (N = 110) -.0049** (3.10) (N = 123) Where *, ** and *** denote statistical significance at the 90%, 95% and 99% confidence levels, respectively. 10