Corruption as Social Order

Similar documents
Becoming Denmark. Historical pathways to European control of corruption

The Global State of Corruption Control. Who Succeeds, Who Fails and What Can Be Done About It

The Global State of Corruption Control. Who Succeeds, Who Fails and What Can Be Done About It

Regional Scores. African countries Press Freedom Ratings 2001

Rethinking the way we do anti corruption

Contracting Parties to the Ramsar Convention

2018 Social Progress Index

REGIONAL INTEGRATION IN THE AMERICAS: THE IMPACT OF THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS

Copyright Act - Subsidiary Legislation CHAPTER 311 COPYRIGHT ACT. SUBSIDIARY LEGlSLA non. List o/subsidiary Legislation

Big Government, Small Government and Corruption: an European Perspective. Alina Mungiu-Pippidi Hertie School of Governance

Daniel Kaufmann, Brookings Institution

A Partial Solution. To the Fundamental Problem of Causal Inference

Statistical Appendix 2 for Chapter 2 of World Happiness Report March 1, 2018

The Multidimensional Financial Inclusion MIFI 1

Per Capita Income Guidelines for Operational Purposes

2017 BWC Implementation Support Unit staff costs

Figure 2: Range of scores, Global Gender Gap Index and subindexes, 2016

FREEDOM OF THE PRESS 2008

Country pairings for the second cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption

GLOBAL PRESS FREEDOM RANKINGS

Sex ratio at birth (converted to female-over-male ratio) Ratio: female healthy life expectancy over male value

The Conference Board Total Economy Database Summary Tables November 2016

58 Kuwait 83. Macao (SAR China) Maldives. 59 Nauru Jamaica Botswana Bolivia 77. Qatar. 63 Bahrain 75. Namibia.

CUSTOMS AND EXCISE ACT, AMENDMENT OF SCHEDULE NO. 2 (NO. 2/3/5)

Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption: country pairings for the second review cycle

STATUS OF THE CONVENTION ON THE PROHIBITION OF THE DEVELOPMENT, PRODUCTION, STOCKPILING AND USE OF CHEMICAL WEAPONS AND ON THEIR DESTRUCTION

Transparency International Corruption Perceptions Index 2013

Geoterm and Symbol Definition Sentence. consumption. developed country. developing country. gross domestic product (GDP) per capita

Country pairings for the first cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption

Country pairings for the first review cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption

LIST OF CONTRACTING STATES AND OTHER SIGNATORIES OF THE CONVENTION (as of January 11, 2018)

GLOBAL RISKS OF CONCERN TO BUSINESS WEF EXECUTIVE OPINION SURVEY RESULTS SEPTEMBER 2017

Antipersonnel Mine Stockpile Destruction (Article 4)

Status of National Reports received for the United Nations Conference on Housing and Sustainable Urban Development (Habitat III)

Proforma Cost for national UN Volunteers for UN Partner Agencies

TD/B/Inf.222. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. Membership of UNCTAD and membership of the Trade and Development Board

2017 Social Progress Index

Montessori Model United Nations - NYC Conference February Middle School Level COMMITTEES

The globalization of inequality

A) List of third countries whose nationals must be in possession of visas when crossing the external borders. 1. States

Transparency International Corruption Perceptions Index 2012

CORRUPTION PERCEPTIONS INDEX 2013.

CORRUPTION PERCEPTIONS INDEX 2013.

Proforma Cost for National UN Volunteers for UN Partner Agencies for National UN. months) Afghanistan 14,030 12,443 4,836

A) List of third countries whose nationals must be in possession of visas when crossing the external borders. 1. States

Transparency International Corruption Perceptions Index 2014

CORRUPTION PERCEPTIONS INDEX 2012.

corruption perceptions index

Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption: country pairings for the second review cycle

Country Participation

Country pairings for the second review cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption

CAC/COSP/IRG/2018/CRP.9

Illustration of Proposed Quota and Voting Shares--By Member 1/ (In percent)

UNHCR, United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees

Global Social Progress Index

Voluntary Scale of Contributions

Collective Intelligence Daudi Were, Project

Country pairings for the first review cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption

Good Sources of International News on the Internet are: ABC News-

Rule of Law Index 2019 Insights

AUSTRALIA S REFUGEE RESPONSE NOT THE MOST GENEROUS BUT IN TOP 25

My Voice Matters! Plain-language Guide on Inclusive Civic Engagement

GUIDELINE OF COMMITTEES IN TASHKENT MODEL UNITED NATIONS CONFERENCE 2019

Views of Member States and Permanent Observers on How to Improve the Implementation of the Madrid Plan of Action (MIPAA)

CENTRAL AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN

GLOBAL CORRUPTION PERCEPTION INDEX (CPI) 2017 published 21 February

Information note by the Secretariat [V O T E D] Additional co-sponsors of draft resolutions/decisions

corruption perceptions index

Delays in the registration process may mean that the real figure is higher.

A Practical Guide To Patent Cooperation Treaty (PCT)

Montessori Model United Nations - NYC Conference March 2018

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 412 persons in December 2017, and 166 of these were convicted offenders.

ECON 1000 Contemporary Economic Issues (Spring 2018) Economic Growth

-Ms. Wilkins. AP Human Geography Summer Assignment

MORTALITY FROM ROAD CRASHES

corruption perceptions index 2016

INCOME AND EXIT TO ARGENTINA

OFFICIAL NAMES OF THE UNITED NATIONS MEMBERSHIP

Charting Cambodia s Economy, 1H 2017

The Henley & Partners - Kochenov GENERAL RANKING

The Global Gender Gap Index 2015

Income and Population Growth

Proforma Cost Overview for national UN Volunteers for UN Peace Operations (DPA/DPKO)

REINVENTION WITH INTEGRITY

Overview of the status of UNCITRAL Conventions and Model Laws x = ratification, accession or enactment s = signature only

8. b) Optional Protocol to the Convention on the Elimination of All Forms of Discrimination against Women. New York, 6 October 1999

TAKING HAPPINESS SERIOUSLY

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

Part 1: The Global Gender Gap and its Implications

GENTING DREAM IMMIGRATION & VISA REQUIREMENTS FOR THAILAND, MYANMAR & INDONESIA

ANNEX IV: RATES APPLICABLE FOR UNIT CONTRIBUTIONS

NOTE BY THE TECHNICAL SECRETARIAT STATUS OF PARTICIPATION IN THE CHEMICAL WEAPONS CONVENTION AS AT 14 MARCH SUMMARY

Committee for Development Policy Seventh Session March 2005 PURCHASING POWER PARITY (PPP) Note by the Secretariat

ANNEX IV: RATES APPLICABLE FOR UNIT

Programme budget for the biennium

Convention on the Physical Protection of Nuclear Material

Financial situation of the United Nations. Statement by Yukio Takasu, Under-Secretary-General for Management

List of Agreements on Mutual Visa Exemption. Between the People s Republic of China and Foreign Countries

Trends in international higher education

TABLE OF COUNTRIES WHOSE CITIZENS, HOLDERS OF ORDINARY PASSPORTS, REQUIRE/DO NOT REQUIRE VISAS TO ENTER BULGARIA

Transcription:

Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized BACKGROUND PAPER GOVERNANCE and THE LAW Corruption as Social Order Alina Mungiu-Pippidi Hertie School of Governance, Berlin

Disclaimer This background paper was prepared for the World Development Report 2017 Governance and the Law. It is made available here to communicate the results of the Bank s work to the development community with the least possible delay. The manuscript of this paper therefore has not been prepared in accordance with the procedures appropriate to formally-edited texts. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect the views of The World Bank, its Board of Executive Directors, or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries.

Background Paper for the 2017 World Development Report Corruption as social order By Alina Mungiu-Pippidi To understand why corruption has become the crucial issue for the latest generation of protest movements and uprisings, from Tunisia to Moldova and from India to Brazil, public corruption is best conceived as part of a broader social order context and not at individual level. Presuming corruption to be the exception and public integrity the norm in every society does not reflect the reality and can lead to erroneous development strategies, as norm building and norm enforcement require two very different approaches. Corruption is hardly a social malady to be eradicated, but rather a default governance order, as all states have started from being owned by a few individuals who control all resources to eventually reach a situation when the state represents everybody equally and shares public resources equitably. Particularism is a natural inclinationpeople tend to favor their own, be it family, clan, race or ethnic group: treating the rest of the world fairly seems to be a matter of extensive social evolution and sufficient resources. The publicprivate separation in public affairs and the complete autonomy of state from private interest are exceptions in the present world, difficult to reach and difficult to sustain as well. A governance order is a salient and stable set of rules of the game, both formal and informal, determining who gets what in a given society. In the modern world we consider as corrupt a governance regime which deviates significantly from the norm of ethical universalism, where similar rules apply to everyone (Parsons 1997: 80-82) resulting in an allocation of public resources which is partial and unfair, due to the presence of ties of a personal and particular nature between office holders and certain individuals or groups. This includes other forms of favoritism beyond those motivated by bribes, and both legal and illegal corruption, reflecting the current global perception of public corruption as shown in surveys (where large majorities across countries claim that most of their officials are corrupt, although only a minority was ever asked directly for a bribe, due to some Panama papers experience) and the broad approach of the United Nations Convention against Corruption (UNCAC), whose ratifying states pledge themselves to governance excluding any favoritism (Mungiu-Pippidi 2015; chapter 1). A country can fall anywhere on this continuum of governance which has as an extreme absolute ethical universalism (public integrity, with open access) and as the other absolute particularism (every public resource is allocated by virtue of status, which largely predicts a person s life prospects). Bribes are often the way to open access for individuals with inferior connections with power and authority in what is otherwise a public resource distribution system dominated by favoritism (Mungiu-Pippidi 2015 chapter 2). The evolution towards the public integrity end should not be taken for granted; universalism and individualism, which spread in the West after the Enlightenment to become generally held norms, are not natural, nor necessarily and under any circumstance good (Wilson 1993), although in the history of Western thought they have advanced continuously from Cicero to United Nations Treaty against Corruption. As they are not about a few people taking bribes, but about power resources being systematically used to sustain and convert into material benefits, governance orders are resilient, with the result of perpetuating unequal opportunities and subverting fair competition on the basis of merit and

hard work. Corruption correlates poorly with democracy, but closely with Geert Hofstede s (Hofstede 2011) psychological concept of power distance (the accepted hierarchy of power status in a society). It is therefore costly for the society at large, as it frequently results in the failure to enforce merit and honesty versus connections or privilege, with the inability to innovate and the drain of best brains towards merit-based societies, creating a vicious circle (Mungiu-Pippidi 2015, chapter 1). Furthermore, if the state is perceived to collect taxes from the many to redistribute them as privileges to the few, the poor also do not pay any taxes and social rebellions may occasionally incur, like the Arab Spring. This was started by a street vendor who set himself on fire to defend his right to remain unlicensed and untaxed by a government perceived to work only for the interest of a dictator and his clique. All societies start from an unequal endowment of power resources distributed across individual members or social groups, but some have managed through a long historical process to reduce such inequalities and arrive at citizenship, whereas society members have sufficient autonomy to defend their rights. Societies also differ in the accessibility of material resources which can be ripped off easily by people with power, such as natural resources. As states develop historically, individual autonomy grows, but so do the material resources available for spoiling, as people entrust more and more common resources for the state to undertake further tasks. Control of corruption can be thus conceived as a balance (see Figure 1) between such resources (of power discretion and potential material spoils) and constraints that an autonomous society is able to inflict on the ruling elites through an independent judiciary and a mass of enlightened citizens who put up a strong demand for good governance (see also Becker, G. 1968; Huther, J, and A Shah. 2000). The first generation of developed Western states has achieved this balance through modernization, but many other countries around the word have since tried to replicate this without achieving similar impersonality and rationalization of government. The last waves of democratization produced about eighty new democracies where politics is still about spoiling public resources by each elections winners in their turn. Figure 1 about here. Control of corruption as a balance

WGI Control of Corruption (-2.5 to 2.5 best) How inescapable is corruption? Modernity, however, as captured in the human development index, explains only a little more than half the variation in control of corruption. The association of control of corruption with human development index shows that some countries over-perform, and others underperform on governance seeing their human development, while in most of the countries we find a close correspondence (see Figure 2). Countries which seem to have found the virtuous circle of development by political agency are New Zealand, Norway, Denmark, Singapore, Chile, Uruguay, Georgia,, Costa Rica, Botswana. Countries which underperform are Venezuela, Argentina, Zimbabwe, Azerbaijan, Central Asian countries, Italy and Greece. How an optimal balance was reached or was missed in such countries becomes essential to learn. The presence among achievers of countries with a poor fit to a classic modernization model by the time they started their transformation (Chile, South Korea, Georgia, Botswana) also shows that transitions from one governance order to another can be engineered and steered, although this is not frequent. Figure 2. Predicted Control of Corruption Scores Based on Human Development 2.5 2 Denmark Singapore New Zealand Netherlands Norway 1.5 1 Botswana Bhutan Cape Verde Chile Qatar Barbados Uruguay St. Lucia St. Kitts and Nevis 0.5 0-0.5-1 -1.5 Burkina Faso Mozambique Liberia Niger Rwanda Lesotho Italy Greece Mexico Argentina Palau Ecuador Kazakhstan Kyrgyz Republic Russia Tajikistan Azerbaijan Iraq Uzbekistan Venezuela Equatorial Guinea Turkmenistan Myanmar -2 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 HDI Score (0 to 1 best) Legend. Dots are estimates of Control of Corruption (World Bank Institute) by Human Development Index (UNDP). Only outliers are shown.

Control of corruption is thus achieved when this balance gets right, and not when one or another anticorruption tool is adopted. Evidence shows that no silver bullet exists and countries which adopt anticorruption agencies, restrictive party finance legislation or whistleblower protection acts do not progress more than countries that don t- sometimes the opposite is true (Mungiu-Pippidi 2015, chapter 4). Mandatory disclosure of assets for officials work only in the presence of a free press. Fiscal transparency helps curb corruption only when an active civil society exists. It is the interaction between these factors which produces the equilibrium, and if on the society side the demand for control of corruption is poor, because spoils are used efficiently to buy off certain strategic groups, then collective action becomes impossible and the equilibrium remains suboptimal with particularism the norm. Both reduction of resources and increase of constraints can greatly be helped by technology. Digitalization helps transparency and rationalization of fiscal management on the government side and creates empowered citizens on the society side. Evidence exists that internet media in general and social networks in particular are indispensable components of citizen empowerment and collective action. Figure3. Structural and Policy Determinants of the Control of Corruption Human development CONSTRAINTS Geography and climate E-citizenship Freedom of the press Administrative burden Budget transparency War and violence Judicial independe nce Trade openness RESOURCES Colonial or Communist Past The index for public integrity from Figure 3 reduces this complex model of control of corruption (fully explained, tested and referenced in Mungiu-Pippidi 2015, chapter 4) to six key strategic areas and their basic indicators, thus providing a first step to an evidence-based strategy for both governments and civil societies 1. This is mirrored by the synthesis of key policies of performing countries those which managed to evolve to ethical universalism as a norm in contemporary 1 For more details on the index, see http://www.againstcorruption.eu/publications/measuring-control-of-corruptionby-a-new-index-of-public-integrity/

times- from Table 1. The policy menu in Table 1 has two advantages over the ordinary toolkit of consultants. First, each variable is tested on a time series model and is robustly significant. We know that it matters in affecting control of corruption in a context with all relevant controls. Second, each strategy or policy action was tried in some of the few countries which made it and worked. The table does not provide a universal recipe, but rather a checklist, an evidence based instrument to trace reforms and measure progress on what should finally be an optimal equilibrium. The current status of 104 countries on the public integrity index can be visualized here http://integrity-index.org/. The index correlates with World Bank Control of Corruption or Transparency International CPI at over 90 per cent. It is not meant to replace a sound political economy approach, but to complement it: the first initial question of anticorruption fighters remains who are those who lose out of current institutional arrangements and how can they be built in some coalition asking for or promoting these reforms. The question of who has to be answered before the question of what to do. Who are the credible agents of change and what can empower some collective action to challenge the status quo?

Table 1. Checklist and indicators to trace progress on control of corruption Reduce opportunity Action Indicator Benchmark country Natural resources Private management with public share of proceeds established by broad consultation and transparently spent Public report on spending revenues from natural resources Botswana Administrative discretion Reduce red tape and enforce equal treatment Ombudsman also auditor, controller, judicial reviewer Make resources transparent through e-government Ease of doing business; indicators of equal treatment Ration between cases solved administratively/cases solved through prosecution E-services as % as total public services Georgia Chile Public spending Transparent public spending concentrated on areas such as health, education, research and innovation Existence of e-portals on online tracking expenses for national and local government procurement Uruguay Formalization Tax simplification Tax collection by private agents E-payments facilitation Increase constraints Time of paying taxes % increase in collection rate yearly Uruguay Judicial independence Tenure, appointment and sanctioning of magistrates entrusted to magistrates bodies only with validation of such bodies by 2/3rds of upper chamber WEF Judiciary independence (perception of businessmen) Successful litigations against government Chile, Botswana and Taiwan Civil society Ease of registering NGOs, sunshine laws for public consultations, civil society component in every donor program, separate or combined with assistance to government, conditions on participatory budgeting, auditing or evaluations Number of NGOs % public consultations from total new legal drafts or policies Existence and traffic of watchdog websites Number of Facebook users Freedom of the media No government regulation for media except anti-trust or cartel legislation and transparency of ownership Political conditionality from international community related to media freedom Media sustainability indicators News readership/audience Empowered citizens IT investment in education, training for educators Freedom of Internet Internet connections per household Facebook users per country South Korea % citizens using e-services Source: Updated from Mungiu-Pippidi 2015, pp. 219-20.

Lessons from success cases Among the few successful transitions from particularism of contemporary times, emerges as the case which managed to strike the balance right in a relative short time about a decade 2. Its example was emulated by Georgia, a country with greater structural problems (partial control over its territory, refugees, territorial and economic conflict with a powerful neighbor country). Both countries experienced full-fledged revolutions, with civil societies taking over government overnight and political liberalization accompanied by free-market reforms aimed at taking away old elites rents. In both and Georgia there was an alternative elite committed to ethical-universalist ideas. In this was the group around the young nationalist historian Mart Laar (later an adviser for the Georgian reforms as well), who was able to engineer Eastern Europe s most successful transition even though, at the time he became premier in 1992, he had read only one book on economics. During his first stint as prime minister (1992 94), he replaced almost every judge left over from Soviet times with either very young or very old magistrates (who had not been first socialized into Communist habits), and uprooted much of the resource base for corruption by removing legal privileges for public companies, passing a flat tax and cutting red tape. When he returned to the premiership from 1999 until early 2002, he furthered the cause of good governance by initiating what has by now become the most advanced e-government system in the world (a single ID card is used to pay tax, public parking and vote). Based on former anti-soviet dissidents, the Laar government learned from the mistakes that Russian premier Yegor Gaidar had made (some following international advice) only a year before: That rule of law must come before privatization. Grasping that in a post-communist context it matters a great deal who the first capitalists are, they prevented the communist-holdover networks of enterprise managers, secretpolice bureaucrats, and other nomenklaturists from emerging as the transition s big winners and controllers, thereby sparing the crony capitalism that has blighted Ukraine and Russia for the past twenty years. The Georgian emulation was also radical, strongly led from the top and supported from the bottom in the same time. Both produced a more honest and performing civil service, albeit with massive replacement of personnel from corrupt times. In both countries civil society remained committed and critical towards government, and growth followed political reforms (see figure 4). 2 see Mungiu-Pippidi 2015, chapter 5 for all the cases and full story.

GDP per capita PPP (2011 constant international $) Control of Corruption -2.5 (worst) to 2.5 (best) Figure 4. Evolution of growth and control of corruption in the n post-communist transition 1.5 1.3 1.1 0.9 0.7 0.5 0.3 0.1-0.1-0.3-0.5 1996 1998 2000 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 35000 30000 25000 20000 15000 10000 5000 0 The revolutionary path, where reformers from civil society simply come to power is not frequent. Most international donors work with governments formed by people who win from the status quo and see reforms as jeopardizing their rents. The idea of incentivizing them is at best naïve. Governance is about rules of the game, in other words about what most people do. People conform to norms in their societies. If corruption is the norm and not the exception, the principal agent model does not work. And donors should watch carefully that they do not increase resources for corruption themselves. Any meaningful aid program should be designed to empower social accountability and develop normative constraints for corruption by means of entrusting ownership for change to the broader society through local communities and NGOs, not just the government.

Most anticorruption industry ignores this lesson and gets lost in buzzwords like incentives and other behavioral triggers. Let s face it. There is no incentive one can offer to a somebody who has grabbed what should be a public diamond mine and spoils it for his (and his cronies) profit. Nothing bigger than a diamond mine (or the whole budget, including assistance funds) exists by way of incentives. Rulers have to be made more accountable, and the ruled have to prevent corruption by permanent greater demand and public scrutiny. Anticorruption is not a win-win game, it s a game played by societies against their spoilers, and to prevent the winners not to turn into new spoilers quite a sustained effort is needed. While the new international legal arena is meant to eliminate areas without jurisdiction (and rightly so), retrieval of assets of former dictators is of little help if their democratically elected successors continue to spoil. Corruption is the real game played beyond many constitutional faҁades in the contemporary world, and without some shift in the balance of power to enable private-public separation little will change. Written laws and constitutions matter little in the real world, in many places no more than they matter in Westeros, as the game of thrones is played. The Romans already had the saying that corrupt Republics have the most laws. References Becker, G. 1968. Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach. Journal of Political Economy 76: 169 217. Hofstede, G. 2011. Dimensionalizing Cultures: The Hofstede Model in Context. Online Readings in Psychology and Culture 2 (1): 8. Huther, J, and A Shah. 2000. Anticorruption Policies and Programs: A Framework for Evaluation. Policy Research Working Paper 2501. The World Bank Mungiu-Pippidi, A. (2015). The quest for good governance: how societies develop control of corruption. Cambridge University Press. Parsons, T. 1997. Introduction to Max Weber. The Theory of Social and Economic Organization. New York: The Free Press. Wilson, J. Q. (1993). The Moral Sense. New York: Free Press.