Experimental economics and public choice

Similar documents
Agendas and Strategic Voting

Tinbergen Institute Amsterdam Keizersgracht EG Amsterdam The Netherlands Tel.: +31.(0) Fax: +31.(0)

HANDBOOK OF EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS RESULTS

Common-Pool Resources: Over Extraction and Allocation Mechanisms

Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory

SLEEPING WITH THE ENEMY: THE ECONOMIC COST OF INTERNAL ENVIRONMENTAL CONFLICTS

POLS G4371 LABORATORY EXPERIMENTS AND FORMAL THEORIES IN POLITICAL SCIENCE. Tuesday 10:10a-12:00p International Affairs Building 711

Behavioral Public Choice. Professor Rebecca Morton New York University

Proposed New Undergraduate Class: Experimental Methods in Political Science. Course Description

The Citizen Candidate Model: An Experimental Analysis

Compulsory versus Voluntary Voting Mechanisms: An Experimental Study

Sequential vs. Simultaneous Voting: Experimental Evidence

the social dilemma?» Emmanuel SOL, Sylvie THORON, Marc WILLINGER

"Efficient and Durable Decision Rules with Incomplete Information", by Bengt Holmström and Roger B. Myerson

An Experimental Investigation of Delegation, Voting and the Provision of Public Goods

Sorting Out Mechanical and Psychological Effects in Candidate Elections: An Appraisal with Experimental Data

Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees

Communication and Information in Games of Collective Decision: A Survey of Experimental Results

HANDBOOK OF SOCIAL CHOICE AND VOTING Jac C. Heckelman and Nicholas R. Miller, editors.

Are Dictators Averse to Inequality? *

The Governance Game. GOVERNANCE and THE LAW BACKGROUND PAPER. Sheheryar Banuri University of East Anglia

I assume familiarity with multivariate calculus and intermediate microeconomics.

Refinements of Nash equilibria. Jorge M. Streb. Universidade de Brasilia 7 June 2016

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

The Mathematics of Voting

Communication and Information in Games of Collective Decision: A Survey of Experimental Results

Laboratory Experiments in Political Economy by Thomas R. Palfrey, Princeton University CEPS Working Paper No. 111 July 2005

A Study of Approval voting on Large Poisson Games

3. Public Choice in a Direct Democracy

1. Collective action theory

LOGROLLING. Nicholas R. Miller Department of Political Science University of Maryland Baltimore County Baltimore, Maryland

Public opinion polls, voter turnout, and welfare: An experimental study *

The Political Economy of Trade Policy

Information Acquisition and Voting Mechanisms: Theory and Evidence

INFORMATION AND STRATEGIC VOTING

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Strategic Interaction, Trade Policy, and National Welfare - Bharati Basu

Sincere versus sophisticated voting when legislators vote sequentially

Communication and Voting Rules in Bargaining Games,

Sincere Versus Sophisticated Voting When Legislators Vote Sequentially

Expressive Voting and Government Redistribution *

Sampling Equilibrium, with an Application to Strategic Voting Martin J. Osborne 1 and Ariel Rubinstein 2 September 12th, 2002.

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997)

Discussion Papers Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

Common Pool Resources

Public Goods Agreements with Other Regarding Preferences

Self-Organization and Cooperation in Social Systems

Public choice and the development of modern laboratory experimental methods in economics and political science

Experimental Economics, Environment and Energy Lecture 3: Commons and public goods: tragedies and solutions. Paolo Crosetto

Compulsory versus Voluntary Voting An Experimental Study

Expressive voting and government redistribution: Testing Tullock s charity of the uncharitable

A Simultaneous Analysis of Turnout and Voting under Proportional Representation: Theory and Experiments. Aaron Kamm & Arthur Schram

Lecture 16: Voting systems

International Environmental Agreements with Endogenous Minimum Participation and the Role of Inequality

Part IIB Paper Outlines

INTERNATIONAL TRADE. (prepared for the Social Science Encyclopedia, Third Edition, edited by A. Kuper and J. Kuper)

Voting. Hannu Nurmi. Game Theory and Models of Voting. Public Choice Research Centre and Department of Political Science University of Turku

An Experimental Study of Self-enforcing Coalitions

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

A joint initiative of Ludwig-Maximilians University s Center for Economic Studies and the Ifo Institute for Economic Research

The welfare effects of public opinion polls

ANALYSES OF SUSTAINABLE MANAGEMENT OF COMMON- POOL RESOURCES

DISCUSSION PAPERS Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

A New Proposal on Special Majority Voting 1 Christian List

Compulsory versus Voluntary Voting An Experimental Study

Intergroup Inequality and the Breakdown of Prosociality

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference?

Voting rules: (Dixit and Skeath, ch 14) Recall parkland provision decision:

Towards an Information-Neutral Voting Scheme That Does Not Leave Too Much To Chance

Learning and Belief Based Trade 1

THE FUTURE OF ANALYTICAL POLITICS...

Polycentric governance as an instrument for promoting benefit sharing

Arrow s Impossibility Theorem

Theoretical comparisons of electoral systems

Andrzej Baranski & John H. Kagel

Experimental Investigation of Voting over Common Pool Resources

Voter Participation with Collusive Parties. David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi

Theoretical Public Economics Syllabus (ECO 7536; Spring 2018)

Why do people vote? While many theories have

Do States Free Ride in Antitrust Enforcement?

P1: aaa SJNW N stylea.cls (2005/11/30 v1.0 LaTeX Springer document class) January 2, :37

Ernst Fehr; Michael Näf und Klaus M. Schmidt: The Role of Equality and Equity in Social Preferences

1.6 Arrow s Impossibility Theorem

Final Exam. Thursday, December hour, 30 minutes

THE PARADOX OF VOTER PARTICIPATION? A LABORATORY STUDY

Public Goods and Public Choice. 1 of 20. Economics: Principles, Applications, and Tools O Sullivan, Sheffrin, Perez 6/e.

PUBLIC DELIBERATION, PRIVATE COMMUNICATION, AND COLLECTIVE CHOICE

The Youth Vote in 2008 By Emily Hoban Kirby and Kei Kawashima-Ginsberg 1 Updated August 17, 2009

1 The Drama of the Commons

Experiments in Political Economy 1

policy-making. footnote We adopt a simple parametric specification which allows us to go between the two polar cases studied in this literature.

Cooperation and Self-interested behavior A Field Experiment in Ivorian plantain sector 1

Extended Abstract: The Swing Voter s Curse in Social Networks

Department of Economics Working Paper

On the Selection of Arbitrators

Resource Allocations and Disapproval Voting in Unequal Groups

IDEOLOGY. Paul H. Rubin

Game Theory and the Law: The Legal-Rules-Acceptability Theorem (A rationale for non-compliance with legal rules)

An Experimental Investigation of Electoral Delegation and the Provision of Public Goods

Voting. Suppose that the outcome is determined by the mean of all voter s positions.

Transcription:

Experimental economics and public choice Lisa R. Anderson and Charles A. Holt June 2002 Prepared for the Encyclopedia of Public Choice, Charles Rowley, ed. There is a well-established tradition of using laboratory techniques to study issues in public choice, dating back to the 1970 s. For example, Fiorina and Plott (1978) and Plott and Levine (1978) reported results of voting experiments, and Bohm (1972) used an experimental approach to estimate demand for public goods. This connection is reflected in the fact that the Economic Science Association (of experimental social scientists) meets jointly with the Public Choice Society each spring in the United States. This chapter provides a selective survey of experiments on public goods, common pool resources, rent seeking, and voting. Experiments have revealed that people do free ride on others contributions to public goods, but the problem is not as severe as economists once thought. A typical public goods experiment involves a group of people who must decide whether to contribute to a group project or account. For example, Ensminger (2001) divided a sample of East African men into groups of four. Each person was given 50 shillings and offered the opportunity to contribute some, all, or none to a group project. The men placed their contributions in envelopes that were collected and shuffled (to preserve anonymity) and counted in front of the group. All contributions were doubled and then divided equally among the four participants. For example, a contribution of 10 shillings would be doubled to 20 and divided 4 ways, for a return of 5 shillings per person. Therefore, the individual receives a private benefit of ½ for each shilling contributed to the group project. In the public goods literature, this private benefit is called the marginal per capita return (MPCR). With a group of size N, the social benefit for each shilling contributed to the group project is N times the MPCR. There is a social dilemma when the MPCR is less than 1 and greater than 1/N, which is typically the case for a public goods experiment.

2 With a group of size 4 and an MPCR of ½, Ensminger observed that about 60 percent of the shilling endowments were contributed to the group project. This contribution level is slightly higher than the 40 to 60 percent range that is commonly observed in the first round of a public goods experiment involving college students in the United States (Anderson, 2001 and Ledyard, 1995). Nearly 200 public goods experiments have been conducted (see the Y2K Bibliography of Experimental Economics at http://www.people.virginia.edu/~cah2k/y2k.htm). The main finding is that significant contributions are observed despite the individual incentive to free ride. Economists have designed experiments with a variety of treatments to better understand motives for contributing. Altruism provides one possible explanation, since contributions may be rational if enough utility is derived from helping others. Many studies have shown that an increase in the MPCR raises contributions, but the interpretation of this result is complicated by the fact that the MPCR affects both one s private return (the internal return ) and the benefit to others (the external return ). It is possible to hold the internal return constant (e.g., at ½) and increase the external return for each token contributed (e.g., ¾). Goeree, Holt and Laury (2002) report that contributions are positively related to the external return, holding the internal return constant. Not surprisingly, contributions are also positively related to the internal return. Another implication of altruism is that contributions will be higher as the number of beneficiaries (i.e. group size) increases, and this is supported by a number of studies. These results are summarized in the first four rows of table 1. All of the experiments discussed thus far were done for a single round. In a multiround experiment some people might reciprocate by contributing more in response to cooperative actions of others. Such reciprocity also opens up the possibility for strategic behavior, where a person might contribute more in early rounds to encourage others to do the same. This explanation is consistent with the observation that contributions decline with repetition. Contributions are also somewhat lower for people who have participated in a public goods experiment on a previous date. Despite the negative effect of repetition and experience on contribution rates, some people contribute in all rounds. 2

3 Table 1. Treatment effects in public goods experiments. Variable Study Effect on contribution rates MPCR Isaac and Walker (1988) Positive Internal Return Goeree, Holt and Laury (2002) Positive External Return Goeree, Holt and Laury (2002) Positive Group Size Isaac, Walker, and Williams (1994) Positive Repetition Isaac, Walker and Thomas (1984) Negative Experience Isaac, Walker and Thomas (1984) Negative Anonymity Laury, Walker and Williams (1995) None Communication Isaac and Walker (1988) Positive Another explanation for positive contributions is that people do not want to appear to be stingy to the researcher, who generally tracks each individual s contributions. This explanation is not supported by the work of Laury, Walker and Williams (1995), who ran parallel treatments; in one case they tracked individual contributions and in the other they did not. Contributions have also been observed to depend on factors such as the ability of subjects to communicate in advance, the presence of a required level of contribution (provision point), and the ability to exclude or punish non-contributors. Just as a contribution to a public good provides a positive externality, the use of a common pool resource provides a negative externality by reducing the value to other users. A classic example of a common pool resource is a fishery, where an increase in one person s harvest may reduce the productivity of others fishing efforts. In a standard common pool resource experiment, each person chooses a level of effort (or usage), and the average product is a decreasing function of the sum of all efforts. Alternatively, each person can allocate effort to a private investment that has a fixed return. This is analogous to a Cournot model where individuals ignore the negative externalities associated with 3

4 their own quantity decisions, and the resulting Nash equilibrium quantity is too high relative to the socially optimal level. Gardner, Ostrom and Walker (1990) report that aggregate usage is higher than the socially optimal level and is often close to the Nash equilibrium prediction, but there is considerable variability in behavior across individuals. Many people devote all effort to the common pool resource as long as the average product exceeds the private return and otherwise switch all effort to the private investment. Over thirty papers on this topic can be found at http://www.people.virginia.edu/~cah2k/y2k.htm. Many papers examine factors that mitigate the amount of overuse, such as communication and monitoring. Another topic that has been investigated with experimental methods is the effect of rent-seeking activities. The standard rent-seeking experiment is based on the simplest Tullock (1980) model in which the probability of obtaining a prize is equal to one s share of the total lobbying activity. Each subject chooses a level of lobbying activity, and the payoff is the prize, if it is obtained, minus the person s own lobbying cost. In a Nash equilibrium for this game, the fraction of the value of the prize that is dissipated is an increasing function of the number of competitors. Experiments show that the total cost of rent-seeking activity is significant and greater than predicted in a Nash equilibrium (Millner and Pratt, 1989 and 1991; Davis and Reilly, 1998). Moreover, an increase in the number of contenders tends to raise the total cost of this rent-seeking activity (Holt, 2002 chapter 29; and Anderson and Stafford, 2002). One area of public choice where there has been a considerable amount of disagreement is voting behavior. As a consequence, this is a fruitful area for experimental research. Early voting experiments focused on testing theoretical concepts, such as the core. Support for this notion is reported in Fiorina and Plott (1978) and Plott (1991). Subsequent studies investigated whether or not voters behave strategically in agendacontrolled committee meetings. Strategic voting requires that decisions made in the initial stages of a meeting are rational given correct expectations about what will happen in subsequent stages. Not surprisingly, subjects tend to behave more myopically in such situations (Plott and Levine, 1978). Strategic voting is more likely to arise after subjects have gained considerable experience in prior meetings (Eckel and Holt, 1989). Additionally, a considerable amount of strategic voting has been observed in single-stage 4

5 voting games where backward induction is not required (Rapoport, Felsenthal and Maoz, 1991). Recent voting experiments have studied alternatives to majority rule. For example, Forsythe et. al. (1996) compared voting outcomes with majority rule, Borda rule and approval voting. Additionally, McKelvey and Palfrey (1998) compared outcomes with unanimity versus majority rule. A number of excellent survey papers and collected volumes cover the topics discussed above in more depth. Ledyard (1995) is the standard reference for public goods experiments. Holt and Laury (2002) survey the more recent research on treatment effects in public goods experiments. Kinder and Palfrey (1993) is a collection of experimental papers on various topics in political science including survey-based experiments and bureaucratic agenda control. Finally, many of the experiments described above have been adapted for classroom use: Holt and Laury (1997) for public goods, Holt and Anderson (1999) for strategic voting, Goeree and Holt (1999) for rent seeking, Anderson and Stafford (2001) for tradable pollution permits, and Hewett et al. (2002) for the Tiebout hypothesis and the median voter theorem. Web-based versions of many of these experiments can be found at http://veconlab.econ.virginia.edu/admin.htm. LISA R. ANDERSON Associate Professor of Economics College of William and Mary CHARLES A. HOLT Merrill Bankard Professor of Economics University of Virginia 5

6 References Anderson, L. (2001). Public choice as an experimental science. In W. Shugart and L. Razzolini (Eds.), The Elgar companion to public choice, chapter 23. Northhampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing. Anderson, L. and S. Stafford (2001). Choosing winners and losers in a permit trading game. Southern Economic Journal 67(1): 212-219. Anderson, L. and S. Stafford (2002). An experimental analysis of rent seeking under varying competitive conditions. Public Choice forthcoming. Bohm, P. (1972). Estimating demand for public goods: An experiment. European Economic Review 3(2): 111-130. Davis, D. and R. Reilly (1998). Do too many cooks always spoil the stew? An experimental analysis of rent-seeking and the role of a strategic buyer. Public Choice 95(1-2): 89 115. Eckel, C. and C. A. Holt (1989). Strategic voting in agenda-controlled committee experiments. American Economic Review 79(4): 763 73. Ensminger, J. (2001). Market integration and fairness: evidence from ultimatum, dictator, and public goods experiments in East Africa. Discussion Paper, California Institute of Technology. Fiorina, M. P. and C. R. Plott (1978). Committee decisions under majority rule: An experimental study. American Political Science Review 72(2): 575 98. Forsythe, R., T. Rietz, R. Myerson and R.Weber (1996). An experimental study of voting rules and polls in three-candidate elections. International Journal of Game Theory 25(3): 355 83. Gardner, R., E.Ostrom and J. M. Walker (1990). The nature of common pool resource problems. Rationality and Society 2: 335-358. Goeree, J. and C. Holt (1999). Classroom Games: Rent seeking and the inefficiency of non-market allocations. Journal of Economic Perspectives 13(3): 217-226. Goeree, J., C. Holt and S. Laury (2002). Private costs and public benefits: Unraveling the effects of altruism and noisy behavior. Journal of Public Economics 83(2): 257-278. 6

7 Hewitt, R., C. Holt, G. Kosmopoulou, C. Kymn, C. Long, S. Mousavi, and S. Sarang (2002). Voting with feet and with ballots: A classroom experiment, Discussion Paper, University of Virginia. Holt, C. (2002). Webgames and strategy: Recipes for interactive learning. Unpublished manuscript, University of Virginia. Holt, C.A. and L. R. Anderson (1999). Agendas and strategic voting. Southern Economic Journal 65(3): 622 29. Holt, C.A. and S. K. Laury (2002). Theoretical explanations of treatment effects in voluntary contributions experiments. In C. R. Plott and V. L. Smith (eds), The Handbook of Experimental Economics Results, Amsterdam: North-Holland, forthcoming. Holt, C. and S. Laury (1997). Classroom games: Voluntary provision of a public good. Journal of Economic Perspectives 11(4): 209-215. Isaac, R. M. and J. M. Walker (1988). Communication and free-riding behavior: The voluntary contributions mechanism. Economic Inquiry 26(4): 585 608. Isaac, R. M., J. M. Walker and A. W. Williams (1994). Group size and the voluntary provision of public goods: Experimental evidence utilizing large groups. Journal of Public Economics 54(1): 1-36. Isaac, R. M., J. M. Walker and S. H. Thomas (1984). Divergent evidence on free riding: An experimental examination of possible explanation. Public Choice 43(2): 113-149. Kinder, D. and T. Palfrey, eds. (1993). Experimental Foundations of Political Science. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Laury, S. K., J. M. Walker and A.W. Williams (1995). Anonymity and the voluntary provision of public goods. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 27(3): 365 80. Ledyard, J. (1995). Public goods: A survey of experimental research. In J. H. Kagel and A.E. Roth (eds.), The Handbook of Experimental Economics, 111-194, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. McKelvey, R.D. and T. R. Palfrey (1998). An experimental study of jury decisions. unpublished manuscript, California Institute of Technology. 7

8 Millner, E.L. and M.D. Pratt (1989). An experimental investigation of efficient rent seeking. Public Choice 62(2): 139 51. Millner, E.L. and M.D. Pratt (1991). Risk aversion and rent seeking: An extension and some experimental evidence. Public Choice 69(1): 91 92. Plott, C. R. (1991). A comparative analysis of direct democracy, two-candidate elections and three-candidate elections in an experimental environment. In T. Palfrey (ed.), Laboratory research in political economy, 11-31, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Plott, C.R. and M.E. Levine (1978). A model of agenda influence on committee decisions. American Economic Review 68(1): 146 60. Rapoport, A., D. S. Felsenthal and Z. Maoz (1991). Sincere versus strategic voting behavior in small groups. In T. Palfrey (ed.), Laboratory research in political economy, 201-235, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent seeking in J. M. Buchanan, R. D. Tollison and G. Tullock (eds) Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society, 97-112, College Station: Texas A&M University Press. 8