INTERNATIONAL TRADE. (prepared for the Social Science Encyclopedia, Third Edition, edited by A. Kuper and J. Kuper)

Similar documents
International Business Economics

Advanced Studies in International Economic Policy Research, International Trade: Theory and Policy

Organized by. In collaboration with. Posh Raj Pandey South Asia Watch on Trade, Economics & Environment (SAWTEE)

International Trade Theory Professor Giovanni Facchini. Corse Outline and Reading List

W. J. Ethier January The Literature

Institut für Weltwirtschaft. Advanced Studies in International Economic Policy Research, INTERNATIONAL TRADE

I N T E R N AT I O N A L T R A D E T H E O RY A N D E V I D E N C E. Maria Luigia Segnana with Andrea Fracasso and Giuseppe Vittucci-Marzetti

UNIVERSITY OF COLORADO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Course Outline

INTERNATIONAL TRADE: THEORY, EVIDENCE AND POLICY

W. J. Ethier April Feenstra, Advanced International Trade (Princeton, 2004). (denoted F below).

Econ 340. Lecture 4 Modern Theories and Additional Effects of Trade

ECONOMICS 825 INTERNATIONAL TRADE THEORY FALL 2003

Readings for Ph.D. Students

Winter 2001 Assaf Razin - Landau 150, ext Economics 266 INTERNATIONAL TRADE THEORY

University of Maryland Department of Economics. International Trade Theory

The Political Economy of Trade Policy

International Trade Theory MF 10:30 Fall Syllabus. (2) a mid-term exam Nov. 3 (3) a final exam, date TBA

Econ 825 Winter 2011: Readings in International Trade

UNIVERSITY OF COLORADO BOULDER, COLORADO. Course Outline and Reading List

Pao-Li Chang 90 Stamford Road, Singapore

Political Science 12: IR -- Sixth Lecture, Part 1

1. Free trade refers to a situation where a government does not attempt to influence through quotas

Economics 791: Topics in International Trade Syllabus: Fall 2008

Trade theory and regional integration

Globalisation and inequality: is Heckscher-Ohlin theory dead? Adrian Wood University of Oxford

University of Oxford, Michaelmas Term International Trade I

INTRODUCTION YAO PAN

Economics 281a / Management 209 Schedule of Classes, Fall Quarter 2002

INTERNATIONAL TRADE & ECONOMICS LAW: THEORIES OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND ECONOMICS

Chapter 11 Evaluating the Controversy between Free Trade and Protectionism

THE GEORGE WASHINGTON UNIVERSITY Department of Economics

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin

International Economics, 10e (Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz) Chapter 2 World Trade: An Overview. 2.1 Who Trades with Whom?

ECONOMICS 825 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS

Wage inequality and skill premium

COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE

Lecture: INTERNATIONAL TRADE

AED ECONOMICS 6200 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS AND POLICY. Additional Reading. 1. Trade Equilibrium, Gains from Trade; and Comparative Advantage

International trade and trade policies

SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

A General Overview of the Political Economy of Trade

ADJUSTMENT TO TRADE POLICY IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

EC 591. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS Professor R Lucas: Fall 2018 Monday and Wednesday ROOM CAS 227

International Political Economy

International Trade: Lecture 5

Comparative Advantage

McGILL UNIVERSITY Department of Economics ECON POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE POLICY 1 WINTER 2018

Mohammad Ghodsi: Summary of Ph.D. Dissertation Trade Policy, Trade Conflicts, Determinants, and Consequences of Protectionism

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Notes on exam in International Economics, 16 January, Answer the following five questions in a short and concise fashion: (5 points each)

ECON/ABIZ Theory of International Trade

Debapriya Bhattacharya Executive Director, CPD. Mustafizur Rahman Research Director, CPD. Ananya Raihan Research Fellow, CPD

Advanced International Trade

Chapter 4. Preview. Introduction. Resources, Comparative Advantage, and Income Distribution

ECON/ABIZ Theory of International Trade

INTERNATIONAL TRADE THEORY J.F. Francois TI541, Tinbergen Institute, Erasmus University Rotterdam, Fall 2005.

NPTEL

Trade and Wages What Are the Questions?

Source: Piketty Saez. Share (in %), excluding capital gains. Figure 1: The top decile income share in the U.S., % 45% 40% 35% 30% 25%

Comparative Advantage. Erik Gartzke, Ph.D.

Theoretical approaches to the analysis of trade and poverty and a review of related literature on South Africa

Introduction to WTO Law

Lahore University of Management Sciences BSc. Program Spring ECON 351 International Trade. Course Outline

ECONOMICS 6421 (FALL 2009) ADVANCED INTERNATIONAL TRADE: THEORY AND POLICY

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Trade and the distributional politics of international labour standards

Factor content of trade

Comparative Advantage. Erik Gartzke POLI 142 A Lec 7A - 23 August 2010

The Development of FTA Rules of Origin Functions

AED ECONOMICS 6200 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS AND POLICY. Additional Reading. 1. Trade Equilibrium, Gains from Trade; and Comparative Advantage

Trade, Migration and Inequality in a World without Factor Price Equalisation

At the end of Chapter 27, you will be able to answer the following questions:

Trade Liberalization and Wage Inequality in India: A Mandated Wage Equation Approach

Growth in Open Economies, Schumpeterian Models

International Trade & Income Inequality in Japan

International Business

Evaluating Stolper-Samuelson: Trade Liberalization & Wage Inequality in India

First Midterm. Time allowed: 50 minutes. Please answer ALL questions. The total score is 100. Please budget your time wisely.

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France

International Economics. Dr Wioletta Nowak

Powered by TCPDF (

Although others are clearly important and they are obviously inter-related, I am only talking about trade liberalisation.

Follow links Class Use and other Permissions. For more information, send to:

ECONOMICS 825 INTERNATIONAL TRADE THEORY

Volume Title: Trade Policy Issues and Empirical Analysis. Volume URL:

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization

Joint Report on the EU-Canada Scoping Exercise March 5, 2009

Ch. 6 Free Trade. Organizing the Marketplace Introduction to International Relations

EC 591. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS Professor R Lucas: Fall 2012 Monday & Wednesday SSW 315

Discussion. 1. Judith Sloan

Regional Economic Integration: Theoretical Concepts and their Application to the ASEAN Economic Community

GRAVITY EQUATIONS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE. based on Chapter 5 of Advanced international trade: theory and evidence by R. C. Feenstra (2004, PUP)

CONFLICT AND COOPERATION IN INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC POLICY AND LAW

UNION COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, FALL 2004 ECO 146 SEMINAR IN GLOBAL ECONOMIC ISSUES GLOBALIZATION AND LABOR MARKETS

CIEE Barcelona, Spain

Open Trade, Closed Borders Immigration Policy in the Era of Globalization

Trade, Migration and Inequality in a World without Factor Price Equalisation

Summary UNICE: POST-CANCUN TRADE AND INVESTMENT STRATEGY. 5 December 2003

international law of contemporary media session 7: the law of the world trade organization

Course Outline for Economics 2300: International Trade Fall, 2003 Daniel Trefler

Transcription:

INTERNATIONAL TRADE (prepared for the Social Science Encyclopedia, Third Edition, edited by A. Kuper and J. Kuper) J. Peter Neary University College Dublin 25 September 2003 Address for correspondence: J. Peter Neary Department of Economics University College Dublin Belfield, Dublin 4, Ireland Tel.: +353-1-716 8334 FAX: +353-1-283 0068 e-mail: peter.neary@ucd.ie home page: http://www.ucd.ie/~economic/staff/pneary/neary.htm.

International trade is not intrinsically different from transactions in which commodities do not cross national boundaries. Nevertheless, the study of international trade has traditionally constituted a separate branch of microeconomics. It may be distinguished from other branches by its focus on situations where some but not all goods and factors are mobile between countries; and from international macroeconomics by its focus on real rather than nominal variables (trade flows and relative prices rather than exchange rates and money supplies), and by a tendency to examine medium-run issues using equilibrium analysis rather than short-run positions of disequilibrium. One of the first and most durable contributions to the analysis of international trade is the principle of comparative advantage developed by David Ricardo in 1817. This is the antecedent of both the normative and positive strands of international trade theory. At a normative level, it postulates that an absolutely inefficient country will nevertheless gain from trade; and at a positive level, it predicts the direction of trade: each country will tend to export those goods which it produces relatively cheaply in the absence of trade. As an explanation of trade patterns, the principle has met with some success. However, in its classical form it is open to two objections: it assumes unrealistically that unit production costs are independent of scale or factor proportions; and it fails to explain why they differ between countries in the first place. A theory which overcomes these deficiencies was developed in the first third of the twentieth century by the Swedish economists Eli Heckscher and Bertil Ohlin, who stressed international differences in factor endowments as the basis for comparative advantage and trade. Thus a country which is relatively capital-abundant will tend to export goods which are produced by relatively capital-intensive techniques. Largely through the influence of the American economist Paul Samuelson, a simplified version of this theory, assuming only two goods and two factors in each country, has come to dominate the textbooks. In this form it

is a useful teaching device for introducing some basic concepts of general equilibrium theory but, not surprisingly, it is overwhelmingly rejected by the data. The most notable example of this is the so-called Leontief Paradox, an early application by Wassily Leontief of his technique of input-output analysis, which found that the presumably capital-abundant United States exported labour-intensive commodities, thus contradicting the theory. Nevertheless, for most economists probably the preferred explanation of trade patterns between countries at different levels of economic development is an eclectic theory of comparative advantage along Heckscher-Ohlin lines, allowing for many factors of production, some of them (such as natural resources) specific to individual sectors. However, this theory fails to account adequately for certain features of contemporary international trade, especially between advanced economies with similar technology and factor endowments. Such trade is frequently intra-industry, involving both exports and imports of differentiated products within a single industry. Recent theories explain such trade in terms of imperfectly competitive firms producing under conditions of increasing returns. Attention has also focused on the increased international mobility of factors, in part through the medium of multinational corporations. The level of foreign direct investment, both in the form of "greenfield" investment (building new plants) and cross-border mergers and acquisitions, has increased even more than that of trade in recent decades. The increased flows of goods, factors and ideas associated with these trends constrain domestic policy-makers, so posing a wide range of problems often grouped together under the catch-all term "globalisation". As well as attempting to explain the pattern of trade, positive trade theory also makes predictions about many aspects of open economies. Best known of these is the implication of the Heckscher-Ohlin model known as the factor price equalization theorem. This predicts that, under certain circumstances, free trade will equalise the prices of internationally 2

immobile factors; more generally, it suggests that as more and more markets are opened to international trade, the remaining domestic markets become more exposed to foreign shocks and less to domestic ones. The theory also makes predictions concerning such issues as the effects of tariffs and international transfers on foreign and domestic prices, the effects of trade policy on domestic income distribution and the consequences of structural change. Turning to normative trade theory, it has traditionally focused on the merits of free trade relative to autarky, stemming from a production gain (as the home economy specialises more according to its comparative advantage) and a consumption gain (as consumers are no longer constrained to consume only domestically produced goods). Similar arguments favour partially restricted trade relative to autarky, although the benefits of discriminatory trade liberalization (such as the formation of a customs union by a sub-group of countries) are not as clearcut. Recent work on trade under imperfect competition has pointed towards additional sources of gain: trade may lead home firms to produce at lower cost and, by exposing them to foreign competition, at higher efficiency levels; and consumers may gain from increased diversity of choice. Two exceptions to the case for free trade are normally admitted. The optimal tariff argument states that a country with sufficient market power can gain by behaving like a monopolist and restricting the supply of its exports. The infant-industry argument defends transitional protection to enable a new industry to benefit from learning and scale economies. (As with many arguments for trade restriction, the latter on closer examination is less an argument against free trade than against laissez faire.) Recent work on strategic trade policy has added to these arguments the possibility that a government s ability to precommit to tariffs or subsidies may allow it to give an advantage to home firms competing against foreign rivals in oligopolistic markets. Notwithstanding these arguments for restricting trade, and the 3

absence of conclusive empirical evidence in its favour, most economists subscribe to a pragmatic case for free trade, while recognising that the benefits of rapid integration into the world economy may well be offset by the costs in the short run. The persistence of protectionist sentiment, despite these theoretical arguments, may be explained by the fact that gains from trade accruing to the economy as a whole are not inconsistent with losses to individual groups, especially owners of factors specific to importcompeting sectors. The textbook Heckscher-Ohlin model illustrates this principle with the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem, which predicts that (for example) increased imports of unskilledlabour-intensive goods will lower the wages of unskilled relative to skilled workers. Empirical evidence suggests that technological change rather than trade is the main culprit for the increased return to skills in developed countries. Nevertheless, organised workers and shareholders in import-competing industries, and other special interest groups, have incentives to lobby for protection, which may explain why trade remains considerably more restricted internationally than domestically. Other special models have been developed to deal with important features of contemporary international trade. Thus, the growth of trade in intermediate goods (as opposed to goods for final consumption) has inspired the theory of effective protection, which builds on the insight that an industry benefits from tariffs on its outputs but is harmed by tariffs on its inputs. Changes in technology have made possible a process of vertical disintegration or fragmentation of production, as firms source their inputs from, or locate different parts of their production chain in, different countries. Falls in transport costs also appear to have encouraged agglomeration of economic activity, as firms locate near their competitors to benefit from lower input costs or improved access to consumers. The enormous growth in world trade since the Second World War has been driven in 4

part by steady declines in trade barriers. Some of these have taken place as a result of the formation of customs unions or free-trade agreements, such as the European Union (formerly the EEC) and the North American Free-Trade Agreement. However, most trade liberalisation has resulted from multilateral negotiations under the auspices of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), formally reconstituted in 1995 as the World Trade Organisation (WTO). Successive rounds of negotiations have had to contend with new forms of trade restrictions, as the decline in importance of tariffs (at least between developed countries) has focused attention on the widespread use of non-tariff barriers (such as quotas, health and safety regulations and government procurement policies) as methods of restricting trade. J. Peter Neary University College Dublin 5

Further Reading Grossman, G. and E. Helpman (2002), Interest Groups and Trade Policy, Princeton: Princeton University Press. Grossman, G. and K. Rogoff (eds) (1995), Handbook of International Economics, Volume III, Amsterdam: North-Holland. Hoekman, B., A. Mattoo and P. English (eds) (2002), Development, Trade, and the WTO: A Handbook, Washington, D.C.: The World Bank. Jones R.W. and P.B. Kenen (eds) (1984), Handbook of International Economics: Volume 1, Amsterdam. (1405 words of text; 1535 words in total) 6