Negotiation democracy versus consensus democracy: Parallel conclusions and recommendations

Similar documents
CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE?

If a party s share of the overall party vote entitles it to five seats, but it wins six electorates, the sixth seat is called an overhang seat.

Electoral Systems and Evaluations of Democracy

Australian Democracy: Modifying Majoritarianism?

Consensus or Conflict? Legislative Behaviour of Opposition Parties during Minority Government in Denmark

THE U.S. POLITICAL SYSTEM AND THE 2014 MIDTERM ELECTION. Hans Noel Georgetown University bit.ly/hansnoel

Ballots not Bullets. Ethnic Conflict & Electoral Systems Pippa Norris KSG Harvard University

RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity

Parliamentary Election Turnout in Europe since 1990

Elections and referendums

The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics

Arguments for and against electoral system change in Ireland

Parliamentary vs. Presidential Systems

ONTARIO SUPERIOR COURT OF JUSTICE. JOAN RUSSOW and THE GREEN PARTY OF CANADA. - and -

THE IMPLICATIONS OF INSTITUTIONAL DESIGN FOR MACROECONOMIC PERFORMANCE Reassessing the Claims of Consensus Democracy

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

EMPIRICAL AND NORMATIVE MODELS OF VOTERS, PARTIES, AND GOVERNMENTS

BCGEU surveyed its own members on electoral reform. They reported widespread disaffection with the current provincial electoral system.

KNOW THY DATA AND HOW TO ANALYSE THEM! STATISTICAL AD- VICE AND RECOMMENDATIONS

Swiss Party System, Political Processes and Interaction with Society Presentation held by Claude Longchamp

Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each

The Politics of Emotional Confrontation in New Democracies: The Impact of Economic

AmericasBarometer Insights: 2011 Number 63

Part Three (continued): Electoral Systems & Linkage Institutions

TYPES OF GOVERNMENTS

A Vote Equation and the 2004 Election

Tzu-chiao Su Chinese Culture University, Taiwan

Parity democracy A far cry from reality.

CASTLES, Francis G. (Edit.). The impact of parties: politics and policies in democratic capitalist states. Sage Publications, 1982.

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

VOTING ON INCOME REDISTRIBUTION: HOW A LITTLE BIT OF ALTRUISM CREATES TRANSITIVITY DONALD WITTMAN ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA

Institutionalization: New Concepts and New Methods. Randolph Stevenson--- Rice University. Keith E. Hamm---Rice University

Introduction Why Don t Electoral Rules Have the Same Effects in All Countries?

What criteria should guide electoral system choice?

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

Comparing the Data Sets

NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Department of Politics V COMPARATIVE POLITICS Spring Michael Laver. Tel:

Two Pictures of the Global-justice Debate: A Reply to Tan*

The Political Economy of Public Policy

NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Department of Politics. V COMPARATIVE POLITICS Spring Michael Laver Tel:

SUMMARY. Migration. Integration in the labour market

The evolution of turnout in European elections from 1979 to 2009

Attitudes towards minority groups in the European Union

Voter Turnout: Ideologically Swayed? Exploring Effects of Ideologically Extreme Parties on OECD Countries

Comparing Foreign Political Systems Focus Questions for Unit 1

Women s. Political Representation & Electoral Systems. Key Recommendations. Federal Context. September 2016

Polimetrics. Lecture 2 The Comparative Manifesto Project

The role of Social Cultural and Political Factors in explaining Perceived Responsiveness of Representatives in Local Government.

Electoral Reform Questionnaire Field Dates: October 12-18, 2016

MODELLING EXISTING SURVEY DATA FULL TECHNICAL REPORT OF PIDOP WORK PACKAGE 5

Human development in China. Dr Zhao Baige

The California Primary and Redistricting

The Crime Drop in Florida: An Examination of the Trends and Possible Causes

Comparative Political Economy. David Soskice Nuffield College

Spring 2012 T, R 11:00-12:15 2SH 304. Pols 234 Western European Politics and Government

Study. Importance of the German Economy for Europe. A vbw study, prepared by Prognos AG Last update: February 2018

DHSLCalc.xls What is it? How does it work? Describe in detail what I need to do

EUROBAROMETER 71 PUBLIC OPINION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION SPRING

Explaining mandate fulfilment: two models of democracy

European Parliament Eurobarometer (EB79.5) ONE YEAR TO GO UNTIL THE 2014 EUROPEAN ELECTIONS Institutional Part ANALYTICAL OVERVIEW

Gender pay gap in public services: an initial report

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 6: An Examination of Iowa Absentee Voting Since 2000

Challenges to established parties: The effects of party system features on the electoral fortunes of anti-political-establishment parties

Constitutional Choices for New Democracies

4 However, devolution would have better served the people of Wales if a better voting system had been used. At present:

What factors are responsible for the distribution of responsibilities between the state, social partners and markets in ALMG? (covered in part I)

Georg Lutz, Nicolas Pekari, Marina Shkapina. CSES Module 5 pre-test report, Switzerland

Why do some societies produce more inequality than others?

The Politics of Fiscal Austerity: Can Democracies Act With Foresight? Paul Posner George Mason University

Do Ideological Differences Determine Whether Center-Right Parties Cooperate with the Radical Right?

INFORMATION SHEETS: 2

Agenda Setting and Executive Dominance in Politics

The Formation of National Party Systems Does it happen with age? Brandon Amash

Liberal political equality implies proportional representation

Runoff Elections and the Number of Presidential Candidates A Regression Discontinuity Design Using Brazilian Municipalities

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018

ANU College of Arts & Social Sciences

Centripetal Democratic Governance: A Theory and Global Inquiry

EU Ornamental Fish Import & Export Statistics 2016 (Third Countries & Intra-EU Community trade)

To link to this article:

Case Study: Get out the Vote

GLOBALIZATION AND THE GREAT U-TURN: INCOME INEQUALITY TRENDS IN 16 OECD COUNTRIES. Arthur S. Alderson

Poznan July The vulnerability of the European Elite System under a prolonged crisis

Letter prices in Europe. Up-to-date international letter price survey. March th edition

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems

EU Ornamental Fish Import & Export Statistics 2017 (Third Countries & Intra-EU Community trade)

THRESHOLDS. Underlying principles. What submitters on the party vote threshold said

Banana policy: a European perspective {

British Election Leaflet Project - Data overview

Congruence in Political Parties

The Politics of Egalitarian Capitalism; Rethinking the Trade-off between Equality and Efficiency

LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men

Does Government Ideology affect Personal Happiness? A Test

DANISH TECHNOLOGICAL INSTITUTE. Supporting Digital Literacy Public Policies and Stakeholder Initiatives. Topic Report 2.

INDIGENOUS ELECTORAL REPRESENTATION IN INTERNATIONAL HUMAN RIGHTS LAW

COLORADO LOTTERY 2014 IMAGE STUDY

Homework 4 solutions

OECD Strategic Education Governance A perspective for Scotland. Claire Shewbridge 25 October 2017 Edinburgh

Equity and Excellence in Education from International Perspectives

Transcription:

European Journal of Political Research 41: 107 113, 2002 107 Negotiation democracy versus consensus democracy: Parallel conclusions and recommendations AREND LIJPHART Department of Political Science, University of California-San Diego, USA Abstract. In spite of a large number of disagreements concerning methodological and classificatory questions between Klaus Armingeon and myself, our substantive conclusions are very similar. Armingeon concludes that all three aspects of his negotiation democracy (consociationalism, corporatism, and counter-majoritarian institutions) result in superior government performance in selected areas a finding that I interpret as supportive of my similar claims for the executives-parties dimension of consensus democracy (which consists of consociationalism plus corporatism) as well as for the federal-unitary dimension (which is the same as Armingeon s counter-majoritarian institutions). We are therefore also in broad agreement on the advice we can give to democratic constitutional engineers. Klaus Armingeon s critical re-analysis and further analysis of the performance of different types of democracy is precisely the kind of work that I hoped my book Patterns of Democracy would stimulate, and that I tried to encourage by including many of my basic data in an appendix to my book, as well as by offering to make my entire data set available to other scholars at their request. 1 I was also pleased to read his article because, while we disagree on quite a few details of both substance and methods I shall respond to Armingeon s list of seven criticisms point by point below I believe that our main substantive conclusions do not diverge a great deal; they may not coincide completely, but they run largely parallel to each other. This is particularly true of the policy implications and the practical recommendations that flow from his and my findings a point to which I shall return at the end of my remarks. How does my consensus democracy differ from Armingeon s negotiation democracy? Negotiation democracy consists of three types, which Armingeon calls consociational democracy, corporatism, and regimes with strong veto players (counter-majoritarian institutions); for simplicity s sake, I shall follow his terminology in the remainder of this discussion. Consensus democracy has two separate and distinct dimensions that I have called the executives-parties and federal-unitary dimensions. Armingeon s veto player type and my federal-unitary dimension coincide completely. Therefore, the only difference between us is that Armingeon prefers to divide my executives-parties dimension into two separate types. Published by Blackwell Publishers, 108 Cowley Road, Oxford, OX4 1JF and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA

108 arend lijphart I certainly agree with Armingeon that there are important differences between the two. First of all, consociationalism is defined in terms of the more purely political actors and actions (types of cabinets, executive-legislative relations, and party and electoral systems), while corporatism has to do with macro-economic actors and policy. Second, the characteristics of consociationalism are linked by a structural cause-and-effect chain: proportional election systems tend to produce multi-party systems, which in turn tend to produce multi-party coalition cabinets and an executive-legislative balance of power (in contrast with plurality systems that tend to yield two-party systems, one-party majority cabinets, and executive dominance). There is no such direct structural link with corporatism; instead the connection is via political culture. For instance, Peter J. Katzenstein (1985: 32, 157) writes that an ideology of social partnership and the absence of a winner-take-all mentality are distinctive traits of corporatism; these cultural characteristics are shared by corporatism and the other, more political, characteristics of consociationalism alike. Third, I readily concede that some of the desirable consequences of consensus democracy may be attributed to particular components of it which operate as the specific causal agents. For instance, I credit their good performance with regard to voter participation and women s representation to one of their usual characteristics: proportional representation (Lijphart 1999: 286). Similarly, some favourable consequences associated with consensus democracy may be specifically caused by the fact that consensus democracies tend to have corporatist institutions. The overall good fit between the consociational and corporatist characteristics was confirmed by my factor analysis. In fact, the correlation (factor loading) between corporatism and the factor representing the executives-parties dimension is 0.78, slightly stronger than the correlations of electoral proportionality and executive-legislative balance with this factor (Lijphart 1999: 246). While acknowledging the differences between consociationalism and corporatism, I think that it is still reasonable to see them as a syndrome of closely related traits. Let me now turn to Armingeon s list of seven criticisms. First, Armingeon prefers to analyze the 22 OECD countries instead of my 36 countries which, as he correctly points out, represent very different levels of socio-economic development. 2 I have been a strong advocate myself of the comparative method which entails the selection of comparable cases for analysis in order to mitigate the small N/large number of variables problem (Lijphart 1970, 1975). This approach is especially advisable if a large number of variables can simultaneously be held constant and if the number of cases does not have to be reduced too drastically. But Armingeon gains the advantage of having one less (albeit undoubtedly important) variable to worry about, at the cost of

negotiation democracy versus consensus democracy 109 having 14 fewer cases which strikes me as a questionable sacrifice of a lot of degrees of freedom. What I should also point out is that I often report results for the OECD countries only by necessity rather than as a conscious choice for all those dependent variables on which no reliable data were available for non-oecd countries (e.g., unemployment, budget deficits, differential satisfaction with democracy, and government-voter proximity) or on which more reliable information could be used for the OECD countries rather than for my full set of countries. In the latter situation, I presented the results for both the full set and the OECD subset (e.g., economic growth, inflation, and income inequality). 3 What I easily could have done in addition and what, in retrospect, I believe I should have done, is to systematically present the correlations for both the full set and the OECD subset even when the same data were used. Let me take advantage of this response to Armingeon s article to quickly make up for this omission with regard to six key dependent variables for which I originally reported the correlations only for the full (or almost full) set of 36 countries (see the tables in Lijphart 1999: 278 279, 296). For the 22 OECD countries, the effect of consensus democracy (executives-parties dimension) on women s parliamentary representation is almost as strong and the effect on women s cabinet participation considerably stronger (significant at the one per cent level and very close to the one per cent level respectively). The effect of consensus democracy on voter turnout, with compulsory voting and frequency of voting controlled for, is weaker (but still significant at the ten per cent level). The correlations with the democratic-quality indicators of popular cabinet support and the John Stuart Mill Criterion are very much stronger among the OECD countries (both significant at the five per cent level). Finally, the correlation with energy efficiency is almost as strong and highly significant at the one per cent level. In short, the overall picture does not change much when the focus is exclusively on the OECD countries. Second, why were Central and East European countries like the Czech Republic and Poland not included in my study? The formal answer to this question is that they failed my criterion of continuous democracy from 1977 to 1996, but let me also point out the two important reasons for my use of this criterion. The substantive reason is that I wanted to make sure that all of the democracies analyzed could all be considered stable and consolidated democratic systems. 4 Equally important was the methodological necessity of having a sufficient time span for my measurements. Large numbers of years are needed, in particular, to measure average cabinet durability, but for key variables like types of cabinets and effective numbers of parties it is also highly desirable to have more than just six years (1990 1996) with only two

110 arend lijphart or three election cycles. The break-up of Czechoslovakia in 1993 presents another problem. Finally, I assume that Armingeon, too, would ultimately have decided against including these new democracies on the basis of his own criterion of high economic development: they are clearly well below the OECD level. Armingeon s third criticism concerns the merger of consociationalism and corporatism, particularly as far as the Scandinavian countries are concerned. I have already responded to the general point above by saying that, while they are clearly not the same, they are sufficiently similar conceptually and empirically to be regarded as part of the same syndrome of characteristics. With regard to specific countries, Norway and Sweden are indeed outliers with stronger corporatism than could have been expected from their consociational traits, and so is Italy with weak corporatism and strong consociationalism. However, the relationships among the different consociational traits are by no means perfect either. For instance, Mauritius is a deviant case in having a much lower percentage of minimal-winning, one-party cabinets than could have been expected on the basis of its low effective number of parties; and Austria, France, the United States, and Costa Rica are outliers as far as the relationship between executive dominance and type of cabinet is concerned (see the scatterplots in Lijphart 1999: 112, 138, 182 183). Fourth, why should the five components of the executives-parties dimension be weighted equally? Armingeon is right that combining several variables into a summary measure without weighting them does not actually avoid the problem of weighting: equal weighting is a form of weighting, too. In practice, however, most researchers opt for equal weighting unless there is a very strong and convincing reason to attach special weights to certain components. In fact, that is Armingeon s own decision, too: his measure of consociationalism consists of the two equally weighted variables of number of parties and type of cabinets. Should the proportionality and executive-dominance be dropped from the index of consociationalism? I am especially reluctant to drop proportionality. It is one of the four basic elements of consociational democracy as I have always defined it (together with grand coalition, cultural autonomy, and minority veto; see Lijphart 1977). Other scholars have also regarded it as one of the key characteristics of consociationalism; in fact, in his first major work on the subject, Gerhard Lehmbruch (1967) called consociational democracy proportional democracy (Proporzdemokratie). Electoral proportionality is also easy to measure on the basis of votes and seats won in national elections. Executive-dominance is a variable that is difficult to measure, and I am not at all sure that the operational indicator I develop in Patterns of Democracy is satisfactory. 5 Nevertheless, I feel that the difference between the patterns of executive-dominance and executive-legislative balance is so impor-

negotiation democracy versus consensus democracy 111 tant in substantive terms that it needs to be included in any index of consensus democracy. Fifth, Armingeon points out that the number of cases that I analyze varies from policy field to policy field. Ideally, I would have liked to have data on all policy variables for all of my 36 countries, but I decided that it was better to use incomplete data than not use the data at all. Results can obviously be artifacts of country selection, but no systematic bias is introduced by including the largest number of countries on which information is available. And excluding countries can obviously also affect one s findings. I assume, incidentally, that the results reported in Armingeon s Table 3 are not all based on complete data for all 22 OECD countries. Sixth, Armingeon is right that I did not systematically test for the existence of non-linear relationships. However, in my visual inspection of all scatterplots for potential outliers I was also alert to the possibility of other than linear relationships and I did not find any clear evidence of the latter. Moreover, if there were any non-linear relationships that I missed, my linear tests would have understated rather than overstated the strength of the effect of type of democracy on policies and outcomes. Armingeon s final criticism concerns my control variables. I did try to control for the most important and plausible alternative explanatory variables; for instance, because my 36 countries have especially large differences with regard to level of development and population size, I always controlled for these two variables. In testing the relationship between type of democracy and some other specific variables, my controls varied; for instance, in testing the effect of consensus democracy on voter turnout, I controlled for compulsory voting and frequency of voting, which are not relevant variables in other contexts. Armingeon proposes some other useful controls that I endorse. Economic openness and the proportion of elderly are excellent controls to use when testing for the effect of democratic institutions on macro-economic policies and characteristics of the welfare state. Catholicism is also a relevant variable, although it may be difficult to use when countries with large non- Christian populations are included. Could the strength of left-wing parties rather than consensus democracy be the explanation for some of the desirable consequences of consensus democracy that I find? Here I think that one can argue that these variables are closely connected instead of alternatives to each other: the stronger community orientation and social altruism that characterize the political culture of consensus democracy tend to lead to stronger left-wing parties. If this view is correct, type of democracy is the independent variable with dominant parties being an intervening variable. Armingeon presents the main results of his analysis in Tables 3 and 4. I was pleased to see that he does not limit himself to a re-analysis of some of the

112 arend lijphart same basic variables and the same operational indicators that I use (such as satisfaction with democracy and voter turnout), but that he also analyzes several new indicators for these variables (such as frequent political discussion and year of last execution) as well as entirely new variables and indicators (such as inter-personal trust and public debt). What also struck me, however, is that he completely ignores some of the key dependent variables for which I find strong connections with consensus democracy. I obviously cannot blame him for not covering each and every point in his re-analysis his article is admirably succinct and to the point but I should point out that the neglected variables provide some of the key evidence of the superior quality of consensus democracy. In particular, government-voter proximity is perhaps the most crucial test of democratic quality (see also Powell 2000). And the better environmental record, lower imprisonment rates, and greater generosity with foreign aid of the consensus democracies show that in three of the four areas of kindness and gentleness the consensus democracies do perform exceptionally well. On the whole, Armingeon s findings concerning the effects of countermajoritarian institutions are somewhat stronger than my own findings. His findings about the consequences of consociationalism are somewhat weaker than what I found the results of consensus democracy to be, but this is partly compensated by his findings about the effects of corporatism, which forms part of my consensus democracy. The main conclusion that stands out is that he shows that all three aspects of his negotiation democracy (corporatism, consociationalism, and counter-majoritarian institutions) have a large number of highly desirable qualities by and large the same superior qualities that I claim for consensus democracy. That means that he can recommend all three types of institutions to countries designing their first democratic constitutions or contemplating democratic reform. In slightly different terminology, I can give exactly the same advice. We could hardly be more mutually supportive! Notes 1. I repeat this offer here. I can send my data either in hard-copy form or as an e-mail attachment to any researcher who would like to use them. Please write to alijphart@ucsd.edu or to Arend Lijphart, Department of Political Science (0521), University of California-San Diego, 9500 Gilman Drive, La Jolla CA 92093, USA. 2. Armingeon excludes OECD-member Iceland from his set of OECD countries. For the sake of comparability, I shall do the same in all of my references to the OECD countries below. 3. Of course, I still faced the problem of missing data, and consequently there were often fewer than 36 cases available for analysis in the full set and fewer than 22 in the OECD subset.

negotiation democracy versus consensus democracy 113 4. I may still have been too lenient; in retrospect, Colombia and Venezuela now seem very dubious cases. 5. In the only review of Patterns of Democracy that (so far) has taken a serious look at how I operationalize my ten basic variables, Henk van der Kolk rightly criticizes my operationalization of executive dominance. I now think that a better and, in particular, less complex operational indicator could be based on cabinet life I only (logged, in order to diminish the impact of the few extremely high values). Van der Kolk is also critical of my operational measure for cabinet types and offers an alternative. I would like to point out that his alternative is actually identical to my own original measure which I obviously did not explain clearly enough. References Katzenstein, P.J. (1985). Small states in world markets: Industrial policy in Europe. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Lehmbruch, G. (1967). Proporzdemokratie: Politisches System und politische Kultur in der Schweiz und in Österreich. Tübingen: Mohr. Lijphart, A. (1970). Comparative politics and the comparative method. American Political Science Review 65(3): 682 693. Lijphart, A. (1975). The comparable-cases strategy in comparative research. Comparative Political Studies 8(2): 158 177. Lijphart, A. (1977). Democracy in plural societies: A comparative exploration. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Lijphart, A. (1999). Patterns of democracy: Government forms and performance in thirty-six countries. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Powell, G.B. Jr. (2000). Elections as instruments of democracy: Majoritarian and proportional visions. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Van der Kolk, H. (2000). Book review of Lijphart 1999. Acta Politica 35(4): 340 343. Address for correspondence: Arend Lijphart, Department of Political Science (0521), University of California-San Diego, 9500 Gilman Drive, La Jolla CA 92093, USA Phone: 001 858 534 3798; E-mail: alijphart@ucsd.edu