The New Urban Economy: Opportunities and Challenges

Similar documents
Meeting the Demand: Hiring Patterns of Welfare Recipients in Four Metropolitan Areas ...a spatial FINDINGS mismatch may

Changing Cities: What s Next for Charlotte?

In abusiness Review article nine years ago, we. Has Suburbanization Diminished the Importance of Access to Center City?

The Brookings Institution Metropolitan Policy Program Robert Puentes, Fellow

The Brookings Institution

Stuart A. Gabriel and Gary D. Painter* Abstract. In a paper published in The Review of Economics and Statistics some 20 years ago, we sought to

Five years after the enactment of federal welfare reform legislation, states have adopted a. What Cities Need from Welfare Reform Reauthorization

The Rise and Decline of the American Ghetto

Residential segregation and socioeconomic outcomes When did ghettos go bad?

What kinds of residential mobility improve lives? Testimony of James E. Rosenbaum July 15, 2008

The Brookings Institution Metropolitan Policy Program Bruce Katz, Director

Working Overtime: Long Commutes and Rent-burden in the Washington Metropolitan Region

The Brookings Institution Metropolitan Policy Program Bruce Katz, Director

Places in Need: The Geography of Poverty and the American Safety Net

are receiving more funding than they should. Funds must be reallocated, zoning ordinances must be modified, train lines need to be laid, and new

The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices

UC Berkeley Earlier Faculty Research

The Brookings Institution Metropolitan Policy Program Robert Puentes, Fellow

The Brookings Institution Metropolitan Policy Program Robert Puentes, Fellow

A PROGRESSIVE AGENDA FOR METROPOLITAN AMERICA Bruce Katz*

The Brookings Institution Metropolitan Policy Program Bruce Katz, Director

The Potomac Conference

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Race, Space and Youth Labor Market Opportunities in the Capital Region. November 2010

3Demographic Drivers. The State of the Nation s Housing 2007

Community Well-Being and the Great Recession

Land Use, Job Accessibility and Commuting Efficiency under the Hukou System in Urban China: A Case Study in Guangzhou

Architecture of Segregation. Paul A. Jargowsky Center for Urban Research and Education Rutgers University - Camden

DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGE AND THE EXPANSION OF URBAN AREAS IN MARYLAND, 1970 TO Marie Howland University of Maryland, College Park.

PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY

The Impact of Immigration on Wages of Unskilled Workers

APPENDIX B. Environmental Justice Evaluation

Minority Suburbanization and Racial Change

Residential Location, Transportation, and Welfare-to-Work in the United States: A Case Study of Milwaukee

Complaints not really about our methodology

City of Hammond Indiana DRAFT Fair Housing Assessment 07. Disparities in Access to Opportunity

Public Transit and the Spatial Distribution of Minority Employment: Evidence from a Natural Experiment

Economic Segregation in the Housing Market: Examining the Effects of the Mount Laurel Decision in New Jersey

UCLA Working Paper Series

PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY

UC Berkeley Earlier Faculty Research

Sprawl and segregation: A study of U.S. metropolitan areas. Len Sprishen Senior Economics Thesis The College of New Jersey

Relationships between the Growth of Ethnic Groups and Socioeconomic Conditions in US Metropolitan Areas

New Directions for Urban Policy

Part 1: Focus on Income. Inequality. EMBARGOED until 5/28/14. indicator definitions and Rankings

Building Stronger Communities for Better Health: The Geography of Health Equity

The State of Rural Minnesota, 2019

A Barometer of the Economic Recovery in Our State

OLDER INDUSTRIAL CITIES

Social and Equity Aspects of Transportation. NL Federation of Labour

Rural Welfare Reform. Lessons Learned. Leslie A.Whitener, Robert Gibbs, Lorin Kusmin,

Poverty in Buffalo-Niagara

Racial Inequities in Montgomery County

Immigrants and the Spatial Mismatch Hypothesis: Employment Outcomes among Immigrant Youth in Los Angeles. Cathy Yang Liu

Patterns of Housing Voucher Use Revisited: Segregation and Section 8 Using Updated Data and More Precise Comparison Groups, 2013

POLICY BRIEF. Achieving Compromise on Welfare Reform Reauthorization. The Brookings Institution. May 2003 Welfare Reform & Beyond #25

Welfare Reform and the Employment Prospects of AFDC Recipients

New Jersey Long-Range Transportation Plan 2030

The Misunderstood Consequences of Shelley v. Kraemer Extended Abstract

Chapter 5. Residential Mobility in the United States and the Great Recession: A Shift to Local Moves

Ethnic Enclave Residence and Employment Accessibility of Latino Workers in Chicago, Los Angeles and Washington, D.C.

Gentrification: A Recent History in Metro Denver

Heading in the Wrong Direction: Growing School Segregation on Long Island

Patterns of Housing Voucher Use Revisited: Segregation and Section 8 Using Updated Data and More Precise Comparison Groups, 2013

SOME REALITIES ABOUT SPRAWL AND URBAN DECLINE

U.S. Workers Diverging Locations: Policy and Inequality Implications

Lost in the Balance: How State Policies Affect the Fiscal Health of Cities

The Brookings Institution Metropolitan Policy Program Robert Puentes, Fellow

Urban Segregation and Employment Access of Ethnic Minorities. Yves Zenou, Stockholm University and GAINS

Hearing on Proposals for Reducing Poverty. April 26, Thank you, Chairman McDermott and members of the Subcommittee. I am John Podesta,

\8;2\-3 AN EXECUTIVE SUMMARY COMMUTING IN TEXAS: PATTERNS AND TRENDS. L~, t~ 1821summary. TxDOT/Uni.

PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY

Labor Supply at the Extensive and Intensive Margins: The EITC, Welfare and Hours Worked

Racial Inequities in Fairfax County

Where Do We Belong? Fixing America s Broken Housing System

Family Shelter Entry and Re-entry over the Recession in Hennepin County, MN:

SEVERE DISTRESS AND CONCENTRATED POVERTY: TRENDS FOR NEIGHBORHOODS IN CASEY CITIES AND THE NATION

Institute for Public Policy and Economic Analysis

POVERTY in the INLAND EMPIRE,

UCLA On-Line Working Paper Series

Spatial Mismatch and Urban Labor Markets in the United States: Evidence for Blacks, Immigrants and Hispanics

Faithful and Strategic Engagement in Metropolitan Richmond Facilitator s Workbook

The Effect of the Mount Laurel Decision on Segregation by Race, Income and Poverty Status. Damiano Sasso College of New Jersey April 20, 2004

Segregation in Motion: Dynamic and Static Views of Segregation among Recent Movers. Victoria Pevarnik. John Hipp

UCLA California Policy Options

Flight and Blight. Pennsylvania Senate Urban Affairs Committee. Running Header: URBAN BLIGHT AND URBAN FLIGHT 2014

Chapter 10. Resource Markets and the Distribution of Income. Copyright 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Ending Concentrated Poverty: New Directions After Hurricane Katrina The Enterprise Foundation October 12, 2005

A snapshot of our communities

Harvard Institute of Economic Research

Foundations of Urban Health. Professor: Dr. Judy Lubin Urban Health Disparities

Published online: 03 Jun 2014.

The Brookings Institution Metropolitan Policy Program Robert Puentes, Fellow

Are Suburban Firms More Likely to Discriminate Against African Americans?

WORKINGPAPER SERIES. Did Immigrants in the U.S. Labor Market Make Conditions Worse for Native Workers During the Great Recession?

"Can residential mobility programs improve human capital? Comparing social mechanisms in different kinds of programs"

The Brookings Institution Metropolitan Policy Program Amy Liu, Deputy Director

The Changing Racial and Ethnic Makeup of New York City Neighborhoods

The Brookings Institution Metropolitan Policy Program Alan Berube, Fellow

University of Virginia

APTA Local Priority Message Testing Results. October 30, 2013

Transcription:

Gale, Pack, and Potter no. 7 June 2001 The New Urban Economy: Opportunities and Challenges The economic and social challenges of urban development have become increasingly significant in recent years. Older cities have seen precipitous declines in economic performance, population, tax bases, and public services. In many, poverty and crime have become more prevalent. At the same time, urban areas also enjoy positive opportunities, including those created by new technologies, idea-intensive industries, and the consumption amenities that cities can offer. The balance of costs and benefits of urban areas, however, has received little systematic attention from researchers over the last few decades. The Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs (BWPUA) is aimed at remedying that lack of attention. This conference report summarizes the findings of the second volume of BWPUA, featuring six papers presented at the Brookings Institution on October 26-27, 2000. The volume features a symposium on issues relating to urban sprawl and decentralization, as well as papers on minority entrepreneurs, the effects of neighborhood on children s educational achievement, and the factors behind the decline in food stamp participation. The volume will be published by Brookings this summer. Symposium on Decentralization and Urban Sprawl The enormous decentralization of economic activity over the past several decades has been the central feature of metropolitan development during the last half-century. Some observers view this trend with alarm and argue that decentralization has led to a series of maladies in central cities, as well as to urban sprawl and related problems in the suburbs. Others view decentralization as a positive development, reflecting the preferences of Americans regarding residence, employment, and other factors. A full assessment of decentralization, however, requires facts documenting the extent and nature of the trend, analyses of the causes and consequences of decentralization, and a conceptual framework that integrates these factors. Accordingly, the volume begins with a symposium of three papers to explore these issues. Decentralization: Basic Facts and Their Implications In the traditional view, urban areas have a dense central business district with concentrated employment and production, in order to reduce costs of transportation and information sharing. In these so-called monocentric urban areas, land has the highest value in the city center because employment density is 1775 Massachusetts Ave. N.W. Washington, DC 20036-2188 Tel: 202-797-6105 www.brookings.edu

William G. Gale The Brookings-Wharton William Gale is Joseph A. Pechman Fellow in the Economic Studies program at the Brookings Institution. Janet Rothenberg Pack highest there. As distance from the city center increases, land and housing prices fall, lot sizes lengthen, workers commute times rise, and poverty declines. This standard view has been increasingly challenged by decentralization. In their paper, economists Edward Glaeser of Harvard University and Brookings and Matthew Kahn of Tufts University document in new ways the basic facts of decentralization and analyze the implications for the economic structure of urban areas. They show that in 1940, only one of the ten largest cities had population density below 10,000 people per square mile. By 1990, seven of the ten largest cities had densities below 7,500. Although there is no formal definition of decentralization, urban areas today are highly decentralized: by 1996, only 24 percent of jobs in U. S. metropolitan areas were within three miles of a city center. Janet Rothenberg Pack is professor of public policy and management and real estate at the Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania. Samara R. Potter Samara Potter is a research assistant in Economic Studies at the Brookings Institution. Despite the ubiquity of decentralization, there are substantial differences across urban areas. In New York, one of the few cities with concentrated employment patterns, over 45 percent of jobs are within three miles of the city center. In Los Angeles, which is known for its sprawling nature, 45 percent of employment is located within an 11-mile ring of the city center. Glaeser and Kahn also find that the dispersion of employment and population in Chicago, and in most other American metropolitan areas, bears a much stronger resemblance to the spatial patterns in Los Angeles than in New York. After documenting these trends, the authors examine the causes. The residential preferences of workers appear to be the driving forces behind this move toward decentralization, according to Glaeser and Kahn. That is, firms have located in the suburbs in large part because that is where the workers choose to live. In addition, better access to trucking routes from suburban locations encourages manufacturing firms to locate in the suburbs. The trend toward decentralization appears to be somewhat less pronounced among cities that are more than 200 years old and somewhat more pronounced among those less than 60 years old. In addition, cities with younger suburbs are associated with more decentralization of employment. Forces offsetting decentralization include the advantage of urban areas in accelerating the communication of ideas. Idea-intensive or service-based industries (such as commercial banking) are more likely to locate in the central city, while manufacturing firms and firms that require more physical infrastructure are more likely to locate in the suburbs. These results have striking implications. The decentralization of employment suggests that the classic stylized facts of urban economics may no longer be empirically valid. Indeed, in contrast to the standard model, Glaeser and Kahn find that cities with more decentralized employment are less likely to have housing prices fall and commute times rise 2 CONFERENCE REPORT JUNE 2001 NO. 7

Conference on Urban Affairs as distance from the city center increases. Interestingly, the spatial patterns for these factors are still correlated with employment densities, but since employment is no longer concentrated at the city center, the spatial patterns do not follow those suggested by the traditional approach. Thus, Glaeser and Kahn present an important set of facts that disputes much traditional thinking on cities, and will challenge urban experts to develop innovative approaches for thinking about urban dynamics. Systematic Thinking About Urban Sprawl Extensive decentralization of cities and the resulting development of the urban fringe bring new users to roadways, reduce open space, and require cities or suburbs to extend their utility services farther. All of these factors raise concerns about urban sprawl, which has become an increasingly contentious political issue in recent years. Twelve states have enacted growth management programs, and 240 anti-sprawl initiatives appeared on November 1998 local and state ballots, with many additional proposals in November 2000. The trend toward decentralization appears to be somewhat less pronounced among cities that are more than 200 years old and somewhat more pronounced among those less than 60 years old. In light of this heated public debate, University of Illinois economist Jan Brueckner provides a framework in which to analyze sprawl issues and the relative merits of alternative remedies. He defines urban sprawl as the excessive spatial growth of urban areas. The emphasis on whether growth is excessive is crucial, because the natural growth of urban areas due to increases in income or population or improvements in transportation efficiency should not be a cause for concern. Brueckner s paper suggests that under current policies, there are reasons to believe that too much new suburban development occurs because developers and new residents are not forced to pay the full costs they impose on others. He recommends that forcing developers and new residents to face these costs with taxes and fees is the best strategy for controlling growth. He highlights three such problems and discusses the prospects and pitfalls of the implied policy solutions. First, each new commuter that moves to the suburbs adds to roadway congestion there and consequently imposes costs on others, including increasing the time and fuel costs needed to drive a given distance. Economists have often suggested forcing drivers to shoulder these costs by assessing congestion tolls. Brueckner points out that technological developments could make assessing such tolls simpler now than they have been previously, but notes a history of strong political resistance to such taxes. THE NEW URBAN ECONOMY: OPPORTUNITIES AND CHALLENGES 3

Second, suburban development reduces the amount of open space around the perimeter of a city, which reduces the benefits that all area residents can obtain from such spaces. Brueckner discusses the possibility of using development taxes to correct this market failure, but warns that identifying the optimal level for such a tax would be extremely difficult in practice because it is nearly impossible to measure precisely the value people place on the amenity of undeveloped land outside the city. The exodus of jobs to the suburbs raises the possibility that people who continue to live in cities may find it more difficult to find jobs close to home. Third, cities do not charge developers or new residents the full cost of extending infrastructure such as water and sewer lines to new developments. This encourages development beyond optimal levels. Impact fees for service extension could correct this pricing error. Some metropolitan areas concerned about urban sprawl, such as Portland, Oregon, have tried another policy alternative: urban growth boundaries. These boundaries are set by governments and designate a ring beyond which urban development is prohibited or very strictly controlled. Brueckner argues that such policies are likely to be difficult to implement effectively and thus are likely to hurt urban residents, especially low-income residents. Moreover, the policies do not specifically target the market failures of road congestion, utility use, and open space. He warns that in some cases, a draconian urban growth boundary policy could be worse for society than no government intervention and its resulting sprawl. Brueckner s findings will not provide solace to staunch advocates on either side in the debate on urban sprawl. Rather, the paper highlights the importance of systematic thinking on the causes and consequences of sprawl and the necessity of matching both the character and level of the policy intervention to the particular problems that sprawl presents. Employment Opportunities in Decentralized Metropolitan Areas The exodus of jobs to the suburbs raises the possibility that people who continue to live in cities may find it more difficult to find jobs close to home. If that is the case, the ability to commute via public transportation or private automobile would become an increasingly important determinant of people s ability to obtain and retain employment. The issue becomes especially interesting from a policy viewpoint, considering that urban residents are disproportionately minority and lower-income households, and that public transportation often provides poor service for those who live in the city and work in the suburbs. University of California economists Steven Raphael and Michael Stoll examine the importance of car ownership for employment. They document anew the spatial mismatch between certain employment opportunities and available workers. The main focus of their paper is an empirical examination of how car ownership affects employment probabilities for the black and Latino population relative to the white population. White families are more likely to have cars; only 5 percent of white households do not own an automobile, compared to 24 percent of black households and 12 percent of Latino households. Among those who own cars, however, the probability of being employed is nearly constant across these groups. The authors find a positive relationship between owning a car and being 4 CONFERENCE REPORT JUNE 2001 NO. 7

employed, controlling for other factors. They also find that this relationship is stronger for more segregated minority groups. It is much stronger for blacks than for whites, and slightly stronger for Latinos than for whites. This effect is also stronger in cities in which black households are more geographically isolated from employment opportunities. Raphael and Stoll then consider subsidies for minority car ownership. The authors show that raising car ownership rates for minorities to those for white households would be expected to significantly reduce the employment rate gap between these groups. They note that increased car use would worsen trafficrelated externalities such as congestion and air quality, but they also suggest that many minorities with cars would be reverse commuters, traveling from homes in the central city to employment in the suburbs. Furthermore, they expect many minority workers to be employed in night shifts or at other times that would not conflict with rush hour traffic. Research Papers The other three papers presented at the conference provide new evidence on several current issues in urban economics and urban policy: the effects of housing relocation programs, the causes of the decline in food stamp participation, and the determinants of minority business ownership. Do Housing Relocation Programs Help Children s School Performance? The combination of residential segregation by income and race and the suburbanization of highincome households raises many questions about the effects of neighborhood on residents and children. To what extent do peer groups influence individuals outcomes? Do children who grow up in high-poverty environments develop differently from other children? At what point do neighborhood effects become irreversible? The combination of residential segregation by income and race and the suburbanization of highincome households raises many questions about the effects of neighborhood on residents and children. The experimental design of the Department of Housing and Urban Development s Moving to Opportunity program, currently operating in five cities, allows researchers to study overall effects of neighborhood on children s outcomes. The program randomly assigns public housing families that volunteer for the program to one of three groups: a group that is given Section 8 housing vouchers valid only in census tracts with a very low poverty rate; a group that is given Section 8 vouchers valid anywhere; and a group that is given no assistance in finding alternative housing. The effect of this program on children s educational achievements is the focus of the conference paper by economists Jens Ludwig of Georgetown University, Helen Ladd of Duke University, and Greg Duncan of Northwestern University. (Earlier research on the issue by Duncan and Ludwig was published as a Brookings Institution Children s Roundtable Policy Brief in July 2000.) In the conference paper, the authors find that children aged five through twelve who moved to lowpoverty neighborhoods demonstrated substantial improvement on standardized tests in both reading and math. For teenagers who moved to low-poverty neighborhoods, only the reading tests were available, and those scores did not differ from non-movers. However, teens who transferred THE NEW URBAN ECONOMY: OPPORTUNITIES AND CHALLENGES 5

to lower poverty areas were more often retained in grade and more often subject to disciplinary action than their peers who did not move. The authors suggest that differences in school standards, rather than actual declines in teens behavior or abilities, may account for these apparently negative implications. The authors believe their findings are encouraging, but are only one component of a larger debate about whether expansion of relocation policies would be desirable. Which aspects of the new neighborhoods or schools are leading to the positive effects remains unclear. In some cases, reform of schools in the low-income neighborhoods might be as effective as relocation. Also, introducing students from low-income neighborhoods into low-poverty areas might have negative impacts on outcomes of host children. The best policy options for taking advantage of neighborhood effects are uncertain. Nevertheless, the findings provide important new evidence that should be part of any discussion of the costs and benefits of relocation programs. Why Did Food Stamp Program Participation Decline? The Food Stamp Program provides a monthly allotment of coupons or credit for lowincome households to purchase food at participating stores, and is currently one of the government s largest transfer programs. However, program participation rates have fallen dramatically in the last several years, from 27 million persons in 1994 to 20 million in 1998, with much of the decline occurring after 1996 and most of it occurring in urban areas. The conference paper by UCLA economists Janet Currie and Jeffrey Grogger examines the causes of the decline in Food Stamp Program enrollment and the implications for public policy and urban areas. Three alternative (and not mutually exclusive) hypotheses have been put forth to explain falling enrollment: welfare reform, the strength of the economy, and changes in stigma and transaction costs attached to participation in the Food Stamp Program. The 1996 welfare reform law allowed states to penalize food stamp participants for failure to meet work requirements, which may have substantially reduced the size of the eligible population. Currie and Grogger found that, overall, welfare reform was responsible for almost a third of the decrease. This effect was especially strong among single-head households. The strong economy and corresponding lower unemployment rates explained about onefifth of the overall decline in food stamp participation between 1993 and 1998. Both of these factors, along with changes in program rules, may have increased the transaction costs and stigma associated with food stamp participation. More frequent recertification requirements under the new rules impose higher costs on households wishing to sign up for the program. Stigma may be more of a factor in states that still provide food stamp coupons, as compared with the roughly two dozen states using credit card-style electronic balance transfer methods. (All states are required to shift to electronic transfer methods by 6 CONFERENCE REPORT JUNE 2001 NO. 7

October 2002. Currie and Grogger s results indicate that transaction costs are especially problematic for single parents and rural households, while stigma has more of an effect for married households without children. The decline in food stamp use is particularly important for urban areas, given the concentration of the poor in cities. Much of the fall in participation rates, in fact, occurred in cities. This is especially true of the decline due to welfare reform. Currie and Grogger found that implementation of the Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF) program had almost no impact on program rolls in rural areas, but was responsible for about 40 percent of the decline in food stamp enrollment in central cities. In comparison, decreases in unemployment were responsible for only 18 percent of the decline in central city locations. TANF implementation seems to play a greater role in the reduction of Food Stamp Program participation in cities while falling unemployment has less impact, suggesting needy families in central cities are experiencing more difficulty in obtaining food stamps, rather than experiencing reduced need. Under these circumstances, policy reforms intended to restore benefits to households in need should target families in central cities, especially single-head households. Why Do Minority Self-Employment Rates Vary Across Metropolitan Areas? The promotion of minority business ownership has been a major thrust of federal and local government policies for some time. The much lower rate of self-employment among minorities contributes to differences in employment rates between minority and white populations, and may well restrict the abilities of minority groups to accumulate wealth. About 11 percent of the overall population, but only 4 percent of the black population, is self-employed. Whites are self-employed at above-average rates of 13 percent, with Asians at 11 percent and Latinos in the middle at about 7 percent. Average earnings from selfemployment are 93 percent higher for whites than for blacks. The variation in selfemployment rates across metropolitan areas is also higher for all three minority groups than for whites. In their conference paper, Syracuse University economists Dan Black, Douglas Holtz- Eakin, and Stuart Rosenthal show that characteristics, including age, immigrant status, and education, are important determinants of whether a particular person is self-employed, but they do not vary across metropolitan areas in ways that can explain variation in selfemployment rates and earnings in different cities. The authors also examine city-level variables and show that the degree of segregation of the minority population within a given metropolitan area does not have a significant impact on minority self-employment rates. What does make a difference is the purchasing power of minority groups in a city. In cities with wealthier minority populations, higher rates of minority self-employment are observed, suggesting that the economic power of the minority community is important to sustaining minority entrepreneurs. There are several possible THE NEW URBAN ECONOMY: OPPORTUNITIES AND CHALLENGES The views expressed in this Conference Report are those of the authors and are not necessarily those of the trustees, officers, or other staff members of the Brookings Institution. Copyright 2001 The Brookings Institution 7

The Brookings Institution 1775 Massachusetts Ave. N.W. Washington, DC 20036 NONPROFIT ORG. U.S. POSTAGE PAID FREDERICK, MD PERMIT NO. 225 Recent Policy Briefs Humanitarian and Human Rights Emergencies Roberta Cohen and James Kunder (June 2001) An Agenda for Election Reform Thomas E. Mann (June 2001) Open Doors Robert E. Litan, Paul Masson, and Michael Pomerleano (Conference Report #6, June 2001) Moving Forward in South Asia Stephen P. Cohen (May 2001) The Caucasus and Central Asia Fiona Hill (May 2001) channels through which a minority group s economic clout could influence the self-employment rate, including various consumer discrimination theories and improved access of minorities to lenders. Distinguishing among these alternatives will play an important role in determining the policy implications of the authors findings. Conclusion Taken together, the papers presented at the Brookings-Wharton conference show that significant progress can be made in disentangling economic issues that affect and are affected by urban areas. Each of the papers provides new facts or models that will be useful to policymakers, academics, students, and other interested groups and individuals. Related Books American Metropolitics Myron Orfield (forthcoming) Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs William G. Gale and Janet Rothenberg Pack, eds. (2000) Inside Game/Outside Game: Winning Strategies for Saving Urban America David Rusk (1999) As the problems and opportunities created by urban areas continue to evolve, the findings in these papers should aid in providing new policy solutions, developing ways to exploit opportunities for enhancing urban development and economic well-being, and setting a foundation for future analysis. This Conference Report and all Policy Briefs are also posted on the Brookings website at www.brookings.edu If you have questions or comments about this Conference Report, please send an email message to policybriefs@brookings.edu Authors responses will be posted on the Brookings website.