This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Sciences Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:

Similar documents
Microfinance Misses Its Mark

This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Sciences Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:

ROMANTICISING THE POOR HARMS THE POOR

Testimony to the United States Senate Budget Committee Hearing on Opportunity, Mobility, and Inequality in Today's Economy April 1, 2014

Following are the introductory remarks on the occasion by Khadija Haq, President MHHDC. POVERTY IN SOUTH ASIA: CHALLENGES AND RESPONSES

By Datuk Dr Denison Jayasooria Principal Research Fellow, Institute of Ethnic Studies, National University of Malaysia (UKM) & Asian Solidarity

Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016

Economic and Social Council

gender equality as smart economics A World Bank Group Action Plan

: Sustainable Development (SD) : Measures to eradicate extreme poverty in developing nations : Lara Gieringer :

Session 2A. Cultural Approaches to addressing Poverty

Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? Income Growth and Poverty

Why Doesn t Microfinance Work?

Why focusing on employment?

Poverty in the Third World

Inequality in China: Rural poverty persists as urban wealth

GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS & GENDER EQUALITY THREATS, OPPORTUNITIES AND NECESSITIES

9.1 Human Development Index Development improving the material conditions diffusion of knowledge and technology Measure by HDI

Structural Change, Social Policy and Politics

CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATIONS

Gender, labour and a just transition towards environmentally sustainable economies and societies for all

Poverty Profile. Executive Summary. Kingdom of Thailand

UNDERSTANDING TRADE, DEVELOPMENT, AND POVERTY REDUCTION

A 13-PART COURSE IN POPULAR ECONOMICS SAMPLE COURSE OUTLINE

IB Diploma: Economics. Section 4: Development Economics COURSE COMPANION. First Edition (2017)

Unlocking Opportunities in the Poorest Communities: A Policy Brief

JICA s Position Paper on SDGs: Goal 10

Informal debate of the General Assembly Promotion of gender equality and the empowerment of women 6 8 March 2007

CIE Economics A-level

Feminization of Poverty & Globalization S. Khan 1. Impact of Globalization on the Feminization of Poverty in South Asia. Saba Khan

Policy Brief Internal Migration and Gender in Asia

Leading the Way Out of Global Poverty

Chapter 2: The U.S. Economy: A Global View

Halve, between 1990 and 2015, the proportion of people whose income is less than $1 a day

Macroeconomics and Gender Inequality Yana van der Meulen Rodgers Rutgers University

Human Rights Council 20 th session

E/ESCAP/FSD(3)/INF/6. Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific Asia-Pacific Forum on Sustainable Development 2016

Initial report. Republic of Moldova

WE RE MORE THAN A STORE

Oxfam Education

COUNTRY PLAN THE UK GOVERNMENT S PROGRAMME OF WORK TO FIGHT POVERTY IN BANGLADESH DEVELOPMENT IN BANGLADESH

A PREVENTIVE APPROACH TO AVOID POVERTY FROM SOCIETY

Social Dimension S o ci al D im en si o n 141

BRAC s Graduation Approach to Tackling Ultra Poverty: Experiences from Around the World

Canadian Journal of Women and the Law, Volume 24, Number 2, 2012, pp (Review)

Synopsis of the thesis entitled

Asia-Pacific to comprise two-thirds of global middle class by 2030, Report says

Eradication of poverty and other development issues: women in development

Towards a World Bank Group Gender Strategy Consultation Meeting 9 July 2015 Feedback Summary Kingston, Jamaica

Dhaka, 10 December 2009

Andhra Pradesh: Vision 2020

The Eighth Session of the Open Working Group on Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) 3-7 February 2014

Ministerial declaration of the 2007 High-level Segment

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

$50 Billion to End Poverty in Sri Lanka and Uganda. Shyenne Horras. Dr. Jessica Lin ECON 351H. 13 May 2015

Inclusive growth and development founded on decent work for all

ECONOMIC EMPOWERMENT FOR WOMEN IN THE INFORMAL ECONOMY IN THAILAND. Poonsap S. Tulaphan

THE EVOLUTION OF FINANCIAL MAPPING OUR FUTURE PROSPECTS CONTENTS CONTENTS 10/27/2014. Why Co operatives in Africa Brief Background of the history of

Commission on the Status of Women Forty-ninth session New York, 28 February 11 March Gender perspectives in macroeconomics

Prospects and Problems of Social Entrepreneurship in North East India

19 ECONOMIC INEQUALITY. Chapt er. Key Concepts. Economic Inequality in the United States

Economic Geography Chapter 10 Development

[text from Why Graduation tri-fold. Picture?]

Financing Sustainable Development

SOCIAL ENTREPRENEURSHIP IN RURAL INDIA: A SMALL STEP APPROACH TOWARDS INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE

Swiss Position on Gender Equality in the Post-2015 Agenda

SEX WORKERS, EMPOWERMENT AND POVERTY ALLEVIATION IN ETHIOPIA

Contemporary Human Geography, 2e. Chapter 9. Development. Lectures. Karl Byrand, University of Wisconsin-Sheboygan Pearson Education, Inc.

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003

OFW Remittances: Magic Bullet?

ACCELERATING GLOBAL ACTIONS FOR A WORLD WITHOUT POVERTY

PRE-CONFERENCE MEETING Women in Local Authorities Leadership Positions: Approaches to Democracy, Participation, Local Development and Peace

Swiss Position on Gender Equality in the Post-2015 Agenda

2011 HIGH LEVEL MEETING ON YOUTH General Assembly United Nations New York July 2011

Sustainable microfinance: The balance between financial sustainability and social responsibility. A business model integrating remittances

The Effects of Trade Policy: A Global Perspective

DECENT WORK IN TANZANIA

Fact Sheet WOMEN S PARTICIPATION IN THE PALESTINIAN LABOUR FORCE: males

Speech. H.E. Yoweri Kaguta Museveni PRESIDENT OF THE REPUBLIC OF UGANDA. On the Occasion to Commemorate INTERNATIONAL WOMEN S DAY

Irving Fisher ON POVERTY & DEVELOPMENT

Income Inequality and Social, Economic, and Political Instability. Joseph Stiglitz Dubai: World Government Summit February 13, 2017

Microcredit as a Cure for Poverty: The Case of Serbia *

Has Globalization Helped or Hindered Economic Development? (EA)

SYNOPSIS Mainstreaming Gender in Urban Renewal Projects

Lifting People Out of Extreme Poverty through a Comprehensive Integrated Approach

Linking growth and equity: exploitation in labour markets. Ursula Grant and Kate Higgins Growth and Equity Conference

Reducing Poverty in the Arab World Successes and Limits of the Moroccan. Lahcen Achy. Beirut, Lebanon July 29, 2010

CONCLUSION, RECOMMENDATIONS, LIMITATIONS OF THE STUDY AND DIRECTIONS FOR FUTURE RESEARCH

and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1

How Can Globalization Become More Pro-Poor?

Executive Summary. Figures provided by the U.S. Census Bureau 1 demonstrate that teen employment prospects are dismal:

Profits and poverty: The economics of forced labour

MY VISION FOR INDIA By Samiksha Mallick Before I begin to tell my readers my vision for India, I would like to bring under limelight the things I see

Downloads from this web forum are for private, non commercial use only. Consult the copyright and media usage guidelines on

Gender at Work Emerging Messages

Globalization: It Doesn t Just Happen

Social Capital and Empowerment

Socio - Economic Impact of Remittance on Households in Lekhnath Municipality, Kaski, Nepal

World Vision International. World Vision is advancing just cities for children. By Joyati Das

SMART STRATEGIES TO INCREASE PROSPERITY AND LIMIT BRAIN DRAIN IN CENTRAL EUROPE 1

Transcription:

= = = = = = = Working Paper Employment, not Microcredit, is the Solution Aneel Karnani Stephen M. Ross School of Business at the University of Michigan Ross School of Business Working Paper Series Working Paper No. 1065 January 2007 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Sciences Research Network Electronic Paper Collection: http://ssrn.com/abstract=962941 UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN

Employment, not microcredit, is the solution Abstract Most studies suggest that microcredit is beneficial but only to a limited extent. The problem lies not with microcredit but rather with microenterprises. With low skills, little capital and no scale economies, these businesses have low productivity and lead to meager earnings that cannot lift their owners out of poverty. Creating opportunities for steady employment at reasonable wages is the best way to take people out of poverty. The government is responsible for providing public services that are critical for increasing the productivity and the employability of the poor.

The Nobel Peace Price for 2006 was awarded to the Grameen Bank in Bangladesh and its founder Muhammad Yunus, a pioneer of the microcredit movement. The Nobel Committee affirmed that microcredit must play "a major part" in eliminating poverty. The central objective of the Grameen Bank has been to reverse the age-old vicious circle of low income, low saving & low investment, into virtuous circle of low income, injection of credit, investment, more income, more savings, more investment, more income. The United Nations, having designated 2005 as the International year of Microcredit, declares on its website, currently microentrepreneurs use loans as small as $100 to grow thriving business and, in turn, provide their families, leading to strong and flourishing local economies. CK Prahalad in his popular book The Fortune at the Bottom of the Pyramid (2004) argues that we should recognize the poor as resilient and creative entrepreneurs, and commends commercial banks, such as ICICI in India, which are expanding into microcredit. Given this intensity of interest and the resources devoted to it, it is reasonable to ask how much do the poor really benefit from microcredit. I argue here that microcredit does yield some non-economic benefits, but that it does not significantly alleviate poverty. The best way to eradicate poverty is help create jobs and increase productivity. Empowering Women Microcredit organizations have primarily targeted women as their clients. Yunus is reported to have said "women have plans for themselves, for their children, about their home, the meals. They have a vision. A man wants to enjoy himself." Microcredit often 2

yields non-economic benefits such as increasing self-esteem and social cohesion, and empowering women. 1 Microcredit enables women to contribute towards the household economy, leading to economic empowerment and increasing their intra-household bargaining power. Microcredit also facilitates women to move from positions of marginalization within household decision making process and exclusion within the community, to greater centrality, inclusion and voice. The social processes of microcredit lead to strengthening the personal and social dimensions of women s empowerment. This results in increased self-esteem and self-worth for women and a greater sense of awareness of social and political issues, leading to increased mobility and reduced seclusion of women. But there is some empirical evidence suggesting that microcredit does not always result in increased empowerment for women. Credit by itself cannot overcome patriarchal systems of control at household and community levels. Women's control over financial resources is probably a key factor in explaining these mixed results. It seems that a significant fraction of women, in spite of having access to credit, do not have control over the loans contracted or the income generated from the microenterprises. 2 Macro credit Overall, microcredit does yield non-economic benefits of empowering women. It also helps the poor smooth consumption over periods of cyclical or unexpected crisis, and thus reduces vulnerability. 3 But, that is not enough; the key issue is whether microcredit helps eradicate poverty. The Economist magazine concluded that while heart-warming 3

case studies abound, rigorous empirical analyses are rare. 4 A few studies have even found that micro-credit has a negative impact on poverty; poor households simply become poorer through the additional burden of debt. 5 However, most studies suggest that microcredit is beneficial but only to a limited extent. The reality is less attractive than the promise. 6 Why is microcredit not more effective? The problem lies not with microcredit but rather with microenterprises. The United Nations declaration that microentrepreneurs use loans to grow thriving businesses leading to flourishing economies is hype. A client of microcredit is an entrepreneur in the literal sense: she raises the capital, manages the business and is the residual claimant of the earnings. But, the current usage of the word entrepreneur requires more than the literal definition. Entrepreneurship is the engine of Joseph Schumpeter s dynamism of creative destruction. An entrepreneur is a person of vision and creativity who converts a new idea into a successful innovation, into a new business model. Some clients of microcredit are certainly true entrepreneurs, and have created thriving businesses these are the heart-warming anecdotes. But the vast majority of microcredit clients are caught in subsistence activities with no prospect of competitive advantage. The self-employed poor usually have no specialized skills and often practice multiple occupations. 7 Many of these businesses operate at too small a scale. The median business operated by the poor has no paid staff; most of these businesses have very few assets as well. With low skills, little capital and no scale economies, these businesses operate in arenas with low entry barriers and too much 4

competition; they have low productivity and lead to meager earnings that cannot lift their owners out of poverty. This should not be too surprising. Most people do not have the skills, vision, creativity, and persistence to be true entrepreneurs. Even in developed countries with high levels of education and infrastructure, about 90% of the labor force are employees rather than entrepreneurs. Even with greater availability of financial services in developed countries, only a small fraction have used credit for entrepreneurial purposes. Most clients of microcredit are not microentrepreneurs by choice and would gladly take a factory job at reasonable wages if possible. We should not romanticize the idea of the poor as entrepreneurs. The International Labor Organization (ILO) uses a more appropriate term: own account workers. Jobs is the solution Creating opportunities for steady employment at reasonable wages is the best way to take people out of poverty. The ILO states that nothing is more fundamental to poverty reduction than employment. In development economics there is much theoretical and empirical support for the increasing preponderance of wage labor in a developing economy. It is instructive to look at the pattern of poverty and employment over time in China, India and Africa (which together account for about three-quarters of the poor in the world), using World Bank and ILO data. 8 5

People below $2/day People below $2/day Late 1980s Late 1990s China 67.4% 50.1% India 83.2% 78.8% Africa 76.1% 76.1% Employment/Population Employment/Population Late 1980s Late 1990s China 51.0% 58.7% India 29.5% 35.8% Africa 33.4% 30.1% In China, where the incidence of poverty has declined significantly, a large and growing fraction of the population is employed. In Africa, where the incidence of poverty has remained unchanged, a small and shrinking fraction of the population is employed. India s performance lies somewhere in between. India s efforts at poverty reduction have been hampered by its poor performance in job creation. India s jobless growth is the result of a distorted emphasis on capital intensive and skill intensive development path. 9 Capital intensive sectors, such as heavy manufacturing, and skill intensive sectors, such as information technology, will not solve India s poverty problem. The trickle down effects of general economic growth are too little and too slow. India needs to emphasize growth in labor intensive, low-skill sectors such as light manufacturing, garments and tourism. Seven world-class Indian Institutes of Technology do not compensate for 39% illiteracy rate. 6

Big is better Many people who have jobs are still stuck below the poverty line the working poor. Whether an employee is poor or not depends on her wages, size of the household, and the income of other household members. It is not enough to create jobs; we also have to increase productivity such that the wages are high enough to enable the employees to rise above poverty. Working poor/employment Working poor/employment Late 1980s Late 1990s China 79.6% 35.2% India 75.0% 62.0% Africa 63.4% 65.4% On this dimension too, India s performance is mediocre and the situation in Africa is dismal. One cause of this poor growth in productivity in India is inadequate scale economies in its enterprises. The average firm size in India is less then one-tenth the comparable size in other emerging economies. 10 The emphasis on microcredit will only make this problem worse. Rather than lending $200 to 500 women so that each can buy a sowing machine and set up a microenterprise manufacturing garments, it is much better to lend $100,000 to an entrepreneur with managerial capabilities and business acumen and help her to set up a garment manufacturing business employing 500 people. Now the business can exploit economies of scale, deploy specialized assets, and use modern business processes to generate value for both its owners and employees. 7

Failure of public services Poverty cannot be defined only in economic terms; it is about a much broader set of needs that permit well being. Amartya Sen, the Nobel Prize economist, eloquently argues that development can be seen as a process of expanding the real freedoms that people enjoy. 11 Social, cultural and political freedoms are desirable in and of themselves, and also enablers of individual income growth. Services such as public safety, basic education, public health and infrastructure nurture these freedoms, and increase the productivity and employability of the poor, and thus their income and well-being. In recent years, the political ideology of the world has shifted decisively towards an increased role for markets and a correspondingly decreased role for the state. But, the role of the state has certainly not been eliminated, nor should it be. The state is responsible for basic education, public health, water, sanitation, public safety and infrastructure. The government in every developing country certainly professes to accept responsibility for these traditional functions. Yet, it has failed dismally to deliver on its promises. As an example of the failure of public services, consider the case of India. The Indian economy is growing rapidly, the stock market is at an all time high, Indian companies are expanding abroad, and a large middle class is emerging. It is the best of times. Contrast this with another India. There is persistent income inequality and gender inequality. 79% of Indians are below the commonly used $2/day poverty line. 39% of adults are 8

illiterate. 10% of boys and 25% of girls do not attend even primary school. 49% of children are underweight for their age. 9% of children die in the first five years of their lives. 31% of rural households and 9% or urban households do not have access to safe drinking water. 81% of rural households and 19% or urban households do not have a toilet. 400,000 children die of diarrhea (a waterborne disease) every year. The boom in the private sector has been accompanied by a significant failure of the state. The cost of this failure is borne disproportionably by the poor. The rich often purchase these services from private enterprises. The middle class are the main beneficiaries of the public service expenditures. The poor have no or little access to these services, or get very low quality public services, or pay very high prices for private services. For example, the rich go to world-class private hospitals and clinics. The middle class has access to reasonable public health facilities. While public health centers do exist to serve rural and poor areas, these centers are grossly under funded and understaffed. Even worse, the staff are under qualified, and often absent. Children of the rich go to exclusive private schools. The middle class uses a mix of private and public schools. Children of the poor often do not go to school or go to low quality public schools. In one survey, a quarter of the teachers were absent and another quarter were present but not teaching. Absentee rates for teachers and health workers are higher in poorer regions. The rich have ample access to clean water: they purchase bottled drinking water, drill private tube wells and use booster pumps. The middle class settles for piped water even if only for a few hours a day. The poor have no or little access to clean public water supply. The rich hire private guards. The middle class live in 9

reasonably well policed neighborhoods. The poor have little protection from thugs and criminals. The burden of failure of public services is borne disproportionably by women, which exacerbates gender inequality. Lack of access to toilets poses a bigger problem for women because of anatomy, modesty and susceptibility to attack. Women often lose much time to hauling buckets of water over long distances. Women are more likely than men to need medical care; they are expected to care for sick family members, especially children. Girls attend school less often, especially in poor families. Markets are not the solution There is a growing neoliberal movement which looks to the private sector for the solution to the failure of public services. There is much debate about whether the direct production of these services should be privatized. But, few would argue that the state can totally avoid its responsibilities. For example, if water supply is privatized, the government needs to regulate the rates or ensure that the poor have enough purchasing power to buy water. In the case of a public good such as sanitation and public health, the market cannot solve the problem. Even late Milton Friedman advocated school voucher system, and not for the state to withdraw totally from the field of education. The state must be responsible for services when there is a natural monopoly (piped water), when it is a public good (public health), and for the sake of equity (education). When the state fails, the market might be a partial complement, but it cannot be a total substitute. 10

The business guru CK Prahalad has said if people have no sewage and drinking water, should we also deny them televisions and cell phones? 12 Writing about the slums of Mumbai, he argues that the poor accept that access to running water is not a realistic option and therefore spend their income on things that they can get now that improve the quality of their lives. 13 This opens up a market, and he urges private companies to make significant profits by selling to the bottom of the pyramid (BOP). The real issue which the BOP proposition glosses over is: why do the poor accept that access to running water is not a realistic option? Even if they do, why should we all accept this bleak view? Instead, we should emphasize the failure of government and attempt to correct it. Giving a voice to the poor is a central aspect of the development process. That is what the civil society, for example Oxfam, is attempting to do. 14 In many developing countries, an autocratic government has denied a voice to the poor. Even in developing countries with a representative democracy, the political process has been hijacked by various vested interests. The business community, bureaucrats, politicians and the media are full of self congratulations on the booming private sector for example, on the increased penetration of cell phones. However, the representative image of a developing country is not a cell phone, but rather defecating in public. For example, in Mumbai, the business capital of India, about 50% of the people defecate outside. There is no magic solution, but the starting point is passion and anger at the failure of the state to provide these basic services. 11

Appealing to private companies to help the poor on the grounds of corporate social responsibility has not been an effective strategy. But, we can demand that private companies at a minimum should not drown out the voice of the poor. For example, sustaining a social movement to empower women is more difficult in the pervasive presence of sexist advertisements, such as those for Fair & Lovely, the whitening cream marketed by Unilever. Self-regulation by the private sector might be the solution. The civil society, with good intentions, often tries to supply the services the state has failed to provide. The problem is that the civil society has neither the resources nor the economies of scale to provide these services to any significant degree. Instead, the civil society should attempt to strengthen the state, support the voice of the poor, and be a catalyst in the political process. Conclusion Microcredit has received much attention and has grown rapidly in recent years. Women, who account for the bulk of the clients of microcredit, have benefited in terms of increased self-esteem and empowerment. But, microcredit has not had a significant impact on alleviating poverty. The women run businesses with low skills, little capital and no scale economies, and as a result do not earn enough to rise out of poverty. Creating employment and increasing productivity is the best solution to poverty. We should emphasize the role of the government in providing basic public services, which have a direct and significant impact on productivity. 1 Sabharwal, G. From the margin to the mainstream. Micro-Finance Programmes and Women s 12

Empowerment: The Bangladesh Experience. University of Wales, Swansea. Available at http://www.gdrc.org/icm/wind/geeta.pdf. 2000 2 Sebstad, J. and G. Chen. Overview of studies on the impact of microenterprise credit, AIMS, USAID, Washington. 1996. 3 Morduch, J. Does microfinance really help the poor? New evidence from flagship programs in Bangladesh. Harvard Institute of International Development and Hoover Institution, Stanford University. http://www.wws.princeton.edu/~rpds/downloads/morduch_microfinance_poor.pdf. 1998. 4 Macro credit, The Economist, 21 October, 2006 5 Hulme, D. and P. Mosley. Finance against poverty. Routledge, 1996. 6 Dichter, T.W. Hype and Hope: The Worrisome State of the Microcredit Movement. Available at http://www.microfinancegateway.org/content/article/detail/31747, 2006. 7 Banerjee, A. and E. Duflo. The economic lives of the poor. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2006. 8 Majid, N. On the evolution of employment structure in developing countries. Employment Strategy Papers, International Labor Organization. 2005. 9 Kochhar, K. et al. India s pattern of development: What happened, what follows? Journal of Monetaary Economics. 2006. 10 Ibid. 11 Sen, A. Development as Freedom. Anchor Books, 2000. 12 Selling to the Poor. Time, 17 April, 2005. 13 Prahalad, C.K., and A. Hammond. Serving the world s poor profitably. Harvard Business Review, 2002. 14 Oxfam. In the public interest. Oxfam International, 2006. 13