THE IMPACT OF CORRUPTION ON THE DIRECT FOREIGN INVESTMENT: CROSS-COUNTRY TESTS USING DYNAMIC PANEL DATA

Similar documents
REGIONAL INTEGRATION IN THE AMERICAS: THE IMPACT OF THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS

Regional Scores. African countries Press Freedom Ratings 2001

FREEDOM OF THE PRESS 2008

GLOBAL RISKS OF CONCERN TO BUSINESS WEF EXECUTIVE OPINION SURVEY RESULTS SEPTEMBER 2017

GLOBAL PRESS FREEDOM RANKINGS

Geoterm and Symbol Definition Sentence. consumption. developed country. developing country. gross domestic product (GDP) per capita

Committee for Development Policy Seventh Session March 2005 PURCHASING POWER PARITY (PPP) Note by the Secretariat

Proforma Cost for national UN Volunteers for UN Partner Agencies

Country pairings for the second cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption

Proforma Cost for National UN Volunteers for UN Partner Agencies for National UN. months) Afghanistan 14,030 12,443 4,836

Transparency International Corruption Perceptions Index 2013

Copyright Act - Subsidiary Legislation CHAPTER 311 COPYRIGHT ACT. SUBSIDIARY LEGlSLA non. List o/subsidiary Legislation

CENTRAL AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN

Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption: country pairings for the second review cycle

LIST OF CONTRACTING STATES AND OTHER SIGNATORIES OF THE CONVENTION (as of January 11, 2018)

Voluntary Scale of Contributions

Transparency International Corruption Perceptions Index 2014

KYOTO PROTOCOL STATUS OF RATIFICATION

Contracting Parties to the Ramsar Convention

Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption: country pairings for the second review cycle

TD/B/Inf.222. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. Membership of UNCTAD and membership of the Trade and Development Board

CORRUPTION PERCEPTIONS INDEX 2013.

CORRUPTION PERCEPTIONS INDEX 2013.

STATUS OF THE CONVENTION ON THE PROHIBITION OF THE DEVELOPMENT, PRODUCTION, STOCKPILING AND USE OF CHEMICAL WEAPONS AND ON THEIR DESTRUCTION

LIST OF CHINESE EMBASSIES OVERSEAS Extracted from Ministry of Foreign Affairs of the People s Republic of China *

A Partial Solution. To the Fundamental Problem of Causal Inference

Status of National Reports received for the United Nations Conference on Housing and Sustainable Urban Development (Habitat III)

GENTING DREAM IMMIGRATION & VISA REQUIREMENTS FOR THAILAND, MYANMAR & INDONESIA

corruption perceptions index

A) List of third countries whose nationals must be in possession of visas when crossing the external borders. 1. States

CORRUPTION PERCEPTIONS INDEX 2012.

Proforma Cost Overview for national UN Volunteers for UN Peace Operations (DPA/DPKO)

A Practical Guide To Patent Cooperation Treaty (PCT)

( ) Page: 1/12 STATUS OF NOTIFICATIONS OF NATIONAL LEGISLATION ON CUSTOMS VALUATION AND RESPONSES TO THE CHECKLIST OF ISSUES

A) List of third countries whose nationals must be in possession of visas when crossing the external borders. 1. States

TABLE OF COUNTRIES WHOSE CITIZENS, HOLDERS OF ORDINARY PASSPORTS, REQUIRE/DO NOT REQUIRE VISAS TO ENTER BULGARIA

INCOME AND EXIT TO ARGENTINA

The Henley & Partners - Kochenov GENERAL RANKING

Country pairings for the second review cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption

2017 BWC Implementation Support Unit staff costs

corruption perceptions index

OFFICIAL NAMES OF THE UNITED NATIONS MEMBERSHIP

Overview of the status of UNCITRAL Conventions and Model Laws x = ratification, accession or enactment s = signature only

corruption perceptions index 2016

Country pairings for the first cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption

CUSTOMS AND EXCISE ACT, AMENDMENT OF SCHEDULE NO. 2 (NO. 2/3/5)

Bahrain, Ecuador, Indonesia, Japan, Peru, Philippines, Republic of Korea, Serbia and Thailand.

UNHCR, United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees

Country pairings for the first review cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption

Scale of assessments for the financial period

Per Capita Income Guidelines for Operational Purposes

Transparency International Corruption Perceptions Index 2012

Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions 2012

58 Kuwait 83. Macao (SAR China) Maldives. 59 Nauru Jamaica Botswana Bolivia 77. Qatar. 63 Bahrain 75. Namibia.

-Ms. Wilkins. AP Human Geography Summer Assignment

Statistical Appendix 2 for Chapter 2 of World Happiness Report March 1, 2018

Japan s s Strategy for Regional Trade Agreements

Governing Body Geneva, November 2006 LILS FOR INFORMATION. Ratification and promotion of fundamental ILO Conventions

Country pairings for the first review cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption

India International Mathematics Competition 2017 (InIMC 2017) July 2017

Visiting Forces. Head of Joint Justice Command. Head of Criminal Justice Services. Case Management Team Leader. Approved by.

CAC/COSP/IRG/2018/CRP.9

The requirements for the different countries may be found on the Bahamas official web page at:

CANADIAN INTERNATIONAL CHARITIES BY COUNTRY OF OPERATION

North/ South America U.S.A. agreements. State Parties of. Eastern Europe. Kyrgyzstan. Cape Verde. Moldova Andorra Africa. Turkmenistan.

Thirty-seventh Session. Rome, 25 June - 2 July Third Report of the Credentials Committee

UNITED NATIONS FINANCIAL PRESENTATION. UN Cash Position. 18 May 2007 (brought forward) Alicia Barcena Under Secretary-General for Management

Candidates to lower or single house of parliament, a Share of women in the parliament, 2009 (%) of parliament 2008 Country or area

**Certificate of Free Sale Request Form** B

Global Environment Facility

Charting Cambodia s Economy, 1H 2017

Certificate of Free Sale Request Form

Illustration of Proposed Quota and Voting Shares--By Member 1/ (In percent)

Open Doors Foreign Scholars

IMO MANDATORY REPORTS UNDER MARPOL. Analysis and evaluation of deficiency reports and mandatory reports under MARPOL for Note by the Secretariat

Collective Intelligence Daudi Were, Project

NAP Global Network. Where We Work. April 2018

CPI 2006 Regional Results: EU and Other Western European

COUNTRIES/AREAS BY REGION WHOSE NATIVES ARE ELIGIBLE FOR DV-2019

ANNEX IV: RATES APPLICABLE FOR UNIT CONTRIBUTIONS

Entry requirements to Mexico for foreign visitors that may be asked upon entry by immigration officials

ANNEX IV: RATES APPLICABLE FOR UNIT

Figure 1: Global participation in reporting military expenditures ( )

Admission of NGOs to official partnership with UNESCO or of Foundations and other similar institutions to official relations with UNESCO

ANNEXES. to the. Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

THE DEATH PENALTY LIST OF ABOLITIONIST AND RETENTIONIST COUNTRIES (DECEMBER 1991)

**Certificate of Cosmetics Good Manufacturing Practice (GMP) Form**

List of eligible countries/areas for the Diversity Visa 2018 Lottery

COMMISSION ON PHYTOSANITARY MEASURES

Hundred and Thirty-eighth Session. Rome, March Scale of Contributions

Millennium Profiles Demographic & Social Energy Environment Industry National Accounts Trade. Social indicators. Introduction Statistics

ALLEGATO IV-RATES APPLICABLE FOR UNIT CONTRIBUTIONS

Human Development Index and its components

Open Doors Foreign Scholars

Geographical grouping 1

NOTE BY THE TECHNICAL SECRETARIAT STATUS OF PARTICIPATION IN THE CHEMICAL WEAPONS CONVENTION AS AT 17 OCTOBER 2015

Figure 2: Range of scores, Global Gender Gap Index and subindexes, 2016

2018 Social Progress Index

NOTE BY THE TECHNICAL SECRETARIAT STATUS OF PARTICIPATION IN THE CHEMICAL WEAPONS CONVENTION AS AT 16 JUNE 2018

Global Prevalence of Adult Overweight & Obesity by Region

Transcription:

THE IMPACT OF CORRUPTION ON THE DIRECT FOREIGN INVESTMENT: CROSS-COUNTRY TESTS USING DYNAMIC PANEL DATA Décio Bottechia Júnior,Banco do Brasil: dbj_dbj@hotmail.com Tito Belchior Silva Moreira,Catholic University of Brasilia: tito@pos.ucb.br Geraldo da Silva e Souza,Embrapa: Geraldo.souza@embrapa.com.br Abstract This paper investigates whether corruption affects the direct foreign investment considering estimates of panel data for 57 countries from 1999 to 2010. The results show empirical evidences that higher levels of perceived corruption have an inversely proportional relationship with the investment. Keywords: Corruption, direct foreign investment, Panel data. Jel classification: K42, F21 (*) The authors would like to thank the CNPq (Conselho Nacional de Pesquisa the National Research Council) for its financial support. 1. Introduction Mauro (2004) stresses that there is increasing recognition that corruption has substantial, adverse effects on economic growth. But if the costs of corruption are so high, why don t countries strive to improve their institutions and root out corruption? Why do many countries appear to be stuck in vicious circles of widespread corruption and low economic growth, often accompanied by ever-changing governments through revolutions and coups? A possible explanation is that when corruption is widespread, individuals do not have incentives to fight it even if everybody would be better off without it. The author develops two models involving strategic complementarities and multiple equilibria attempt to illustrate this formally. This review presented above shows that there is no consensus on the direction of the effect of corruption on investment. After all, corruption contributes to increase or decrease investment in the nations. Mauro (1995) analyzes the determinants factors in the domestic investment for a cross section of countries. The empirical results show that corruption is found to lower investment, thereby lowering economic growth. Habib and Zurawicki (2002) examine the impact of corruption on foreign direct investment (FDI). First, the authors analyze the level of corruption in the host countries. Second, they examine the absolute difference in the corruption level between the host and the home country. The analysis provides support for negative impacts of both and the results suggest that foreign investment generally avoid corruption because it is considering wrong and it can create operational inefficiencies. 14

This paper investigates whether corruption affects the direct foreign investment considering estimates of panel data for 57 countries from 1999 to 2010. We expect a negative association between corruption and foreign direct investment (FDI), even after controlling for a variety of other determinants such as real interest rate, risk premium and domestic investment/gdp ratio. We assume that the higher the level of corruption in a given country, the greater the perception among foreign investors that the country risk will increase. As a consequence, increase the risk premium of the said country and also of the real interest rate, which will result in lower levels of foreign investment. In addition, investors seek countries with capital scarcity or who have low levels of the domestic investment / GDP ratio in order to obtain higher rates of return on their investments. Accordingly, we expect a negative relationship between the ratio domestic investment / GDP and foreign investment flows. Business environments pervading corruption and impunity generate uncertainties and insecurities that result in increases business costs - due, for example, the release of bribery to obtain timely environmental permits, records and documentation notary. Finally, the uncertainty in the economy due to a corrupt environment is not favorable to business, since increase the difficult to obtain estimates of basic questions to base decisions about investments in a particular country, as a simple projection or a calculation of the internal rate of return. An environment of legal uncertainty and weak institutions also creates uncertainty about the compliance of contracts and certainly weighs negatively on the decision to invest in the country. Our article proceeds as follows. We cover the brief review of the literature in Section 2 and a methodological aspects in Section. The empirical results are presented in Section 4. In Section 5 we present the main conclusions. 2. Literature review Mauro (2004) argues that seems to have emerged a consensus that corruption and other aspects of poor governance and weak institutions have substantial, adverse effects on economic growth. The author stresses that many countries seem to be unable to improve their institutions and curb corruption. Economists and policymakers have long recognized that institutions matter in determining economic performance. 15

The literature on rent seeking has analyzed the relationship between trade distortions, rent seeking behavior, and economic inefficiencies (Krueger, 1974). North (1990) has argued that weak property rights may worsen a country s economic performance. The author states that society is formed by institutions, defined by him as the rules that define actions. These rules are composed of laws and moral values of society and they can create incentives in terms of human interactions, political, social or economic resulting in transactions occurring in various areas, having a certain cost. When these costs are high, the quality of the transactions is compromised (Norton, 1990). In this context, we infer that corruption can raise transaction costs for economic agents, for example, due to payment of bribes. Shleifer and Vishny (1993) show that for invest in a Russian company (post-communist) the foreigner must bribe all departments involved in foreign investment. The authors refer to the office of foreign investment, the ministries of industry and finance, the executive of the local government, the congress, the central bank, among other government agencies. They stress that the result is that foreigners do not invest in Russia. These bureaucracies, which can paralyze the project at any time, impede investment and growth worldwide, but especially in countries where the government is weak. Murphy, Shleifer, and Vishny (1991) have suggested that countries where talented people are allocated to rent-seeking activities will tend to grow more slowly. Shleifer and Vishny (1993) present two propositions about corruption. First, the structures of government institutions and of the political process are very important determinants of the level of corruption. In particular, weak governments that do not control their agencies experience very high corruption levels. Second, the illegality of corruption and the need for secrecy make it much more distortionary and costly than its sister activity, taxation. These results may explain why, in some less developed countries, corruption is so high and so costly to development. Hall and Jones (1996) aim investigate why output per work varies enormously across countries. According their results, a high-productivity country has institutions that favor production over diversion. It probably takes the form of government institutions, especially law enforcement, but it also likely includes systems of moral and ethics supported by other nongovernment institutions. The authors stress that talented people never pursue careers of rent seeking or corruption; they produce goods. 16

During the last two decades there has been considerable research on the macroeconomic consequences of corruption. Part of the literature has studied the effects of corruption on inflation, economic growth and others macroeconomics indicators. Other part has concluded that the economic costs of corruption and the weak governance are relevant. The availability of indices of corruption, specially the corruption perception index, has stimulated a flurry of empirical studies (for example, Kaufmann, Kraay, and Zoido-Lobatón, 1999; Knack and Keefer, 1995; and Mauro, 1995; Bardhan, 1997; Tanzi, 1998 and Al-Marhubi, 2000). Sanyal and Samanta (2008) examined US foreign direct investment outflows with respect to the level of corruption, in the form of bribery, in 42 recipient countries over a five-year period. Analysis indicates that US firms are less likely to invest in countries where bribery, as measured by the Corruption Perceptions Index (CPI), is widespread. 3. Methodological aspects We use a balanced panel data for 28 countries 1 with annual data from 1999 to 2010 and an unbalanced panel data for 57 countries 2 for the same period. The variables and the notation used in this article (in parentheses) are as follow. The variables foreign direct investment (FDI), risk premium (risk) and investment/gdp (Investment/GDP) were obtained in the site of World Development Indicators. The variable corruption perception index (corruption) 3 was obtained in the site Transparency International. In the section 4 we estimate a dynamic balanced panel data (Arellano-Bond/Blundell- Bond: GMM - robust standard errors) for 28 countries in table 1. The table 1 presents four specifications of econometric models. The model 1 presents the variable dependent (FDI) as function of its lagged value in the period t-1 and t-2 and also of the interest variable, i.e., the corruption. We add control variables to the other models. The model 2 adds to model 1 the real interest rate variable. The model 3 adds to model 2 the risk premium variable and the model 4 adds to model 3 the investment/gdp ratio. We follow the same procedure for the table 2 1 The counties of the balanced panel are Azerbaijan, Bolivia, Brazil, Bulgaria, Canada, Czech Republic, Egypt, Hong Kong, Hungary, Israel, Japan, Kenya, Latvia, Lithuania, Malawi, Malaysia, Mexico, Moldova, Namibia, New Zealand, Nigeria, Philippines, Singapore, South Africa, Tanzania, Uganda, Vietnam and Zambia. 2 The countries of the unbalanced panel include all the countries of the balanced panel and more Albania, Algeria, Armenia, Bahamas, Bahrain, Barbados, Belize, Cape Verde, Dominica, Fiji, Gambia, Grenada, Guyana, Jamaica, Kyrgyzstan, Laos, Lebanon, Lesotho, Mauritania, Papua New Guinea, Saint Lucia, Saint Vincent and the Grenadines, Seychelles, Sierra Leone, Solomon Islands, Sri Lanka, Swaziland, Trinidad and Tobago and Yemen. 3 The range of the score of corruption perception index (CPI) is 0 to 1. When the score approaches 1, the country presented very low corruption perception index. By convenience, we transform this CPI where (1 CPI)*10 = corruption. In this sense, when the score approaches 10, the country presented very high corruption perception index. 17

considering a dynamic unbalanced panel data (Arellano-Bond/Blundell-Bond: GMM - robust standard errors) for 57 countries. The estimates of model parameters are obtained by the method known as GMM-system, developed by Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998). This method is more appropriate to correct the problems typical statistical models of dynamic panel, especially when the instruments are considered weak due to the relatively high level of persistence of the dependent variable. In these regression models, the GMM estimator is also advantageous because it does not need additional valid instruments, because they employ lags of its own variables besides being consistent even in the presence of endogenous explanatory variables are not strictly exogenous and which are possibly correlated with present and past accomplishments of the error term. 4. Empirical results The empirical results for the balanced panel data are presented in Table 1. The estimated coefficients of the constant term in all models are statistically significant at the 5% level. The estimated coefficients of the FDI t 1 and FDI t 2 are statistically significant at 1% level in all models. They show inertial effects with coefficient positive and negative respectively. Noticing that the positive coefficients are greater that the negatives. All coefficients statistically significant have the expected signs. The signs of the estimated coefficients of the corruption perception are negative and they are statistically significant at 5% level in all models. The signs of the estimated coefficients of the real interest rate are negative and they are marginally significant at 10% level in the models 2, 3 and 4. The signs of the estimated coefficients of the risk premium are negative and they are statistically significant at 5% level according to results of models 3 and 4. The estimated coefficient of the control variable Investment/GDP is not statistically significant according to model 4. 18

Table 1 System dynamic panel-data estimation - Arellano-Bond/Blundell-Bond: GMM - robust standard errors (Balanced model) Dependent variable: Direct Foreign Investment (DFI) Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Constant 2.85e+10 ** [1.18e+10] 3.80e+10 * [1.33e+10] 4.13e+10 * [1.41e+10] 3.86e+10 * [1.37e+10] (DFI) t-1 0.6995464 * [0.0492009] 0.6779617 * [0.0499075] 0.6705324 * [0.0472752] 0.6656354 * [0.0465997] (DFI) t-2-0.3753226 * [0.1340012] -0.3885314 * [0.1438665] -0.3910232 * [0.1461697] -0.3879684 * [0.1442802] (Corruption) t -4.11e+09 ** [1.95e+09] -5.25e+09 ** [2.19e+09] -5.17e+09 ** [2.19e+09] -5.25e+09 ** [2.23e+09] (Real interest rate) t -4.07e+08 *** [2.15e+08] -3.11e+08 *** [1.79e+08] -2.87e+08 *** [1.74e+08] (Risk premium) t -6.68e+08 ** [3.16e+08] -6.71e+08 ** [3.13e+08] (Investment/GDP) t 131982.8 [141816.6] Other statistics Serial correlation 1 st order (p-value) 0.0139 0.0073 0.0072 0.0087 2 nd order (p-value) 0.0981 0.1288 0.1362 0.1344 Sargan test (p-value) 0.9999 0.9999 0.9999 0.9999 Number of obs. 280 280 280 280 Number instruments 130 67 68 69 Source: elaborated by authors. Note 1: [.] = Robust standard error. Note 2: Arellano Bond test zero autocorrelation in first-differenced errors, Ho: no autocorrelation. Note 3: Sargan test of overidentifying restrictions, Ho: overidentifying restrictions are valid. Note 4: * = Sig. at 1% level; ** = Sig. at 5% level; *** = Sig. at 10% level. It is observed that the null hypothesis of no autocorrelation of the second-order was not rejected with a p-value > 0.09 in all models according to table 1. We use the test for validity of the instruments, known as Sargan test, and obtained a p-value of 0.9999 for all the models. Therefore, do not reject the null hypothesis validation of instruments. The empirical results presented in table 2 are similar to results of table 1. However, the empirical results for unbalanced panel-data show the estimated coefficient of the real interest rate statistically significant at 5% level. In the table 1 the same coefficient is marginally significant at 10% level. 19

Table 2 System dynamic panel-data estimation - Arellano-Bond/Blundell-Bond: GMM - robust standard errors (Unbalanced model) Dependent variable: Direct Foreign Investment (DFI) Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Constant 3.27e+10** [1.32e+10] 3.46e+10* [1.27e+10] 3.73e+10* [1.33e+10] 3.47e+10* [1.27e+10] (DFI) t-1 0.6959402* [.0552924] 0.6913596* [0.0533641] 0.6845014* [0.0508867] 0.6769978* [.0497628] (DFI) t-2-0.3761183* [0.1435403] -0.3793256* [0.1431425] -0.381445* [0.1450982] -0.3795423* [0.1434445] (Corruption) t -4.90e+09** [2.11e+09] -4.96e+09** [2.02e+09] -4.90e+09** [1.97e+09] -5.01e+09** [2.00e+09] Year (Real interest rate) t (Risk premium) t -1.99e+08** [9.39e+07] -1.46e+08** [7.19e+07] -5.11e+08** [2.61e+08] -1.42e+08** [7.21e+07] -5.09e+08** [2.58e+08] (Investment/GDP) t 146899 [108250.1] Other statistics Serial correlation 1 st order (p-value) 0.0138 0.0096 0.0095 0.0098 2 nd order (p-value) 0.1004 0.1092 0.1106 0.1128 Sargan test (p-value) 0.8302 0.8445 0.8389 0.2563 Number of obs. 475 447 447 435 Number instruments 66 55 68 69 Source: elaborated by authors. Note 1: [.] = Robust standard error. Note 2: Arellano Bond test zero autocorrelation in first-differenced errors, Ho: no autocorrelation. Note 3: Sargan test of overidentifying restrictions, Ho: overidentifying restrictions are valid. Note 4: * = Sig. at 1% level; ** = Sig. at 5% level; *** = Sig. at 10% level. 6. Conclusions This paper aims evaluate whether corruption affects the foreign direct investment (FDI) considering two estimates of a dynamic panel data from 1999 to 2010. The first estimative is a balanced dynamic panel data for 28 countries and the second one is a dynamic panel data for 57 countries. We find a significant negative association between corruption and FDI, even after controlling for a variety of other determinants of the latter. 20

References Al-Marhubi, Fahim A. (2000). Corrupção e Inflação. Economics Letters n. 66, p. 199-202. Arellano, M. & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental-variable estimation of errorcomponents model. Journal of Econometrics, 68:29 52. Bardhan, Pranab, (1997). Corruption and Development: A Review of Issues, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 35, No. 3, pp. 1320 46. Blundell, R. & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87:115 143. Habibi, Mohsin and Leon Zurawicki (2002). Journal of International Business Studies, vol. 33, no. 2, pp. 291-307, 2002 Hall, Robert E. and Charles I. Jones (1996). The Productivity of Nations. NBER Working Papers Series, Working Paper 5812. Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Pablo Zoido-Lobatón, (1999). Governance Matters, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2196 (Washington: World Bank). Knack, Stephen, and Philip Keefer, (1995). Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross- Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures, Economics and Politics, Vol. 7, No. 3, pp. 207 27. Krueger, Anne O., (1974). The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society, American Economic Review, Vol. 64, No. 3, pp. 291 303. Mauro, Paolo. (2004). The Persistence of Corruption and Solow Economic Growth. IMF Staff Papers, Vol.51, No. 01, International Monetary Fund. 21

Mauro, Paolo (1995). Corruption and Growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.110, N.3, pp. 681-712. Murphy, Kevin M., Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny, (1991). The Allocation of Talent: Implications for Growth, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 106, pp. 503 30. North, Douglass C. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance, New York: Cambridge University Press. Sanyal, R. and S. Samanta (2008), Effect of Perception of Corruption On Outward US Foreign Direct Investment, Global Business and Economics Review, 10: 123-140. Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert Vishny, (1993). Corruption, Quarterly Journal of Economics,Vol. 108, No. 3, pp. 599 617. Tanzi,V. (1998). Corruption around the world: causes, consequences, scope, and cures. IMF Working Paper WP/98/ 63, 1 39. 22