TRADE AND WAGE INEQUALITY: THE HONG KONG CASE

Similar documents
Immigration and Economic Growth: Further. Evidence for Greece

Journal of Economic Cooperation, 29, 2 (2008), 69-84

The widening income dispersion in Hong Kong :

Foreign Remittances have a great role in the development

Volume 30, Issue 2. An empirical investigation of purchasing power parity for a transition economy - Cambodia

Investigating the Relationship between Residential Construction and Economic Growth in a Small Developing Country: The Case of Barbados

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Do Remittances Transmit the Effect of US Monetary Policy to the Jordanian Economy?

5. Destination Consumption

Population Change and Economic Development in Albania

The impacts of minimum wage policy in china

Determinants of International Capital Flows: The Case of Malaysia

Response of the Philippines Gross Domestic Product to the Global Financial Crisis

Economy ISSN: Vol. 1, No. 2, 37-53, 2014

TOURISM AND POVERTY REDUCTION: EVIDENCE FROM

Crime and economic conditions in Malaysia: An ARDL Bounds Testing Approach

POLICY OPTIONS AND CHALLENGES FOR DEVELOPING ASIA PERSPECTIVES FROM THE IMF AND ASIA APRIL 19-20, 2007 TOKYO

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

ARTNeT Trade Economists Conference Trade in the Asian century - delivering on the promise of economic prosperity rd September 2014

Rural-urban Migration and Urbanization in Gansu Province, China: Evidence from Time-series Analysis

Exports, Education, and Growth in Malaysia

Direction of trade and wage inequality

Wage Inequality and Offshoring: Are They Related?

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Trade Liberalization and Inequality: Re-examining Theory and Empirical Evidence

Foreign Aid, FDI and Economic Growth in East European Countries. Abstract

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES,

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1

International Journal of Economics and Society June 2015, Issue 2

DEPENDENCY OF TURKISH EXCHANGE RATE UNDER ACCESSION CONDITIONS TO EUROPEAN UNION

Volume 31, Issue 4. Can population growth contribute to economic development? New evidence from Singapore

Changing income distribution in China

International Productivity Differences and the Roles of Domestic Investment, FDI and Trade

NEW CANDIDATES FOR THE EURO AREA? SIMILARITY OF SUPPLY AND DEMAND SHOCKS IN THE NON-EURO AREA COUNTRIES Stanislav Kappel 1

THE EVALUATION OF OUTPUT CONVERGENCE IN SEVERAL CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES

Trade, Technology, and Institutions: How Do They Affect Wage Inequality? Evidence from Indian Manufacturing. Amit Sadhukhan 1.

Trade, foreign investment, and wage inequality in developing countries

Asian Research Consortium

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Aid-Growth Nexus in South Asia: Evidence from Time Series and Panel Cointegration

THE USA S INTERNATIONAL TRAVEL DEMAND AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN TURKEY: A CAUSALITY ANALYSIS: ( )

THE IMPACT OF MIGRANTS REMITTANCES ON ECONOMIC GROWTH EMPIRICAL STUDY: CASE OF ALGERIA ( )

GLOBALIZATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN CAMBODIA

Source: Piketty Saez. Share (in %), excluding capital gains. Figure 1: The top decile income share in the U.S., % 45% 40% 35% 30% 25%

TRADE LIBERALIZATION AND ITS IMPACT ON THE RELATIVE WAGE AND EMPLOYMENT OF UNSKILLED WORKERS IN THE UNITED STATES

A Multivariate Analysis of the Factors that Correlate to the Unemployment Rate. Amit Naik, Tarah Reiter, Amanda Stype

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin

Economic assimilation of Mexican and Chinese immigrants in the United States: is there wage convergence?

China s (Uneven) Progress Against Poverty. Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen Development Research Group, World Bank

Wage inequality and skill premium

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE DETERMINANTS OF FDI IN TUNISIA: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY THROUGH A GRAVITY MODEL

The Macroeconomic Determinants of Outward Foreign Direct Investment: The Case of Kuwait

ECONOMIC TRANSFORMATION AND ITS IMPACT ON INCOME INEQUALITY: EVIDENCE FROM HONG KONG

FURTHER EVIDENCE ON DEFENCE SPENDING AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN NATO COUNTRIES

Explaining the 40 Year Old Wage Differential: Race and Gender in the United States

The Role of Workers Remittances in Development of Jordanian Banking Sector

Crime and Corruption: An International Empirical Study

Asian Journal of Empirical Research

Macroeconomic Determinants of Tariff Policy in Pakistan

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization

Financial Development And Economic Growth Revisited: Time Series Evidence

COINTEGRATION ANALYSIS OF TOURISM DEMAND FOR TURKEY

Labour Market Reform, Rural Migration and Income Inequality in China -- A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Industrial & Labor Relations Review

The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis

POLICY BRIEF. Assessing Labor Market Conditions in Madagascar: i. World Bank INSTAT. May Introduction & Summary

Trade, technology, and China s rising skill demand 1

Wage Structure and Gender Earnings Differentials in China and. India*

Cai et al. Chap.9: The Lewisian Turning Point 183. Chapter 9:

Remittance Inflow and Economic Growth: The Case of Georgia

High Technology Agglomeration and Gender Inequalities

Analysis on Spatial Integration of Thailand and Vietnam Rice Market in Indonesia

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

Inflation and relative price variability in Mexico: the role of remittances

The Relationship between Real Wages and Output: Evidence from Pakistan

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Trade Policy, Agreements and Taxation of Multinationals

Latin American Immigration in the United States: Is There Wage Assimilation Across the Wage Distribution?

The wage gap between the public and the private sector among. Canadian-born and immigrant workers

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

The Improving Relative Status of Black Men

A poverty-inequality trade off?

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different?

Quantitative Analysis of Migration and Development in South Asia

Impact of FDI on Economic Growth: Evidence from Pakistan. Hafiz Muhammad Abubakar Siddique Federal Urdu University, Islamabad, Pakistan.

Globalization: What Did We Miss?

IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY

Rising Income Inequality in Asia

International Trade and Inequality

The Impact of Foreign Workers on Labour Productivity in Malaysian Manufacturing Sector

SSRG International Journal of Economics and Management Studies (SSRG-IJEMS) volume 4 Issue 8 August 2017

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Income Inequality and Trade Protection

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

An Overview of the Chinese Economy Foundation Part: Macro-economy of the Mainland

Will Inequality Affect Growth? Evidence from USA and China since 1980

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Transcription:

PER_217.fm Page 131 Tuesday, April 13, 2004 5:43 PM Pacific Economic Review, 9: 2 (2004) pp. 131 142 Blackwell Oxford, PER Pacific 1361-374X 2004 June 92Original trade c. s. fan 2004 Blackwell and Economic and UK Article wage Publishing, k. y. Publishing inequality cheung Review Ltd. Asia Pty Ltd TRADE AND WAGE INEQUALITY: THE HONG KONG CASE C. SIMON FAN* Lingnan University, Hong Kong KUI-YIN CHEUNG Lingnan University, Hong Kong Abstract. This paper examines the effects of Hong Kong mainland China trade on the wage inequality in Hong Kong. Because of the large volume of trade and the large income disparity between these two regions, this empirical study provides a good test of the theories on North South trade. The econometric analyses show that the relative wage between the skilled and unskilled workers in Hong Kong increased as the share of the volume of Hong Kong s trade with mainland China in Hong Kong s total trade volume rose. 1. INTRODUCTION Since the early 1980s the demand for less skilled labor has fallen, so that the income gap between skilled and unskilled workers has widened in most developed economies (e.g. Gottschalk and Smeeding, 1997). At the same time, we have witnessed increasing globalization. The rough concordance of increasing income inequality in many developed countries with their increasing trade with developing countries has created a heated debate about the effects of trade on wage inequality. On one hand, some economists, notably Wood in a series of papers (Wood, 1995; 1997, 1998), believe that wage inequality has risen because factor price equalization has been at work through the increasing trading activities between developed and developing countries. Because developed countries are abundant in skilled labor, while developing countries are abundant in unskilled labor, the well-known Stolper Samuelson theorem clearly predicts that unskilled (skilled) workers in developed countries will earn lower (higher) real wage rates from trading with developing countries. 1 On the other hand, other economists (e.g. Krugman, 1995; Richardson, 1995) argue that the effects of trade on wage inequality may not be empirically significant. In particular, they point out that the trade volume between some advanced countries (e.g. the United States) and developing countries still constitutes only a small percentage of total spending for the advanced nations. This debate has fostered much empirical research on *Address for correspondence: Department of Economics, Lingnan University, Tuen Mun, Hong Kong; Email: fansimon@ln.edu.hk. We are grateful to an anonymous referee, whose insightful comments and suggestions improved the quality of the paper significantly. The remaining errors are our own. 1 In fact, the impact of trade on income inequality has been a major concern to less skilled workers in developed countries; see e.g. Unions stage Capitol Hill rally against China trade deal, cnn.com, April 12, 2000. PER: 217 Pages: 12 Proofreader: Wu Yanming Operator: YuYanJun

PER_217.fm Page 132 Tuesday, April 13, 2004 5:43 PM 132 C. S. FAN AND K. Y. CHEUNG the impact of trade and trade liberalization on wage inequality and labor market outcomes. 2 The present paper hopes to contribute to the existing literature by empirically examining the effects of Hong Kong mainland China trade on the wage inequality in Hong Kong. This empirical study is interesting for two reasons. First, the volume of trade between these two regions relative to Hong Kong s GDP has been very large and has increased rapidly over the past two decades; for example, in 1996 the volume of trade between Hong Kong and Chinese mainland was about 123.2% of Hong Kong s GDP. In fact, the flows of goods and capital between southern China, Hong Kong and Taiwan have expanded so rapidly that these regions are often referred to as the Greater China in the literature (e.g. Ash and Kueh, 1993). Second, the income disparity between Hong Kong and mainland China over the last two decades has been very large, despite the fact that China has experienced very rapid economic growth since 1978. For example, in 1992 the average income in mainland China was only US$1,747 in terms of purchasing power parity (PPP), 3 which was only 9.3% of the average income in Hong Kong. Even in the richest province of mainland China, Guangdong, the average income was only US$2,731 (in PPP), which was 14.5% of the average income in Hong Kong in 1992. Thus, the present empirical study should provide a good test of the theories on North South trade. After first discussing the theoretical background and hypotheses, we use cointegration techniques to examine the long-run relationship between wage inequality in Hong Kong and Hong Kong trade with mainland China. In particular, the empirical analysis indicates that relative wages between skilled and unskilled workers in Hong Kong increased significantly as the share of the volume of Hong Kong s trade with mainland China in Hong Kong s total trade volume rose. Meanwhile, the variance decomposition analysis reconfirms that Hong Kong s trade with mainland China has been the most important determinant of the wage inequality in Hong Kong. Thus, the findings are consistent with the implications of the Stolper Samuelson theorem. 2. HYPOTHESES The effects of trade on wage inequality are usually analyzed in a Heckscher Ohlin model with skilled and unskilled labor as the two factors of production. In recent literature, it has been increasingly emphasized that a country s comparative advantage depends mainly on its average level of human capital, rather than its physical capital labor ratio. For example, on the basis of his comprehensive empirical analysis and survey, Wood (1994, p. 116) concludes: Upon examination, the results of these cross-country regression studies seem consistent with the hypothesis that North South trade is based on differences in the availability of skill but not of capital. 2 See e.g. Kambhampati et al. (1997); Reiner and Roland-Holst (1998); Beyer et al. (1999); Robbins and Gindling (1999). 3 World Development Indicators, CD-ROM version, World Bank, 2000.

PER_217.fm Page 133 Tuesday, April 13, 2004 5:43 PM TRADE AND WAGE INEQUALITY 133 In the Heckscher Ohlin framework, international trade follows the pattern of comparative advantage. If two countries have different comparative advantages, their relative prices in autarky will be different. So, when trade is possible between the two countries, market forces will result in a country exporting the good that it has a comparative advantage in. Meanwhile, international trade will cause the convergence of the autarkic relative prices. So the volume of trade and the domestic price of exported goods are positively related. Thus, on the basis of the Stolper Samuelson theorem, there is a close relationship between trade and wage inequality. A simple reasoning for the basic logic of the Stolper Samuelson theorem is provided by Wong (1995, p. 31) and can be readily applied here as follows. In the context of Hong Kong and the Chinese mainland, clearly, mainland China has been abundant in unskilled labor, while Hong Kong has been abundant in skilled labor. So, Hong Kong has a comparative advantage in the production of the goods and services in which skilled labor is more intensively used, and Chinese mainland has a comparative advantage in the production of the goods and services in which unskilled labor is more intensively used. Thus, in Hong Kong the trade between these two regions will expand the production of skillintensive goods and services but reduce the production that is intensive in unskilled labor. The simultaneous expansion of the skill-intensive sector and contraction of the low-skill sector will create an excess demand in skilled labor and an excess supply of unskilled labor, thus widening the wage gap between skilled and unskilled labor. Meanwhile, we note that the per capita income of Hong Kong has been significantly lower than in the United States, Japan and many other of Hong Kong s major trading partners. So the Stolper Samuelson theorem implies that Hong Kong s trade with these rich countries is decreasing the wage gap in Hong Kong. 4 For example, from Table 1 we can see that in 1993 the per capita income of Hong Kong was US$13,890, which was significantly lower than that of the United States (US$22,956) and of Japan (US$25,089). 5 In addition, Hong Kong s statistical yearbooks show that the trade volume between other developing countries and Hong Kong is very small relative to that between mainland China and Hong Kong. Thus, we obtain the following hypothesis: HYPOTHESIS 1. The relative wage between skilled and unskilled workers in Hong Kong increases as the share of the volume of Hong Kong s trade with mainland China in Hong Kong s total trade volume rises. Next, we consider the supply factors that may affect the wage gap. There are competing theories in the economic literature concerning the relationship between the proportion of skilled labor in the population and the rate of return 4 Wood (1997) shows that in Hong Kong the greater openness to trade in the 1960s and 1970s led to a narrowing of the wage gap between skilled and unskilled workers. 5 United Nations (various issues).

PER_217.fm Page 134 Tuesday, April 13, 2004 5:43 PM 134 C. S. FAN AND K. Y. CHEUNG Table 1. Per capita GDP (GNP) in Hong Kong, the USA and Japan, 1982 1994 (in 1990 US$) Hong Kong (2) USA (3) Japan (4) to human capital. On one hand, in the neoclassical framework the law of diminishing returns implies that the wage rate of skilled labor will decrease as the proportion of skilled workers rises. On the other hand, some recent literature (e.g. Lucas, 1988; Acemoglu, 1996) emphasizes the externality effect of human capital, which arises when the investment of an individual in skills training creates benefits for other agents in the economy. Thus, the relationship between the wage gap between skilled and unskilled labor and the proportion of skilled labor is theoretically ambiguous. It will be interesting, therefore, to examine this relationship empirically. In this paper skilled laborers refers to those who have a college/university degree. Moreover, considering that an individual s working experience is another important factor in determining her wage, we included only those who were in their 40s in our sample. Finally, we included the unemployment rate in Hong Kong as a proxy variable for economic environment in our regression analysis, for two reasons: first, it is an important indicator of the business cycles in Hong Kong; second, it is well known that business cycles affect skilled and unskilled workers differently (e.g. Rosen, 1968; Ashenfelter and Ham, 1979). 3. DATA DESCRIPTION % share (5) = (2)/(3) % share (6) = (2)/(4) 1983 6,096 20,204 17,610 30.2 34.6 1984 6,794 21,376 18,665 31.8 36.4 1985 6,823 21,649 19,482 31.5 35 1986 8,560 21,079 19,887 40.6 43 1987 11,658 20,396 20,604 57.2 56.6 1988 12,470 20,434 21,988 61 56.7 1989 11,948 21,753 22,959 54.9 52 1990 12,100 22,442 24,042 53.9 50.3 1991 12,506 22,313 24,880 56 50.3 1992 13,210 22,446 25,072 58.9 52.7 1993 13,890 22,956 25,089 60.5 55.4 1994 15,598 24,193 25,196 64.5 61.9 Hong Kong has experienced significant rise in income inequality over the last two decades. For example, the GINI coefficient increased from 0.451 in 1981 to 0.518 in 1996. 6 In particular, the wage gap between skilled and unskilled labor has been rising. In this paper the wage gap between skilled and unskilled labor is measured as the wage ratio between those who have a university degree and those in the same age group who have received only primary education. 6 Hong Kong Population Census, 1991 and 1996: Census and Statistics Department, Hong Kong.

PER_217.fm Page 135 Tuesday, April 13, 2004 5:43 PM TRADE AND WAGE INEQUALITY 135 Table 2. Average labor income ratio received by heads of households according to the education level of the head of the family 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 Average monthly labor income according to the education level of the head of the family in HK$ of 1990 Primary education 3,269 3,620 4,466 5,002 5,104 University education 12,298 13,699 17,061 19,706 20,211 Distribution of households according to the education level of the head of the family (%) Primary education 35.7 32.3 29.3 25.1 22.3 University education 3.6 4.4 5.6 6.0 8.8 Average labor income ratio according to the education level of the head of the family University/primary education 3.76 3.78 3.84 3.94 3.96 Sources: Author s calculations. The wages for workers with different educational attainment were obtained from an unpublished data set collected by the Hong Kong Census and Statistics Department through its quarterly General Household Survey. This data set provides the information on various earning ranges by education and age on quarterly basis for the period between 1985 and 1992. Based on this data, we calculated the median wage for the group with primary education and those with university degree for the age between 40 and 49. 7 We choose a certain age group in order to control working experience, which affects wage rate. Table 2 documents the wage gap and the proportion of those in Hong Kong s labor force who have a university degree and those who have completed primary education in the 40 49 age group over the period 1982 94. From the table we can see that the wage gap has increased, despite the fact that the supply of skilled labor has also increased. For instance, from 1982 to 1994, although the proportion of the Hong Kong workforce holding a university degree increased from 3.6% to 8.8%, the wage gap increased from 3.76 to 3.96. The data on the unemployment rate in Hong Kong and on Hong Kong mainland China trade were obtained from various issues of the Hong Kong Annual Digest of Statistics. From Table 3 we can see that Hong Kong mainland China trade has been rising rapidly, both in terms of the absolute trade volume and in terms of the share of the volume of Hong Kong s trade with mainland China out of Hong Kong s total trade volume. Finally, in our analysis all variables are transformed into logarithmic forms. The dependent variable is the wage gap between skilled and unskilled labor, and the explanatory variables include: (i) the share of the volume of Hong Kong s trade with mainland China in Hong Kong s total trade volume; (ii) the proportion of those who have a university degree in Hong Kong s labor force; and (iii) the unemployment rate in Hong Kong. 7 Note that the skilled individuals in this sample include both foreign workers and domestic workers living in Hong Kong.

PER_217.fm Page 136 Tuesday, April 13, 2004 5:43 PM 136 C. S. FAN AND K. Y. CHEUNG Table 3. Hong Kong China trade and unemployment rates in Hong Kong, 1982 1994 (HK$m) Total trade with China (HK$bn) (2) Total trade in Hong Kong (HK$bn) (3) % share (4) = (2)/(3) 4. ONOMETRIC ANALYSIS AND EMPIRICAL FINDINGS Unemployment rate in Hong Kong (%)(5) 1982 44.73 270.28 16.55 3.6 1983 61.23 336.14 18.21 4.5 1984 95.10 444.81 21.38 3.9 1985 120.18 466.57 25.76 3.2 1986 140.55 552.49 25.44 2.8 1987 205.40 755.98 27.17 1.7 1988 288.57 991.87 29.09 1.4 1989 343.44 1133.29 30.30 1.1 1990 394.51 1282.40 30.76 1.3 1991 501.08 1544.87 32.44 1.8 1992 628.11 1880.25 33.41 2.0 1993 740.09 2118.85 34.93 2.0 1994 854.72 2420.72 35.31 1.9 In this section we use cointegration techniques to examine the long run relationship between wage inequality in Hong Kong and Hong Kong mainland China trade. A statistical diagnosis for the univariate trend properties of time series is a prerequisite to studying the nexus between these two variables. The causal relation between them is not spurious if the involving variables are non-stationary in the levels, but is stationary in the first or second differences. This procedure is also required to examine the existence of a long-run stable relationship between these variables. To determine the integrating order of the time series variables, the augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF) procedure suggested by Dickey and Fuller (1979) is used to test each variable for a unit root first in its level form, and then in the first difference form. Table 4 presents the results of the unit root tests for four variables: the wage ratio between skilled and unskilled workers; the share of Hong Kong s trade with mainland China; the proportion of university graduates in Hong Kong s labor force; and the unemployment rate in Hong Kong. The second column of table 4 presents the test statistics with a constant, and the third column reports the results when the regression contains both a constant and time trend. On the basis of the critical values reported by MacKinnon (1990), the null hypothesis of a unit root for each variable in its level form cannot be rejected, whether time trend is included in the regressions or not. Thus, all variables are best characterized as integrated of degree one, I(1). The fourth column of Table 4 reports the test results for the first difference form with a constant term, and the fifth column presents the results when the equations had constant and trend terms. The null hypothesis that a unit root exists for each variable is rejected at the 0.01 level of significance in the first difference, which indicates that all variables are characterized as integration of zero in first differencing.

PER_217.fm Page 137 Tuesday, April 13, 2004 5:43 PM TRADE AND WAGE INEQUALITY 137 Table 4. Unit root tests for relative wage, trade share, skilled worker share and unemployment rate a Variable Level form As a stochastic trend has been confirmed for each of the series, the observed time series, which possess trends, can be removed by first differencing. The question is whether there exists some long-run relationship between these variables. A linear combination may exist between two or more economic variables that converge to a long-run equilibrium, even though the series by themselves (at their level forms) are non-stationary. In other words, when they are cointegrated, a linear combination of them may result in stationary. In this paper Johansen s (1991) multivariate cointegrating testing approach based on maximum-likelihood estimation is used to test the null hypothesis of the existence of a long-run relationship between relative wages, Hong Kong China trade, education and the unemployment rate. The advantage of using the Johansen cointegrating test is that it provides a maximum-likelihood estimation procedure, which simultaneously regresses vector autoregressions (error correction method, ECM) to estimate cointegrating vectors. In addition, this method is capable of identifying multiple cointegrating vectors, and it is also orthogonal to an arbitrary normalization. Table 5 presents the testing results from the cointegrating tests for a longrun relationship between trade, education and unemployment rates on relative wages. The eigenvalues are presented in the first column of the table, while the second column gives the likelihood ratio (LR) test statistic: for r = 0, 1,..., k 1, where λ i is the ith largest eigenvalue; Q Γ is the trace statistic and is the test of H 1 (r) against H 1 (k). According to the critical values reported by Osterwald-Lenum (1992), both maximal eigenvalue test statistics and trace test statistics provide significant evidence for the existence of a cointegrating (long-run equilibrium) relationship between the wage ratio, trade with mainland China, the proportion of university graduates and the unemployment ADF First difference form (with c) (with t & c) (with c) (with t & c) LRWUP 1.354 3.349 6.918** 6.828** LTCSH 0.116 3.258 6.703** 6.690** LUNEMP 1.788 1.459 5.116** 5.865** LDEG 0.125 3.237 5.334** 5.442** a ADF = augmented Dickey Fuller statistic; LWRUP = relative wage rate of skilled and unskilled workers aged 40 49; LTCSH = the share of Hong Kong s with China to Hong Kong s total trade with the world; LUNEMP = unemployment rate; LDEG = proportion of university graduates in Hong Kong s labor force. The critical values are according to McKinnon s statistics. **statistically significant at the 1% level. *statistically significant at the 5% level. k QΓ = T log( 1 λi) i= r+ 1

PER_217.fm Page 138 Tuesday, April 13, 2004 5:43 PM 138 C. S. FAN AND K. Y. CHEUNG Table 5. Johansen test for cointegrating relationship between trade, education, unemployment rate and relative wages a Eigenvalue Likelihood ratio 5% critical value 1% critical value Hypothesized no. of CE(s) (a) LRWUP = f (LTCSH) 0.466 19.03 15.41 20.04 None* 0.007 0.198 3.76 6.65 At most 1 (b) LRWUP = f (LTCSH, LDEG) 0.622 37.19 29.68 35.65 None* 0.233 8.02 15.41 20.04 At most 1 0.002 0.04 3.76 6.65 At most 2 (c) LRWUP = f (LTCSH, LDEG, LUNEMP) 0.667 63.38 62.99 70.05 None* 0.475 30.36 42.44 48.45 At most 1 0.250 10.99 25.32 30.45 At most 2 0.075 2.35 12.25 16.26 At most 3 a LR test indicates 1 cointegrating equation(s) at 5% significance level in each case. *denotes rejection of the hypothesis at 5% significance level. rate. The likelihood ratio test rejects the hypothesis of no cointegration, but not the hypothesis of at most one cointegrating relation. The normalized cointegrating relation based on one cointegrating relation, r = 1, determined by the LR tests, can be written as LRWUP 1. 319* LTCSH + 2. 109* LDEG + 0. 175* LUNEMP 0. 024* t 0. 442 = 0 (. 0 658) (. 0 0765) (. 0 073) (. 0 012) where figures in parentheses are asymptotic standard errors and * denotes statistically significantly at 5% level. More comprehensive regression analyses are summarized in Table 6. From this table we first note that for all cases there has been a consistently statistically significant positive relationship between increases in the share of total trade with mainland China and the relative wage between skilled and unskilled workers in Hong Kong. Thus, our empirical finding is consistent with the hypothesis that the trade between developed and developing economies reduces the relative wage of unskilled labor in developed economies. Quantitatively, it is estimated that, for a 1% increase in the share of total trade with mainland China, the wage ratio between skilled and unskilled workers in Hong Kong increased by about 1.32% over the study period. Second, our regression analysis indicates that the wage gap between skilled and unskilled labor decreased with the proportion of skilled labor. This statistically significant negative relationship suggests that the effect of the law of diminishing returns is greater than the externality effect of human capital in Hong Kong during the study period 1985 92. Third, from Table 6 we can see that unemployment rate and relative wages between skilled and unskilled labor in Hong Kong has been negatively correlated. A possible explanation is as follows. In an economic downturn the increase in the unemployment rate for unskilled labor is significantly higher

PER_217.fm Page 139 Tuesday, April 13, 2004 5:43 PM TRADE AND WAGE INEQUALITY 139 Table 6. The cointegrating equation(s) of the relative wage: normalized cointegrating coefficients: 1 cointegrating equation for each case a LRWUP LTCSH LDEG LUNEMP Trend C (a) 1.00 0.592** 0.500 (0.094) Log likelihood = 102.7 (b) 1.00 2.270** 1.195* 4.080 (0.756) (0.518) Log likelihood = 161.9 (c) 1.00 1.319* 2.109* 0.175* 0.024* 0.442 (0.658) (0.765) (0.073) (0.012) Log likelihood = 192.5 a Figures in parentheses are asymptotic standard errors. **denotes statistically significantly at 1% level. *denotes statistically significantly at 5% level. than that for skilled labor (e.g. Rosen, 1968; Ashenfelter and Ham, 1979). In particular, the least productive unskilled workers often become unemployed in a recession. Thus, as the unemployment rate rises in a recession, the average wage of unskilled workers is less negatively affected than that of skilled workers, because the lowest paid unskilled workers may lose their jobs in the recession. Further, to complement our cointegration analysis, we employ Sim s method of decomposing the forecast error variance to provide an alternative approach to explaining the predicting power of trade, the share of university graduates and unemployment rate variables for wage gap. Ten lags of the relative wage are used for estimating the VAR system and ten quarters forecast error variances are explained. The empirical findings are summarized in Table 7, which describes the percentage of the variable movement explained by its own lags, the percentage of trade, the proportion of university graduates and the unemployment rate. From Table 7 we can see clearly that the trade between Hong Kong and China explains a much higher percentage of variances for relative wages the proportion of university graduates and unemployment rate does. 6. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS The recent sharp increase in the wage gap between skilled and unskilled labor in many developed countries has led to a lively debate on the importance of North South trade on wage inequality. This paper tries to complement the recent literature by examining the effects of Hong Kong mainland China trade on the wage inequality in Hong Kong. Our empirical study provides a good test of the theories on North South trade because of the large volume of trade and the large income disparity between Hong Kong and mainland China.

PER_217.fm Page 140 Tuesday, April 13, 2004 5:43 PM 140 C. S. FAN AND K. Y. CHEUNG Table 7. Variance decomposition of the relative wage equation explained by the trade share, skilled worker share and unemployment rate a Period S.E. Variance decomposition of LRWUP LRWUP LTCSH LDEG LUNEMP (a) 1 0.061 100.0 0.0 2 0.062 99.91 0.09 3 0.063 95.68 4.31 4 0.064 94.70 5.30 5 0.066 93.17 6.83 6 0.067 92.30 7.70 7 0.068 91.04 8.96 8 0.070 90.11 9.89 9 0.071 89.11 10.88 10 0.072 88.27 11.73 (b) 1 0.065 100.0 0.0 0.0 2 0.071 96.98 0.16 2.90 3 0.081 94.72 2.41 2.87 4 0.087 93.95 2.39 3.66 5 0.094 94.31 2.38 3.29 6 0.101 94.74 2.31 2.95 7 0.107 94.83 2.46 2.71 8 0.112 94.88 2.49 2.62 9 0.118 94.95 2.53 2.52 10 0.122 95.05 2.55 2.41 (c) 1 0.065 100.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 2 0.072 95.00 2.32 2.56 0.11 3 0.080 93.74 2.86 2.86 0.52 4 0.087 92.48 3.23 3.78 0.51 5 0.095 93.24 3.06 3.26 0.43 6 0.102 93.58 3.18 2.85 0.38 7 0.108 93.71 3.32 2.60 0.36 8 0.114 93.70 3.44 2.53 0.32 9 0.119 93.82 3.46 2.41 0.29 10 0.124 93.96 3.51 2.26 0.27 a Ten lags are used for estimating VAR system. The cointegration analysis in this paper shows that the relative wages between skilled and unskilled workers in Hong Kong increases as the share of the volume of Hong Kong s trade with mainland China in Hong Kong s total trade volume rises. Furthermore, the variance decomposition analysis indicates that Hong Kong s trade with mainland China is the most important determinant of its wage inequality. Thus, the findings are in support of the Stolper Samuelson theorem. Finally, the empirical analysis shows that the wage gap in Hong Kong decreases as the share of university graduates in the labor force increases. The increase in the number of university graduates has been due to the fact that the Hong Kong government has greatly increased its expenditure on tertiary

PER_217.fm Page 141 Tuesday, April 13, 2004 5:43 PM TRADE AND WAGE INEQUALITY 141 education; in addition, the opening up of mainland China has strengthened people s incentives to acquire skills in Hong Kong. Thus, we suggest that increasing educational expenditure not only can promote economic growth but also can partially offset the negative impact of globalization on the welfare of unskilled workers in developed countries. REFERENCES Acemoglu, D. (1996) A Microfoundation for Social Increasing Returns in Human Capital Accumulation, Quarterly Journal of Economics 111, 779 804. Ash, R. and Y. Y. Kueh (1993) Economic Integration within Greater China: Trade and Investment Flows between China, Hong Kong and Taiwan, China Quarterly 136, 711 45. Ashenfelter, O. and J. Ham (1979) Education, Unemployment and Earnings, Journal of Political Economy 87, S99 S116. Beyer, H., P. Rojas and R. Vergara (1999) Trade Liberalization and Wage Inequality, Journal of Development Economics 59, 103 23. Dickey, D. A. and W. A. Fuller (1979) Distribution of the Estimators for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root, Journal of American Statistical Association 74, 427 31. Gottschalk, P. and T. M. Smeeding (1997) Cross-National Comparisons of Earnings and Income Inequality, Journal of Economic Literature 35: 633 87. Johansen, S. (1991) Estimation and Hypothesis Testing of Cointegration Vectors in Gaussian Vector Autoregressive Models, Econometrica 59: 1551 80. Kambhampati, U., P. Krishna and D. Mitra (1997) The Effect of Trade Policy on Reforms on Labor Markets: Evidence from India, Journal of International Trade and Economic Development 6, 287 97. Krugman, P. R. (1995) Growing World Trade: Causes and Consequences, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 327 62. Lucas, R. E. (1988) On the Mechanics of Economic Development, Journal of Monetary Economics 22, 3 42. MacKinnon, J. G. (1990) Critical Values for Cointegration Tests, Working Paper, University of California, San Diego. Osterwald-Lenum, M. (1992) A Note with Quantiles of the Asymptotic Distribution of the Maximum Likelihood Cointegration Rank Test Statistics, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 54, 461 72. Reiner, K. A. and D. W. Roland-Holst (1998) North South Trade and Occupational Wages: Some Evidence from North America, Review of International Economics 6, 74 89. Richardson, J. D. (1995) Income Inequality and Trade: How to Think, What to Conclude, Journal of Economic Perspectives 9, 33 55. Robbins, D. and T. H. Gindling (1999) Trade Liberalization and the Relative Wages for More-Skilled Workers in Costa Rica, Review of Development Economics 3, 140 54. Rosen, S. (1968) Short-Run Employment Variation on Class-I Railroads in the US, 1947 63, Econometrica 36, 511 29. Sims, C. A. (1972) Money, Income, and Causality, American Economic Review 62, 540 52. Sims, C. A. (1980) Macroeconomics and Reality, Econometrica 48, 1 48. State Statistical Bureau (1991) Zhongguo Tongji Nianjian (China Statistical Yearbook) (in Chinese), various issues. Beijing: State Statistical Bureau. Suen, W. (1995) Impact of Sectoral Shifts on Hong Kong Workers, Journal of International Trade and Economic Development 4, 135 52. United Nations (UN) (various issues) Statistical Yearbook. New York: Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Statistics Division, UN. Wong, K.-Y. (1995) International Trade in Goods and Factor Mobility. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Wood, A. (1994) North South Trade, Employment and Inequality: Changing Fortunes in a Skill- Driven World. New York: Oxford University Press. Wood, A. (1995) How Trade Hurt Unskilled Workers, Journal of Economic Perspectives 9, 57 80. Wood, A. (1997) Openness and Wage Inequality in Developing Countries: The Latin American Challenge to East Asian Wisdom, World Bank Economic Review 11, 33 57.

PER_217.fm Page 142 Tuesday, April 13, 2004 5:43 PM 142 C. S. FAN AND K. Y. CHEUNG Wood, A. (1998) Globalization and the Rise in Labor Market Inequalities, Economic Journal 108, 1463 82. APPENDIX Table A1 describes the variables and lists their sources. Table A1. Key to variables Variables Description Data sources LRWUP Log of relative wage rate of skilled and unskilled workers aged 40 49 LTCSH Log of the share of Hong Kong s trade with China to Hong Kong s total trade with the world LUNEMP Log of unemployment rate (seasonally adjusted) LDEG Log of the proportion of university graduates in Hong Kong s labor force Unpublished statistics from Census and Statistics Department, General Household Survey Section, Hong Kong Hong Kong Annual Digest of Statistics, various issues, Census and Statistics Department, Hong Kong