Fairness as a constraint on trust in reciprocity: earned property rights in a reciprocal exchange experiment

Similar documents
Staff Rotation: A Powerful Weapon Against Corruption?

Are Dictators Averse to Inequality? *

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

DISCUSSION PAPERS Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

Ernst Fehr; Michael Näf und Klaus M. Schmidt: The Role of Equality and Equity in Social Preferences

Resource Allocations and Disapproval Voting in Unequal Groups

Goods, Games, and Institutions : A Reply

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES. No THE ROLE OF EQUALITY AND EFFICIENCY IN SOCIAL PREFERENCES. Ernst Fehr, Michael Naef and Klaus M.

Experimental and Behavioral Economics

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, SAN DIEGO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement

Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study. Jens Großer Ernesto Reuben Agnieszka Tymula

file:///j /STUDENT%20SERVICES/UGRAD%20PROGRAM/STUDENT% %20WI07%20Andreoni/Econ%20182%20WI07%20Andreoni.txt

How Mediator Compensation Affects the Conflicting Parties, and the Mediator s Behavior. An Economic and Experimental Analysis.

Trust and Social Capital in Immigrant Networks

A New Paradigm for the Study of Corruption in Different Cultures

Jan Theodor Schikora: Bringing good and bad Whistle-blowers to the Lab

Tacit Lobbying Agreements: An Experimental Study

Public Choice by Referenda or Delegation. An Experimental Comparison of Direct and Indirect Democracy

Norms of Distributive Justice in Rural Malawi

The Financial Crises of the 21st Century

The Governance Game. GOVERNANCE and THE LAW BACKGROUND PAPER. Sheheryar Banuri University of East Anglia

THREATS TO SUE AND COST DIVISIBILITY UNDER ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION. Alon Klement. Discussion Paper No /2000

Immigrant Assimilation, Trust and Social Capital

Long Tenure and Punishment Effect on Corrupt Behaviour

HOTELLING-DOWNS MODEL OF ELECTORAL COMPETITION AND THE OPTION TO QUIT

Trust and Trustworthiness of Immigrants and Native-Born Americans *

the social dilemma?» Emmanuel SOL, Sylvie THORON, Marc WILLINGER

Testing Leniency Programs Experimentally

Immigrant Assimilation, Trust and Social Capital

Residential segregation and socioeconomic outcomes When did ghettos go bad?

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems

The determinants of voting in multilateral bargaining games

REVIEW OF FOUNDATIONS OF HUMAN SOCIALITY: ECONOMIC EXPERIMENTS AND ETHNOGRAPHIC EVIDENCE FROM FIFTEEN SMALL-SCALE SOCIETIES

Incentives for separation and incentives for public good provision

ISSN , Volume 13, Number 2

Agendas and Strategic Voting

MORALITY - evolutionary foundations and policy implications

Selection in migration and return migration: Evidence from micro data

Subject pool effects in a corruption experiment: A comparison of Indonesian public servants and Indonesian students

EXAMINATION 3 VERSION B "Wage Structure, Mobility, and Discrimination" April 19, 2018

Cooperation and Self-interested behavior A Field Experiment in Ivorian plantain sector 1

political budget cycles

The Citizen Candidate Model: An Experimental Analysis

From Experimental Economics toward Integral Human Rationality

Coalition Governments and Political Rents

On Preferences for Fairness in Non-Cooperative Game Theory

Committee proposals and restrictive rules

Authority and Centrality

What you donõt know wonõt hurt me: Costly (but quiet) exit in dictator games

George Mason University

MERIT-Infonomics Research Memorandum series. Inequality Aversion, Efficiency, and Maximin Preferences in Simple Distribution Experiments

The Envious Punisher: Understanding Third and Second Party Punishment with Simple Games

Conditional Clauses in GHG Abatement Legislation

When users of congested roads may view tolls as unjust

Equality and Priority

Responsibility judgments in voting scenarios

F E M M Faculty of Economics and Management Magdeburg

Social Norms. Prepared for the New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics H. Peyton Young

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Does Willful Ignorance Deflect Punishment? An Experimental Study

Legal Change: Integrating Selective Litigation, Judicial Preferences, and Precedent

The Costs of Conflict

IMPERFECT INFORMATION (SIGNALING GAMES AND APPLICATIONS)

Intro Prefs & Voting Electoral comp. Voter Turnout Agency GIP SIP Rent seeking Partisans. 4. Voter Turnout

Bargaining in Legislatures: An Experimental Investigation of Open versus Closed Amendment Rules*

HARVARD NEGATIVE-EXPECTED-VALUE SUITS. Lucian A. Bebchuk and Alon Klement. Discussion Paper No /2009. Harvard Law School Cambridge, MA 02138

Veto Power in Committees: An Experimental Study* John H. Kagel Department of Economics Ohio State University

Cooperative membership as a signal of trust and trustworthiness in a low income economic environment: a randomized experiment in the Philippines

Veto Power in Committees: An Experimental Study* John H. Kagel Department of Economics Ohio State University

International Cooperation, Parties and. Ideology - Very preliminary and incomplete

Gender, Risk, and Corruption Insights from an Experimental Analysis 1

Legislative Bargaining and Partisan Delegation

Veto Power in Committees: An Experimental Study* John H. Kagel Department of Economics Ohio State University

University of Toronto Department of Economics. Party formation in single-issue politics [revised]

Do Liberals Play Nice? The Effects of Party and Political Ideology in Public Goods and Trust Games

Bribery and the Fair Salary Hypothesis in the Lab

Preferences for Redistribution and Pensions: What Can We Learn from Experiments?

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lecture 11: Economic Policy under Representative Democracy

Introduction to Political Economy Problem Set 3

Multilateral Bargaining: Veto Power PS132

Corruption and Cooperation

Viktor J. Vanberg. Corporate Social Responsibility and the Game of Catallaxy : The Perspective of Constitutional Economics

Social Polarization and Political Selection in Representative Democracies

Learning and Belief Based Trade 1

Subject Pool Effects in a Corruption Experiment: A Comparison of Indonesian Public Servants and Indonesian Students 1

Migration, Intermediate Inputs and Real Wages

International Environmental Agreements with Endogenous Minimum Participation and the Role of Inequality

The Transfer of the Remittance Fee from the Migrant to the Household

Center for the Study of Neuroeconomics GEORGE MASON UNIVERSITY, 4400 University Dr., MSN 1G3, Fairfax, Va.

Moral Obstinacy in Political Negotiations

What is Fairness? Allan Drazen Sandridge Lecture Virginia Association of Economists March 16, 2017

THE LIMITED POWER OF VOTING TO LIMIT POWER

Voting Power in Weighted Voting Games: A Lobbying Approach by Maria Montero, Alex Possajennikov and Martin Sefton 1 April 2011

Bilateral Bargaining with Externalities *

BOOK REVIEW BY DAVID RAMSEY, UNIVERSITY OF LIMERICK, IRELAND

DETERMINANTS OF IMMIGRANTS EARNINGS IN THE ITALIAN LABOUR MARKET: THE ROLE OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND COUNTRY OF ORIGIN

Gamson s Law versus Non-Cooperative. Bargaining Theory

Strong Reciprocity and the Welfare State. Christina M. Fong, Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis. July 3, 2004

What is the Nature and Social Norm within the Context of In-Group Favouritism?

Transcription:

Economics Letters 66 (2000) 275 282 www.elsevier.com/ locate/ econbase Fairness as a constraint on trust in reciprocity: earned property rights in a reciprocal exchange experiment Rene Fahr, Bernd Irlenbusch a b, * a Bonn Graduate School of Economics, Universitat Bonn, Adenauerallee 24 26, D-53113 Bonn, Germany Laboratorium f ur Experimentelle Wirtschaftsforschung, Universitat Bonn, Adenauerallee 24 26, D-53113 Bonn, Germany b Received 22 February 1999; accepted 23 September 1999 Abstract We igate the concept of mindreading in a trust reciprocity experiment. Our results show that the Trustees send back more, the stronger the Trustors property rights are. But instead of strategically relying on this reciprocal behavior, Trustors tend to unilaterally implement a fair outcome. 2000 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved. Keywords: Mindreading; Fairness; Trust; Reciprocity; Property rights; Real effort; Experiments JEL classification: C70; C78; C91; D63 1. Introduction 1 Several experimental studies show that in ultimatum games (Guth et al., 1982) the behavior of the 2 first mover changes when participants earn different property rights (Hoffman et al., 1994, 1996; Ruffle, 1998). If the Proposer holds property rights, she offers substantially lower amounts to the Responder compared to the situation with no property rights. On the other hand, if the Responder holds property rights, the proposal is much more generous than in a no property rights setting. The *Corresponding author. Tel.: 149-228-73-9196; fax: 149-228-73-9193. E-mail address: bi@uni-bonn.de (B. Irlenbusch) 1 In an ultimatum game the first mover, i.e., the Proposer, has to offer some proportion of a fixed amount of money. The second mover, i.e., the Responder, either accepts or rejects the offer. If the offer is accepted the money is allocated accordingly. If the Responder rejects nobody receives anything. 2 In accordance with the cited literature we use the term property rights in the sense of an entitlement obtained by performing a (working) task. 0165-1765/ 00/ $ see front matter 2000 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved. PII: S0165-1765(99)00236-0

276 R. Fahr, B. Irlenbusch / Economics Letters 66 (2000) 275 282 fact that the rejection rates remain virtually the same in all settings (see Hoffman et al., 1994) is 3 particularly interesting. Smith (1998) explains these observations with the concept of mindreading. According to this concept there is a mental process which enables human beings to infer the reactions of others from the consciousness of their own behavior: [Mindreading] enables me to see not only the value to me of possessing certain rights to act [i.e., property rights], but also to know intuitively the value of such rights for others (Smith, 1998, p. 8). By applying the concept of mindreading to the ultimatum game, Smith claims that the Proposer as a property rights holder offers less because, due to mindreading, she expects the Responder to reward her property rights. Similarly, if the Responder holds the property rights, offers are supposed to be high because the Proposer may fear that the offer will be rejected otherwise. We doubt whether Smith s concept of mindreading really characterizes the main driving force behind the observed behavior. Instead, we argue that, concerning property rights effects, unilateral fairness considerations (compare Kahneman et al., 1986) are much more important. As a test this paper igates whether in a slightly different game the trust reciprocity game the first mover really strategically acts according to the expected behavior of the second mover, as mindreading would predict. In our one-shot trust reciprocity game (see Fehr et al., 1993, 1997; Berg et al., 1995) the first mover (Trustor) is endowed with DM 10 to make an ment x while keeping the rest for herself (0 # x # 10). In a second stage the second mover (Trustee) receives a multiple (3x) of the ment and may return an amount y to the Trustor (0 # y # 3x). Trivially, the game is reduced to one stage if the Trustor passes nothing to the Trustee. In fact, x 5 0, y 5 0 ; x is the subgame perfect solution of the trust game, given the players are mere money-maximizers. In contrast to other reciprocity studies, we conducted three treatments along the property rights dimension, i.e., previous to the trust reciprocity game various participants earn property rights by performing a real effort working task. In 4 treatment WL only the Trustor holds a property right, whereas in treatment LW a property right is obtained by the Trustee, but not by the Trustor. In a control treatment WW none of the two players is entitled to more than the other one. In the following we speak of subjects as holding a stronger property right, if they worked more than the participant they are paired with. 2. Experimental design and procedure: entitlement in a trust game The experiment was conducted at the Laboratorium fur Experimentelle Wirtschaftsforschung at the Rheinische Friedrich-Wilhelms-Universitat Bonn. Participants were students of different disciplines, but most of them were law or economics students. Depending on the treatment, some participants (the workers) had to perform a real effort working 5 task, i.e., they were asked to crack walnuts. In order to succeed they had to come up with at least 3 This concept is taken from the literature on evolutionary psychology (see Baron-Cohen, 1995). 4 WL (LW) indicates that the Trustor Worked (had Leisure time) while the Trustee had Leisure (Worked) time. WW indicates that both participants Worked. 5 We wanted the working task to make the workers suffer to a certain extent in order to guarantee that they really felt entitled to the property rights. Furthermore, we chose to let subjects crack walnuts because the experiments were conducted some weeks before Christmas and, therefore, we could credibly assure that the work created a surplus. In fact, the walnut kernels were indeed sold in a supermarket as ingredients for cookies.

Table 1 Experimental design and procedure R. Fahr, B. Irlenbusch / Economics Letters 66 (2000) 275 282 277 Treatment WL Treatment LW Treatment WW Number of observed pairs 17 20 18 I. Working phase a Instructions for the working phase are read aloud to all the participants. Roles are randomly determined by drawing a card. Trustor Works Trustor has Leisure Trustor Works Trustee has Leisure Trustee Works Trustee Works II. Trust reciprocity game Instructions for the trust reciprocity game are read aloud to all the participants. Trustors are endowed with DM 10 in coins (contained in an envelope): If Trustor meets Unconditionally If Trustor meets working requirements working requirements Trustor decides to send x, 0#x#10. Trustee receives 3x: Unconditionally If Trustee meets If Trustee meets b working requirements b working requirements Trustee decides to return y, 0#y#3x (if x.0). III. Payment All participants are paid an additional DM 5 show-up fee. a The instruction sheets and the raw data can be obtained from the authors on request. b At the time when the Trustor made her ment decision she did not know whether the Trustee had succeeded in his working task. This would have created a situation of incomplete information for the Trustor in which she would have to estimate the success probability of the Trustee. Because we wanted the game to be one of perfect information, we set up the rule that a Trustor would get back her original ment if she was matched with a Trustee who did not accomplish his work. 150 g of walnut kernels in half an hour. The subjects who did not have to work were at leisure to do what they wanted. For example, they could leave the laboratory to drink coffee, read newspapers, study their lecture notes, play cards, or watch the workers. The design and procedure of the experiment is depicted in Table 1. The trust reciprocity game was conducted under anonymous conditions, i.e., participants did not know with whom they were matched. 3. Research hypotheses The main aim of this study is to analyze whether property rights alter the behavior in the trust reciprocity game and if so, whether we can predict this influence with the mindreading concept. Testing for the equity principle (Selten, 1978) in the trust reciprocity game was the second objective we had in mind when designing the present experiment. 3.1. Hypothesis implied by mindreading versus that emerging from fairness If the concept of mindreading is applicable, the Trustor implicitly has to form a hypothesis on the expected behavior of the Trustee. It is reasonable for the Trustor to assume that the Trustee tends to return more, the stronger the Trustor s property rights are. This hypothesis is in line with the

278 R. Fahr, B. Irlenbusch / Economics Letters 66 (2000) 275 282 6 experimental results in Hoffman et al. (1994), on the dictator game. They find that the Allocator gives less if he holds stronger property rights. If the Trustee in our game has received money, he faces a situation which is strategically equivalent to that of the Allocator in the dictator game. Thus, let us first consider the reactions of the Trustee. We use F return(? ) to denote the cumulative distribution 7 function of returns on an ment of DM 10 for each of the three treatments: H return: the stronger the property rights of the Trustors, the higher the returns (on ment of DM 10): F return(wl), F return(ww), F return(lw) According to the concept of mindreading the Trustor should anticipate the Trustee s behavior as outlined in H return. Thus, if the Trustor tries to strategically exploit the knowledge obtained from mindreading, it would be profitable for her to more, the more she is entitled. This would enable the Trustee to reciprocate, i.e., to send back more money. With F (?) denoting the cumulative distribution function of ments, we have the mindreading hypothesis: mind H : The stronger the property rights of the Trustors, the higher the ments: F (WL), F (WW), F (LW) Alternatively, Trustors could unilaterally implement an outcome that can be considered to be fair, i.e., the one who has higher property rights should earn more. The latter means that Trustors only place confidence in the Trustees with a high ment if this ment does not conflict with their own fairness considerations. In this case, higher ments should be observed if the Trustees are the ones who deserve the higher payoffs by holding stronger property rights. This gives us the hypothesis emerging from fairness considerations: fair H : the stronger the property rights of the Trustees, the higher the ments: F (LW), F (WW), F (WL) 3.2. Hypotheses implied by the equity principle One important fairness norm is the equity principle: an allocation is perceived as fair if the ratio of the outcome to the input is equal to the outcome/input ratio of others. This is formulated in a qualitatively similar way by Burrows and Loomes (1994, p. 203): differentials in payoffs are deserved, and are, therefore, fair if they correlate positively with the amount of effort involved in obtaining them. According to the equity principle, the difference in entitlement should make a difference in payoffs, namely Trustors deserve the highest (lowest) payoff in treatment WL (LW), in which they have a strong (weak) property right (vice versa for the Trustee). Because in treatment WW the property rights 6 In the dictator game one player (the Allocator) receives a sum of money from the experimenter which he can unilaterally distribute between another person (the Recipient) and himself. 7 We compare the returns of those pairs in which the Trustor ed DM 10 because, besides zero, DM 10 is by far the most frequently occurring ment. Moreover, only the ment of the full endowment is certainly perceived as a friendly action, which is a necessary condition for positive reciprocal behavior.

R. Fahr, B. Irlenbusch / Economics Letters 66 (2000) 275 282 279 of the two players are equal, we expect the payoffs of this treatment to lie in between. Let F P(?) (?) be the cumulative distribution function of payoffs for each of the three treatments. Thus, our hypotheses about the payoffs are: H P(Trustors) : the stronger the property rights of the Trustors, the higher their payoffs: F (WL), F (WW), F (LW) P(Trustors) P(Trustors) P(Trustors) H P(Trustees) : the stronger the property rights of the Trustees, the higher their payoffs: F (LW), F (WW), F (WL) P(Trustees) P(Trustees) P(Trustees) We will test all our hypotheses against the null hypothesis that the distributions are identical. 4. Results and conclusion By applying the nonparametric Jonckheere test for ordered alternatives, we find the following results. We can weakly significantly reject the null hypothesis that the distributions of payoffs are equal in all treatments in favor of H P(Trustors) (P50.0526, see Fig. 1). Analogously, we reject the null hypothesis in favor of H P(Trustees), which is highly significant (P50.0001, see Fig. 2). Thus, our results underline the robustness of property rights effects found in a number of experimental settings. Final payoffs of both the Trustors and the Trustees tend to increase if they hold stronger property rights. It is amazing that even in such an extreme asymmetric bargaining situation as the reciprocal exchange, the observed total payoffs qualitatively reflect the equity principle. Fig. 1. Cumulative distributions of Trustors payoffs.

280 R. Fahr, B. Irlenbusch / Economics Letters 66 (2000) 275 282 Fig. 2. Cumulative distributions of Trustees payoffs. We can significantly reject the null hypothesis that the distributions of the considered returns are the same, in favor of our hypothesis H return (P50.0179, see Fig. 3). This means that Trustees return significantly more, the stronger the property rights of the Trustors are. According to the concept of mindreading proposed by Smith (1998), bargainers are able to foresee the tendency of the reactions of others. If we apply this concept to our trust game, the Trustor would expect the observed behavior of Fig. 3. Cumulative distributions of returns.

R. Fahr, B. Irlenbusch / Economics Letters 66 (2000) 275 282 281 Fig. 4. Cumulative distributions of ments. the Trustee. Thus, a Trustor should more if she holds stronger property rights and thereby strategically exploit the expected reciprocal behavior of the Trustee. However, we do not observe such mind behavior and thus cannot significantly reject the null hypothesis in favor of the hypothesis H. fair Instead, the null hypothesis is rejected very clearly in favor of our hypothesis H (P50.0026, see Fig. 4). This is clear evidence against the implications of mindreading. Trustors unilaterally implement a fair outcome by ing more, the more the Trustee is entitled. Unilateral fairness considerations seem to be sufficiently strong to abandon strategic opportunities, which would arise from trust in the norm of reciprocity. Our result that the Trustor tends to less, the more the Trustee is expected to reciprocate rejects the applicability of the concept of mindreading in a trust reciprocity game and thereby raises severe doubts as to whether the concept really explains what is observed in the ultimatum game. Acknowledgements The authors thank the anonymous referee, Klaus Abbink, Simon Gachter, Werner Guth, Radosveta Ivanova-Stenzel, Manfred Konigstein, Bettina Kuon, Abdolkarim Sadrieh, Wendelin Schnedler and Reinhard Selten and the participants of the GEW-Workshop 1998 for helpful comments. Financial support by the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft through Sonderforschungsbereich 303 at the University of Bonn, the Ministerium fur Wissenschaft und Forschung des Landes Nordrhein- Westfalen, and the European Union through the EU-TMR Research Network ENDEAR (FMRX- CT98-0238) is gratefully acknowledged.

282 R. Fahr, B. Irlenbusch / Economics Letters 66 (2000) 275 282 References Baron-Cohen, S., 1995. In: Mindblindness. An Essay on Autism and Theory of Mind, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., McCabe, K., 1995. Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games and Economic Behavior 10, 121 142. Burrows, P., Loomes, G., 1994. The impact of fairness on bargaining behaviour. Empirical Economics 19, 201 221. Fehr, E., Kirchsteiger, G., Riedl, A., 1993. Does fairness prevent market clearing? An experimental igation. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (2), 437 460. Fehr, E., Gachter, S., Kirchsteiger, G., 1997. Reciprocity as a contract enforcement device: experimental evidence. Econometrica 65 (4), 833 860. Guth, W., Schmittberger, R., Schwarze, B., 1982. An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 3, 367 388. Hoffman, E., McCabe, K., Shachat, K., Smith, V.L., 1994. Preferences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining games. Games and Economic Behavior 7, 346 380. Hoffman, E., McCabe, K., Smith, V.L., 1996. On expectations and the monetary stakes in ultimatum games. International Journal of Game Theory 25, 289 301. Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J.L., Thaler, R., 1986. Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: entitlements in the market. The American Economic Review 76 (4), 728 741. Ruffle, B.J., 1998. More is better, but fair is fair: tipping in dictator and ultimatum games. Games and Economic Behavior 23, 247 265. Selten, R., 1978. The equity principle in economic behavior. In: Gottinger, H.W., Leinfellner, W. (Eds.), Decision Theory and Social Ethics, Issues in Social Choice, D. Reidel, Dordrecht, pp. 289 301. Smith, V.L., 1998. Distinguished guest lecture. The two faces of Adam Smith. Southern Economic Journal 65 (1), 1 19.