Is the Great Gatsby Curve Robust?

Similar documents
Voter Turnout, Income Inequality, and Redistribution. Henning Finseraas PhD student Norwegian Social Research

Political Skill and the Democratic Politics of Investment Protection

IV. Labour Market Institutions and Wage Inequality

ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality

Cross-Country Intergenerational Status Mobility: Is There a Great Gatsby Curve?

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

Why is there Cross-Country Variation in Female Labor Force Participation Rates? The Role of Male Attitudes Toward Family and Sex Roles

Great Gatsby Curve: Empirical Background. Steven N. Durlauf University of Wisconsin

Intergenerational Mobility and the Rise and Fall of Inequality: Lessons from Latin America

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Revisiting the Great Gatsby Curve

Volume 30, Issue 1. Corruption and financial sector performance: A cross-country analysis

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective

Commission on Growth and Development Cognitive Skills and Economic Development

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis Nanak Kakwani

Wage inequality, skill inequality, and employment: evidence and policy lessons from PIAAC

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications

Why are the Relative Wages of Immigrants Declining? A Distributional Approach* Brahim Boudarbat, Université de Montréal

Ethnic Intergenerational Transmission of Human Capital in Sweden

GLOBALIZATION AND THE GREAT U-TURN: INCOME INEQUALITY TRENDS IN 16 OECD COUNTRIES. Arthur S. Alderson

Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries

The effect of a generous welfare state on immigration in OECD countries

The globalization of inequality

U.S. Family Income Growth

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different?

The 'Great Gatsby' Curve In 3D: Inequality of Outcomes, Inequality of Opportunities and Social Mobility across Countries

Why is wage inequality so high in the United States? Pitching cognitive skills against institutions (once again)

IMPLICATIONS OF WAGE BARGAINING SYSTEMS ON REGIONAL DIFFERENTIATION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION LUMINITA VOCHITA, GEORGE CIOBANU, ANDREEA CIOBANU

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Honors General Exam Part 1: Microeconomics (33 points) Harvard University

Human Capital and Income Inequality: New Facts and Some Explanations

The Changing Relationship between Fertility and Economic Development: Evidence from 256 Sub-National European Regions Between 1996 to 2010

What Creates Jobs in Global Supply Chains?

Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation immigrants in Sweden

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

A Regional Look at Single Moms and Upward Mobility. Family-Friendly Policies Can Be Linked to Greater Economic Mobility Among Single Mothers

School Quality and Returns to Education of U.S. Immigrants. Bernt Bratsberg. and. Dek Terrell* RRH: BRATSBERG & TERRELL:

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005

Income and wealth inequalities

Settling In: Public Policy and the Labor Market Adjustment of New Immigrants to Australia. Deborah A. Cobb-Clark

Supporting Information for Representation and Redistribution in Comparative Perspective. Tiberiu Dragu and Jonathan Rodden

Determinants and Effects of Negative Advertising in Politics

ISSUE BRIEF: U.S. Immigration Priorities in a Global Context

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means

Recent Immigrants as Labor Market Arbitrageurs: Evidence from the Minimum Wage

Europe and the US: Preferences for Redistribution

the notion that poverty causes terrorism. Certainly, economic theory suggests that it would be

Inclusive global growth: a framework to think about the post-2015 agenda

Exposure to Immigrants and Voting on Immigration Policy: Evidence from Switzerland

Inequality, Life Chances, and Public Policy

The Transmission of Economic Status and Inequality: U.S. Mexico in Comparative Perspective

III. Wage Inequality and Labour Market Institutions

Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity

PURC CONFERENCE FEBRUARY

Violent Conflict and Inequality

On Trade Policy and Wages Inequality in Egypt: Evidence from Microeconomic Data

SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University

Family Return Migration

Evaluating Russian Economic Growth without the Revolution of 1917

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK

Revisiting the effects of skills on economic inequality: Within- and cross-country comparisons using PIAAC

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

Online Appendix for. Home Away From Home? Foreign Demand and London House Prices

Skills and Wage Inequality:

Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Globalization and Inequality : a brief review of facts and arguments

Statistical Analysis of Corruption Perception Index across countries

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Natural Resources & Income Inequality: The Role of Ethnic Divisions

Migrant Wages, Human Capital Accumulation and Return Migration

Commuting and Minimum wages in Decentralized Era Case Study from Java Island. Raden M Purnagunawan

Income and Democracy

Immigrant Employment and Earnings Growth in Canada and the U.S.: Evidence from Longitudinal data

Earnings Inequality, Educational Attainment and Rates of Returns to Education after Mexico`s Economic Reforms

SIMPLE LINEAR REGRESSION OF CPS DATA

NERO INTEGRATION OF REFUGEES (NORDIC COUNTRIES) Emily Farchy, ELS/IMD

Income inequality the overall (EU) perspective and the case of Swedish agriculture. Martin Nordin

Wage Rigidity and Spatial Misallocation: Evidence from Italy and Germany

Education, Health and Fertility of UK Immigrants:

Taiwan s Development Strategy for the Next Phase. Dr. San, Gee Vice Chairman Taiwan External Trade Development Council Taiwan

RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

Industrial & Labor Relations Review

Education, Health and Fertility of UK Immigrants: The Role of English Language Skills

Social capital and social cohesion in a perspective of social progress: the case of active citizenship

Immigration and the US Wage Distribution: A Literature Review

Labor Market Adjustment to Globalization: Long-Term Employment in the United States and Japan 1

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

World changes in inequality:

Who wants to be an entrepreneur?

Honors General Exam PART 3: ECONOMETRICS. Solutions. Harvard University April 2014

Trade Flows and Migration to New Zealand

Transcription:

Comment on Corak (2013) Bradley J. Setzler 1 Presented to Economics 350 Department of Economics University of Chicago setzler@uchicago.edu January 15, 2014 1 Thanks to James Heckman for many helpful comments.

Introduction Intergenerational Elasticity of Earnings: The coefficient β in the regression, ln Y c i,j = α j + β j ln Y p i,j + δ jx i,j + ɛ i,j, (1) where Y p is parents lifetime earnings, Y c is children s lifetime earnings, X is a vector of covariates often including a polynomial in parent s age (T ), j is the index over countries, and i is the index over individuals. See Black and Devereaux (2011) for a recent survey

Introduction The Great Gatsby Curve: the relationship between inequality and the intergenerational elasticity of earnings (IGE). Popularized in a speech by Alan Krueger (2012), it is defined by Corak (2013) as the regression, β j = γ 0 + γ 1 G j + η j, (2) where G is the disposable income Gini coefficient (a measure of inequality) and β is estimated from Equation (1). 2 2 No explicit reference to the error η is made in the literature, but this error structure is presupposed by the OLS estimation employed. Left implicit is the least strong assumption needed for unbiasedness and consistency of OLS, that G and η are uncorrelated. In an open economy, I expect this conditon to be violated as omitted variables (e.g., labor supply, the skill distribution, technology) are expected to causally affect both inequality and earnings, and to vary across countries. Nevertheless, I suspend disbelief in this comment.

Introduction Figure : The Great Gatsby Curve of Corak (2013) Intergen. Elasticity of Earnings (IGE) 0.1.2.3.4.5 Sweden Finland Norway Denmark Germany NZ Italy UK France Japan Canada Australia USA.2.25.3.35 Gini Coefficient, After Taxes and Transfers Corak's Chosen IGE OLS Slope=2.05, p-value=.001

Introduction Corak finds that, as a country becomes more unequal, earnings become more strongly preserved from parents to children. This result would raise serious questions about intergenerational distributive justice. But where did the data come from? Are the subjective aspects of data selection driving the inference that the Great Gatsby Curve has positive slope? I test the sensitivity of the inference to Corak s choices. A fragile inference is not worth taking seriously. -Ed Leamer (1985, AER)

Robustness Check 1: Gini Coefficients Corak fits the Great Gatsby Curve by regressing before tax-and-transfer earnings on after tax-and-transfer Gini coefficients. Recall Footnote 2: the model specification assumes that the IGE is linearly related to inequality, but it is difficult to imagine that, 1 taxes and transfers to do not affect earnings inequality (either in the same period or over time), 2 the relationship between taxes and transfers and earnings inequality is captured by subsuming taxes and transfers into the Gini coefficient only. I compute the Great Gatsby Curve when before tax-and-transfer Gini coefficients are used. The result is striking: the Great Gatsby Curve no longer has statistically significant slope.

Robustness Check 1: Gini Coefficients Figure : Corak s Great Gatsby Curve (Before Tax-and-Transfer Gini) Intergen. Elasticity of Earnings (IGE) 0.1.2.3.4.5 Japan Norway Italy Canada Finland Denmark NZ Sweden USA Germany UK France Australia.34.38.42.46 Gini Coefficient, Before Taxes and Transfers Corak's Chosen IGE OLS Slope=1.36, p-value=.093

Robustness Check 2: Corak s Weights Although Corak is collecting IGE estimates from other sources, he is not using them as reported. He uses the following process to modify the data prior to use: 1 Pick the most plausible IGE estimate for the USA from among 41 published estimates. 2 Match every non-usa country to a USA IGE estimate from the literature based upon similarity of the estimation method. 3 If the matched USA IGE estimate is different from the most plausible estimate by a factor of F, then the corresponding non-usa IGE is modified by a factor of F.

Robustness Check 2: Corak s Weights Suppose that we disagree with Corak s (at least partly) subjective choice of the most plausible IGE estimate for the USA? Corak took his most plausible estimate from Grawe (2004). Grawe (2004) reported two values as equally plausible: Corak s chosen 0.47 as well as 0.15. I compute the Great Gatsby Curve using Grawe s lower estimate. However, I find that the Great Gatsby Curve is unaffected if we discard Corak s weights.

Robustness Check 2: Corak s Weights Figure : Corak s Great Gatsby Curve with Lower USA IGE Estimate Intergen. Elasticity of Earnings (IGE) 0.1.2.3.4.5 Sweden Finland Norway Denmark Germany NZ Italy UK France Japan Canada Australia USA.2.25.3.35 Gini Coefficient, After Taxes and Transfers Corak's Chosen IGE except USA OLS Slope=0.65, p-value=.001

Robustness Check 3: Corak s Chosen Data We have seen how Corak s Great Gatsby Curve is affected if we maintain his weighting scheme but select an alternate USA IGE estimate: the slope shifts proportional to the change in USA IGE. We have also noted that we can discard his weighting scheme without qualitatively changing his results. But how will the results change if we choose from among the many other IGE estimates available in the literature for the various countries? To motivate the question, I replace Corak s IGE choices for three of the 13 countries (Norway, UK, and USA). Two of my estimates are taken from papers from which Corak takes some of his chosen estimates. I find that the Great Gatsby Curve now has a negative slope.

Robustness Check 3: Corak s Chosen Data Figure : Great Gatsby Curve using Three Alternate Elasticities (Gini Before) Intergen. Elasticity of Earnings (IGE) 0.1.2.3.4.5 Italy Japan Norway Sweden Canada Finland Denmark NZ USA Germany France Australia UK.34.38.42.46 Gini Coefficient, Before Taxes and Transfers Alternate IGE Choice OLS: Slope=-0.14, p-value=.859

Robustness Check 3: Corak s Chosen Data More generally, consider the following sensitivity analysis: using a survey of every IGE estimate available on each country, estimate the Great Gatsby Curve for every combination. There are 246,000 combinations, so I obtain a distribution of 246,000 slope coefficient estimates and 246,000 corresponding p-values. Using before tax-and-transfer Gini coefficients, 97.6% have positive estimated slope coefficient but only 0.003% of these slope estimates are statistically significant. The mean coefficient is 0.916 and the standard deviation is 0.467, so zero is just within two standard deviations of the mean. Using after tax-and-transfer Gini coefficients, none has negative estimated slope coefficient and 83% of these slope estimates are statistically significant. The mean coefficient is 1.846 and the standard deviation is 0.509.

Robustness Check 3: Corak s Chosen Data My sensitivity analysis reveals that Corak has chosen IGE s that correspond to a Great Gatsby Curve slope estimate that is in the largest 15% using before tax-and-transfer Gini coefficients and in the largest 10% using after tax-and-transfer Gini coefficients.

Robustness Check 3: Corak s Chosen Data Figure : Distribution of Great Gatsby Curve Slopes for All IGE Combinations Density (100 Bins) 0.2.4.6.8 -.5 0.5 1 1.5 2 Slope of Great Gatsby Curve (Before Tax-and-Transfer Gini)

Robustness Check 3: Corak s Chosen Data Figure : Distribution of Great Gatsby Curve p-values for All IGE Combinations Density (100 Bins) 0 1 2 3 4 5 0.2.4.6.8 1 p-values of Great Gatsby Curve (Before Tax-and-Transfer Gini)

Robustness Check 3: Corak s Chosen Data Figure : Distribution of Great Gatsby Curve Slopes for All IGE Combinations Density (100 Bins) 0.2.4.6.8 0 1 2 3 4 Slope of Great Gatsby Curve (After Tax-and-Transfer Gini)

Robustness Check 3: Corak s Chosen Data Figure : Distribution of Great Gatsby Curve p-values for All IGE Combinations Density (100 Bins) 0 20 40 60 80 0.2.4.6.8 1 p-values of Great Gatsby Curve (After Tax-and-Transfer Gini)

Conclusions I have demonstrated that the leading estimate of the Great Gatsby Curve, the least-squares regression of Corak (2013), fails three tests of robustness: 1 It is not robust to the choice of Gini coefficient (before tax-and-transfer versus after tax-and-transfer.) 2 It is not robust in level of slope to the choice of USA IGE. 3 Even the sign of the slope is not robust to the choice of alternate IGE choices across countries when using before tax-and-transfer Gini coefficients. I propose disentangling the effects of earnings inequality, taxes, and transfers on the IGE. 3 3 I continue to suspend disbelief regarding omitted variables and linear functional form, as described in Footnote 2.

Conclusions Using estimates by the OECD (2011) of average tax rate (T ) payed by the top 20% of the earnings distribution and average benefit as a fraction of income (B) transferred to the bottom 20% of the earnings distribution, I fit all possible combinations of IGE estimates to the modified Great Gatsby Curve, 4 β j = γ 0 + γ 1 G B j + γ 2 T j + γ 3 B j + η j, (3) where G B is the before tax-and-transfer Gini coefficient. 4 Even more so than the Gini coefficients from the OECD (2011,2013), the tax and transfer estimates correspond to more recent years than the IGE estimates, so the validity of the estimates depends on similarity over time in the Gini coefficients and tax and transfer rates.

Conclusions I find that the mean coefficient is 1.428 and 37.7% are statistically significant. Furthermore, I find that the mean coefficients on taxes and transfers are -0.833 and -0.204 and 70.5% and 95.7% are statistically significant, respectively. Thus, I conclude that inequality has a positive and somewhat statistically significant effect on IGE, while taxes and transfers have negative and mostly statistically significant effects on IGE. I have no reason to believe that this result is robust to alternate model or statistical assumptions. Take this only as motivation for a more general analysis of the relationship between inequality and intergenerational mobility across countries. See my paper for more details and citations.