The Elgar Companion to Marxist Economics

Similar documents
George C. Comninel a a Department of Political Science, York. To link to this article:

All societies, large and small, develop some form of government.

Economic Change and The Bi-Polar World Economy

World History I: Civics and Economics Essential Knowledge

Theory as History. Essays on Modes of Production and Exploitation BRILL. Jairus Banaji LEIDEN BOSTON 2010 ''685'

Chapter 12. Services

Note on the historical background for European industrialization. Social organization. Trade in Feudal era. Social norms 9/20/2017

INTRODUCTION. Notes for this section begin on page 8.

History Revolutions: Russian Teach Yourself Series Topic 3: Factors that contributed to the revolution

(Institute of Contemporary History, China Academy of Social Sciences) MISUNDERSTANDINGS OF FEUDALISM, AS SEEN FROM THE DIFFERENCE BETWEEN THE CHINESE

Village Communities and Global Development

History (HI) Modules. History 1000 & 2000 Level 2013/14 August HI2001 History as a Discipline: Development and Key Concepts

Chapter 2. The Evolution of Economic Systems. Copyright 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

From: Handbook of Historical Sociology edited by Gerard Delanty and Engin Isin Sage: London, (Please cite from published version.

Summary The Beginnings of Industrialization KEY IDEA The Industrial Revolution started in Great Britain and soon spread elsewhere.

Feminist Critique of Joseph Stiglitz s Approach to the Problems of Global Capitalism

ECON Modern European Economic History John Lovett Code Name: Part 1: (70.5 points. Answer on this paper. 2.5 pts each unless noted.

Classical Civilizations of the Mediterranean & Middle East. Persia, Greece & Rome

History Revolutions: Russia Teach Yourself Series Topic 3: Trigger factors that contributed to the revolution

1. How did Robespierre government ensure equality in the French Society? Explain any five measures.

Preface... ix Acknowledgements... xi Introduction: The Method of Ellen Meiksins Wood... 1

INDEPENDENT SCHOOL DISTRICT 196 Rosemount-Apple Valley-Eagan Public Schools Educating our students to reach their full potential

2008 World History I History and Social Science Standards of Learning STANDARD

World History I (Master) Content Skills Learning Targets Assessment Resources & Technology CEQ: features of early. civilizations.

(3) parliamentary democracy (2) ethnic rivalries

COMPANY TOWNS: THE PATRONAGE SYSTEM FROM MEDIEVAL EUROPE TO THE AMERICAN SOUTH AND BEYOND

Base your answers to questions 1 and 2 on the art work below and on your knowledge of social studies.

INTERNATIONAL SOCIALISM

Grade Level: 9-12 Course#: 1548 Length: Full Year Credits: 2 Diploma: Core 40, Academic Honors, Technical Honors Prerequisite: None

Chapter 20: Historical Material on Merchant s Capital

Comparative Law II. The Common / Civil Law Divide. Unit 2: History of Common Law and Civil Law

Description and History of Common Law

European History

Developing the Periphery & Theorising the Specificity of Peripheral Development

History (HIST) History (HIST) 1

Study Questions for George Reisman's Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics

A nineteenth-century approach: Max Weber.

Chapter 2: The Modern State Test Bank

Rise Great Leader Achievements Fall

Part 1: Roman Empire Part 2: Medieval Europe. Lesson 18

The Western Heritage Since 1300 Kagan, Revised, 11 th Edition AP Edition, 2016

The Beginnings of Industrialization

Directives Period Topics Topic breakdowns

The Low Countries in the Transition to Capitalism

The Early Industrial Revolution Chapter 22 AP World History

FOUNDATIONS OF LAW SUMMARY

IV. Social Stratification and Class Structure

1. Base your answer to question on the chart below and on your knowledge of social studies.

DBH 4 Social Science Contemporary history Unit 1: Political Revolutions: French Revolution. Name & last name:

The Class Structure of Pakistan. Taimur Rahman

3. Which region had not yet industrialized in any significant way by the end of the nineteenth century? a. b) Japan Incorrect. The answer is c. By c.

Public sphere and dynamics of the Internet

Part IV Population, Labour and Urbanisation

World History and Civilizations

TRADE AND THE DECLINE OF FEUDALISM

World History (Survey) Chapter 22: Enlightenment and Revolution,

early twentieth century Peru, but also for revolutionaries desiring to flexibly apply Marxism to

GCE History A. Mark Scheme for June Unit : Y303/01 English Government and the Church Advanced GCE

SOCIAL STUDIES GRADE 7. I Can Checklist Office of Teaching and Learning Curriculum Division

Standards Social Studies Grades 4-12 History Center

CH 17: The European Moment in World History, Revolutions in Industry,

C) an increase in population B) Code of Hammurabi B) codified the laws of their empire B) producing only enough crops to meet family

JROTC LET st Semester Exam Study Guide

Standards Social Studies Grades K-12 Mille Lacs Indian Museum

INTRODUCTION TO NZ LEGAL SYSTEMS SUMMARY 2011

MRS. OSBORN S APWH CRAM PACKET:

HIST252 Guide to Responding to Units 3 & 4 Reading Questions

SOCIAL STUDIES 8 COURSE OUTLINE WORLD CIVILIZATIONS

12. Which foreign religious tradition was absorbed into China during the classical period? A) Hinduism B) The Isis cult C) Buddhism D) Christianity

Chapter 9 1/14/2019. Alabama Standard. Ch.9 Section 1 (page #283)

UNIT 6 FEUDAL SOCIETIES

Balance of Power. Balance of Power, theory and policy of international relations that asserts that the most effective

Vladimir Lenin, Extracts ( )

World Civilizations. The Global Experience. Chapter. The Rise of Russia. AP Seventh Edition

Groveport Madison Local School District Seventh Grade Social Studies Content Standards Planning Sheets

WEEK 1 - Lecture Introduction

Brunswick High School Social Studies World History I - Grade 9 UNIT 6: The Golden Age of Empires

Overview The Dualistic System Urbanization Rural-Urban Migration Consequences of Urban-Rural Divide Conclusions

In Refutation of Instant Socialist Revolution in India

THEMATIC ESSENTIAL QUESTIONS BY UNIT

The French Revolution

GRADE 7 SOCIAL STUDIES SOCIAL STUDIES APPLICATION. SOCIAL STUDIES STANDARDS for Grade 7

The Growth of the Territorial State of France

Independent Schools Examinations Board COMMON ENTRANCE EXAMINATION AT 13+ COMMON ACADEMIC SCHOLARSHIP EXAMINATION AT 13+ HISTORY SYLLABUS

Aconsideration of the sources of law in a legal

PREFACE. This book aims to help students prepare for the O Level Combined Humanities History Elective Examination.

POL 343 Democratic Theory and Globalization February 11, "The history of democratic theory II" Introduction

SENIOR 4: WESTERN CIVILIZATION HISTORICAL REVIEW OF ITS DEVELOPMENT (OPTIONAL)

Possible Essay Topics for ECON 306 Final, Spring Semester 2016

Chapter 10: America s Economic Revolution

Test Blueprint. Course Name: World History Florida DOE Number: Grade Level: 9-12 Content Area: Social Studies. Moderate Complexity.

History (

B.A. IN HISTORY. B.A. in History 1. Topics in European History Electives from history courses 7-11

ECONOMICS WITHOUT TIME

5 Historical materialism in Forms which Precede Capitalist

World Encyclopedia of Entrepreneurship

GRADE 9 WORLD HISTORY

Capitalism, Laws of Motion and Social Relations of Production

The Comparative Advantage of Nations: Shifting Trends and Policy Implications

Chapter 16: Attempts at Liberty

Transcription:

The Elgar Companion to Marxist Economics Edited by Ben Fine Professor of Economics, SOAS, University of London, UK Alfredo Saad-Filho Professor of Political Economy, SOAS, University of London, UK Marco Boffo University of London, UK Edward Elgar Cheltenham, UK Northampton, MA, USA M2834 FINE TEXT.indd iii 10/11/2011 09:59

Ben Fine and Alfredo Saad Filho 2012 All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical or photocopying, recording, or otherwise without the prior permission of the publisher. Published by Edward Elgar Publishing Limited The Lypiatts 15 Lansdown Road Cheltenham Glos GL50 2JA UK Edward Elgar Publishing, Inc. William Pratt House 9 Dewey Court Northampton Massachusetts 01060 USA A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library Library of Congress Control Number: 2011932881 ISBN 978 1 84844 537 6 (cased) Typeset by Servis Filmsetting Ltd, Stockport, Cheshire Printed and bound by MPG Books Group, UK M2834 FINE TEXT.indd iv 10/11/2011 09:59

21. Feudalism George C. Comninel The idea of feudalism is enormously contested among historians and theorists of all stripes. With some notable exceptions, non- Marxist British historians have generally conceived feudalism as a formal hierarchy of lords and fiefs a technical conception identified with F.L. Ganshof (Comninel, 2000a). Recently, whether feudalism in those terms ever even existed has been challenged (Reynolds, 1996). Marxists and other socially oriented medievalists like Georges Duby (1968) have instead followed Marc Bloch in focusing on feudal society, comprising peasants as well as lords (Comninel, 2000a). While often posed as alternatives, these views are compatible (to whatever extent a formal feudal hierarchy actually existed). Marxists concerned with feudalism as a system of class relations cannot, in any case, dismiss relations among lords as irrelevant. Marxists, however, generally differ from non- Marxists in conceiving feudalism as one of a sequence of modes of production or forms of class society. Usually grounded in a brief account of such modes by Marx, Marxist approaches must confront three basic sets of questions: (1) how, when and why was there a transition from ancient society usually understood in terms of a slave mode of production to feudal society; (2) how should the class relations of feudalism be conceived; and (3) how, when and why was there a subsequent transition from feudalism to capitalism. A further issue has been how, if at all, historical developments elsewhere relate to European feudalism. Focusing on any domination of peasants by landowners, some accounts have multiplied feudal and semi- feudal societies across the globe. The debates over feudalism, therefore, remain too numerous and complex to detail in any short survey. Certain lines of enquiry, however, have been influential. One crucial contribution was the Transition Debate launched by Paul Sweezy and Maurice Dobb (1978). In retrospect, this mostly exposed the weakness of Marxist accounts of feudalism and the transition to capitalism down through the 1960s. Presuppositions about modes of production and historical processes bedevilled the debate, revealing how little agreement there was over Marx s ideas and methods, and how to apply them. The core disagreement was over Sweezy s contention that feudalism was fundamentally defined by the absence of market relations, lordly income taking the form of compulsory labour by serfs, challenging Dobb s broader conception of feudalism as the appropriation of peasant surpluses through rent, whether in labour, kind or money. Ultimately, neither conception is adequate. Despite its limitations, the debate importantly focused attention on the discussion of feudal rent in Capital III, chapter 47. Marx argued that, because peasants in the first instance produce to meet immediate household needs, surplus- labour for the nominal 131 M2834 FINE TEXT.indd 131 10/11/2011 09:59

132 The Elgar companion to Marxist economics owner of the land can only be extorted from them by other than economic pressure, whatever the form assumed may be. Indeed: all forms in which the direct labourer remains the possessor of the means of production and labour conditions necessary for the production of his own means of subsistence, the property relationship must simultaneously appear as a direct relation of lordship and servitude, so that the direct producer is not free; a lack of freedom which may be reduced from serfdom with enforced labour to a mere tributary relationship. In this context Marx uttered a striking statement of historical materialist method: The specific economic form, in which unpaid surplus- labour is pumped out of direct producers, determines the relationship of rulers and ruled, as it grows directly out of production itself and, in turn, reacts upon it as a determining element. Upon this, however, is founded the entire formation of the economic community which grows up out of the production relations themselves, thereby simultaneously its specific political form. It is always the direct relationship of the owners of the conditions of production to the direct producers... which reveals the innermost secret, the hidden basis of the entire social structure and with it the political form of the relation of sovereignty and dependence, in short, the corresponding specific form of the state. Applying equally to capitalist and pre- capitalist societies, this statement dramatically underlines a crucial distinction between them. In the capitalist mode of production, surplus is appropriated through seemingly purely economic relations, formally distinct from relations of political power; in pre- capitalist modes of production no comparable separation of the political from the economic can exist. Instead, pre- capitalist surplus appropriation depends on extra- economic coercive force (whether manifest or implicit). This recognition of the fundamentally extra- economic character of pre- capitalist class relations marked a significant theoretical advance. When the Transition Debate began, Marx s Grundrisse was almost unknown. A small part concerning pre- capitalist economic formations was subsequently published in which Eric Hobsbawm confronted problems with mode of production analyses (1965); the whole appeared in 1973. This previously obscure work had considerable impact upon those attending to the Transition Debate. Perry Anderson, particularly, drew together elements from these sources in a highly original and influential account of the arc of Western European history from antiquity to capitalism (1974a, 1974b). Anderson s work transformed the way feudalism was conceived by Marxists and non- Marxists alike by identifying parcellized sovereignty as its specific form of pre- capitalist extra- economic coercion. He also rejected outright the idea that the feudal mode of production existed outside Europe, making the novel (often overlooked) argument that non- European societies must be investigated without preconceptions, looking for historically specific class relations and modes of production, rather than attempting to fit them into a European model. It is ironic, therefore, that his own analysis of European history is undercut precisely by its limitation to the usual few modes of production. Anderson begins with an ancient world characterized by a slave mode of production. He argues this was self- limiting in its dependence on an external supply of slaves, causing a transition to feudalism during the later Roman Empire. Feudalism then characterized the entire Middle Ages, remaining dominant well into the modern era. The capitalist mode of production, however, developed in medieval urban interstices where Roman M2834 FINE TEXT.indd 132 10/11/2011 09:59

Feudalism 133 legacies persisted, igniting economic take- off and eventually producing bourgeois revolutions that established contemporary societies. This account has been challenged on several key points, from the existence of a slave mode of production to the idea of bourgeois revolution (Comninel, 1987; Wood, 1988). When taken as a whole, however, it also reveals how difficult it is to make sense of Western European history with just these three modes of production. On the one hand, it is hard to comprehend the complex histories of ancient societies from the early Athenian polis and early Roman republic, through the rise of Hellenistic monarchies and growth of Roman imperial power, the heyday of the Pax Romana, and ultimately the later Empire s huge latifundia and stifling bureaucratism based on the single idea of a slave mode of production. On the other hand, Anderson takes feudal society to have developed from the third through to the ninth centuries; then undergoing profound crisis and population collapse from the mid- fourteenth through fifteenth centuries; only to survive in revised and transitional form as the Absolutist State through the eighteenth century. Little of the ancient world seems to fit the slave mode of production attributed to it, and of 1500 years of the feudal mode of production, 1100 are spent in transition or crisis! Setting aside the overall account, it is striking that, although Anderson does more than simply acknowledge extra- economic coercion in conceiving feudalism, identifying its specific form to be parcellized sovereignty, he offers little more of substance in building on this. Instead, the largely unexamined possession of coercive power by holders of estates seems to develop into parcellized sovereignty merely through a long- term decline of central state power. The essential elements of transition from slave to feudal modes of production, then, are a replacement of household and barracks slaves by dependent peasant tenants (of various statuses), accompanied by an accelerating recession of public authority in Rome and its successor kingdoms. It is in these terms that the transition is conceived to unfold between the third and ninth centuries. While this analysis asserts continuity at the level of the estate (indeed, it becomes hard to distinguish between Roman latifundium and medieval manor), it poorly accords with the substantial political and legal continuity at the level of the state that is now generally recognized in the early Middle Ages. In large part, this is because there is no place in Anderson s account for the survival of large numbers of free persons not living as dependent tenants on lordly estates, for which the evidence is incontrovertible into the tenth century. Among historians who continue to think in terms of feudal society, there is, indeed, widespread recognition that it came into existence very rapidly between the later decades of the tenth century and the early eleventh century centring on the year 1000 through a transformation, or even revolution, based precisely on a parcellization of sovereign royal power, in the first instance among regional magnates, from whom it increasingly devolved, eventually reaching the level of individual seigneuries (Comninel, 2000a). THE FEUDAL TRANSFORMATION AND FEUDAL MODE OF PRODUCTION This sudden transformation of much of Western Europe, through the fragmentation of previously royal power in the empire established by Charlemagne, had enormous M2834 FINE TEXT.indd 133 10/11/2011 09:59

134 The Elgar companion to Marxist economics consequences, marking a rupture far more profound than the fall of Rome. To begin with, regional magnates erected fortifications and, as castellans, arrogated the fundamental royal powers of the ban: taxation, command and the provision of justice in courts. Public courts that had continued to serve free men into the mid- tenth century thus became appurtenances of the estates of lords, whose primary relationship with peasants now took the form of territorial jurisdiction. As a result, villages of free peasants, previously independent of lords and manors, were suddenly subject to the arbitrary authority of a lord through judgements in his courts, obligations to build and maintain fortifications and roads and, especially, unrestrained taxation. Almost immediately, the sovereign powers of jurisdiction became by far the most lucrative element of lordly property. Lordship was itself transformed, from an informal status of men with many dependents on their estates the magnates into a formal Order in society. In this new social conception, the lordly second Order was vested with secular rule, although the Order of the Church had formal precedence. Within the labouring third Order, any distinction between free and unfree disappeared entirely, outside the cities. Virtually all rural producers became subject to immediate lordly rule, and were made to pay dearly for it. Most taxes, dues and fines took the form of money payments, and a rapid re- monetarization followed. Indeed, minting became a lucrative right of sovereignty enjoyed by lords possessing sufficient jurisdiction. During the heyday of feudal society, the population of Western Europe roughly tripled, mostly between 1100 and 1250. Forests were cleared, wetlands drained, and wastes generally reduced and transformed through varieties of production. Trade revived, generating dramatic urban growth in northern Italy, where cities acquired republican self- government in conjunction with a take- off both in manufacture of luxury goods (for example, 1 Florentine woollens) and imports from the East, satisfying growing demand from newly rich feudal lords in northwest Europe. Towns also grew in the feudal heartland, and great gothic cathedrals were built. Western European lords increasingly organized the conquest and colonization of Eastern Europe. Culture was transformed by chivalry, and a new pre- eminence of the Church at the apex of society. And, of course, the Crusades were launched. In short, feudal society quickly and fundamentally transformed Europe, in ways that most Marxist historians and theorists have completely overlooked because of preconceived ideas about the nature, number and timing of precapitalist modes of production, and the transitions between them. Still, Marx s assertion that the specific form of surplus appropriation is the key to both the political and economic organization of society is readily revealed to be sound for parcellized sovereignty in the feudal mode of production. Not only was parcellized sovereignty the immediate means for extra- economic appropriation of surplus, and foundation for the relations between lords and peasant producers, but it figured centrally in the organization of feudal production. Pre- capitalist agrarian production has in most times and places depended on self- reproducing peasant households (agrarian production by barracks slaves was common only in parts of Rome s West, between the second century BCE and the third century CE, and never dominant even then). Outside of areas of irrigation and water- course management, formal intrusion into largely autarkic household production was limited, and even then individual households remained largely self- managing beyond the particulars of water supply. The feudal mode of production, however, was dramatically different, its open- field M2834 FINE TEXT.indd 134 10/11/2011 09:59

Feudalism 135 systems of collective crop and livestock management directly dependent upon the court of the lord. Rotation of crops was known prior to the feudal transformation, and sometimes practised on the lord s fields in manors. Only after the establishment of parcellized sovereignty, however, were lordly manors integrated with the fields of peasant villages and all fields subdivided into narrow strips, each possessed by separate individuals (including the lord), widely scattered but equally divided among two, three or rarely four fields of systematic crop rotation (Verhulst, 2002). The court of the lord was essential in regulating this system as is evident in the continued role of the court leet in the village of Laxton, Nottinghamshire, the only place where open- field farming is still practised. The more productive the soil, and the greater its maximum potential population, the more important was the court s role in coordination and regulation. In subdivided fields, livestock must be kept away from crops, and crops grown in sequence for collective harvests, and use of stubble for herds pastured in common. With open- field agriculture, virtually every aspect of production is directly subject to legal regulation more intrusive, even, than practices of irrigation. Such collectively regulated, labour- intensive production tends to maximize the population supported by pre- capitalist peasant production, varying in form, details and degree of intensity with geography and quality of the land. This generalized non- capitalist intensification of production not grounded in innovation, but in upholding custom as law through effective local jurisdiction was responsible for the demographic upsurge of feudal Europe. For lords, demographic growth translated into more residents subject to fines, dues and per capita taxes, with increases over time not only in the extent of land in production, but in output per hectare. For peasants, it increased resources both in households and in the village as a whole, expanded total production and potentially also the standard of living (if greater lordly impositions could be resisted). The implications of such patterns have been extensively analysed by demographically inclined historians (Aston and Philpin, 1985). What they have failed to recognize, however, is that such patterns are not general to pre- capitalist societies, even within Western Europe, but follow directly from the transformation of early medieval manors and independent villages into feudal seigneuries, ruled through parcellized sovereignty in wholly novel ways, and with unprecedented consequences. While it is true that the crisis of feudal society in the mid- fourteenth century was caused by over- population of the land relative to its productive capacity, this was no natural phenomenon, but the consequence of a specific system of class relationships operating over time. The historical details of feudal societies are sufficiently wellestablished for this brief overview to provide an adequate means of entry and analysis. Once the specific social form that emerged from the parcellization of sovereignty around the year 1000 is clearly distinguished from the sort of manorial society that preceded it, much of the errors and confusion in prior accounts can be sorted out. What remains especially to be noted, however, is that this feudal transformation grew out of, and was centred upon, the monarchy constructed and repeatedly extended by the Franks. The heartland of feudalism was the most completely developed areas of Frankish rule, primarily northern France and western Germany, from which it spread. The subsequent imposition of feudalism in Eastern Europe, southern Italy and the Crusader states is notable, but by far the most significant extension of the feudal mode of production was through the Norman Conquest of England. M2834 FINE TEXT.indd 135 10/11/2011 09:59

136 The Elgar companion to Marxist economics ENGLISH FEUDALISM AND THE TRANSITION TO CAPITALISM Prior to the Norman Conquest, Anglo- Saxon England had developed a strong central state, in striking contrast to contemporary Continental developments. As Duby observed, feudal society in England was, therefore, unique: Inside the manor, authority over men and over land, domestic lordship and land lordship, coincided. On the other hand the autonomous seigneurie banale, the independent territorial lordship, did not, properly speaking, exist at all. William the Conqueror held all the castles. (1968, p. 194) Through the Conquest, William made good a real claim to the throne, not only acquiring, but strengthening its central power. His retention of a system of effective royal courts had the most profound historical consequences. William carved out some 10 000 manors in England, conveying most to his followers. Through this largely new social framework, virtually the whole of feudal social relations of production, and virtually the whole range of feudal exactions, were introduced into England. Open- field agriculture, with its subdivided fields and manorial courts, was imposed, along with its usual geographic variations. The manorial courts exercised nearly complete jurisdiction over roughly three- quarters of the peasantry, whom royal jurists determined to be unfree based on the burden of their obligations. The courts also possessed jurisdiction over production in the open- fields, regulating free and unfree alike. In France, all peasants equally were subject to arbitrary lordly jurisdiction, except as villages eventually purchased charters of freedom to fix their obligations. In England, however, although most peasants were unfree, and conceived as chattels of the manor, roughly one- quarter were taken to be free (having less onerous obligations) and, thus, entitled to justice in the King s courts. In these, a Common Law of property rights developed limited, however, to the free peasants and lords having freehold tenures. Initially, royal justices counterbalanced the local power of lords, issuing writs holding them to account for abuse of free peasant property (Comninel, 2000a). These royal writs were so effective in preserving property rights, however, that lords themselves soon turned to them to protect infants and other vulnerable heirs, for which feudal law was wholly unreliable. The specific form of extra- economic surplus appropriation in England, therefore, differed crucially in relation to the state, compared to France, and with this difference a double legal system developed during the feudal era. English manors partook in the general historical patterns of the feudal mode of production, through the open- field production regulated in their manorial courts. Royal courts, however, evolved to provide elaborate instruments protecting freehold but not customary property rights. The Common Law established truly effective abstract property rights, which underlay the day- to- day regulation of customary tenurial succession and open- field production in the manorial courts. As Robert Brenner first demonstrated (Aston and Philpin, 1985), the final crisis of feudal society brought radically different results in England and France. Through unique historical processes that enclosed the open- fields and eliminated customary law, Common Law property rights emerged as the foundation for agrarian capitalism in M2834 FINE TEXT.indd 136 10/11/2011 09:59

Feudalism 137 England, eventually leading to fully capitalist society through the Industrial Revolution (Comninel, 2000a). In France, by contrast, specifically feudal forms of politically constituted property increasingly were transformed into state offices within the Absolutist State no longer truly feudal, but still entirely non- capitalist (Comninel, 1987). Only after the Napoleonic Wars did industrial capitalist social relations of production begin to transform the various non- capitalist Continental societies that had developed through historically specific paths following the crisis of feudalism. M2834 FINE TEXT.indd 137 10/11/2011 09:59